Co-opetition Between Giants- Collaboration With

download Co-opetition Between Giants- Collaboration With

of 14

Transcript of Co-opetition Between Giants- Collaboration With

  • 8/10/2019 Co-opetition Between Giants- Collaboration With

    1/14

    Research Policy 40 (2011) 650663

    Contents lists available atScienceDirect

    Research Policy

    j o u r n a l h o m e p a g e : w w w . e l s e v i e r . c o m / l o c a t e / r e s p o l

    Co-opetition between giants: Collaboration with competitors for technologicalinnovation

    Devi R. Gnyawali , Byung-Jin (Robert) Park 1

    Department of Management, Virginia Polytechnic Institute and State University, Blacksburg, VA 24061 (0233), USA

    a r t i c l e i n f o

    Article history:

    Received 1 June 2009

    Received in revised form24 November 2010

    Accepted 13 January 2011

    Available online 12 February 2011

    Keywords:

    Co-opetition

    Innovation

    S-LCD

    Co-opetition capability

    Case study

    a b s t r a c t

    We investigate why and how co-opetition (simultaneous pursuit of collaboration and competition)

    between large firms occurs, evolves, and impacts the participating firms and the industry. We develop

    a multi-level conceptual framework by combining literature-based conceptual arguments and insights

    from an in-depth study of an exemplar case of co-opetition between Samsung Electronics and Sony Cor-

    poration. Our study demonstrates that co-opetition is challenging yet very helpful for firms to address

    major technological challenges, to create benefits for partnering firms, and to advance technological

    innovation. We alsoshow thatco-opetition between giants causes subsequent co-opetition among other

    firms and results in advanced technological development. Moreover, co-opetition capabilities of firms

    play an important role in enhancing common benefits as well as in gaining proportionately larger share

    of the benefits.

    2011 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

    1. Introduction

    Scholarly attention to co-opetition, which we define as a

    strategy embodying simultaneous cooperation and competition

    between firms (Bengtsson and Kock, 2000; Gnyawali et al.,

    2008)has increased with its practical significance (Brandenburger

    and Nalebuff, 1996; Dagnino and Padula, 2002; Luo, 2004;

    Walley, 2007). Co-opetition is more critical in high technol-

    ogy contexts because of several challenges such as shrinking

    product life cycles, need for heavy investments in research and

    development, convergence of multiple technologies, and impor-

    tance of technological standards (Garud, 1994; Gnyawali and

    Park, 2009; Gomes-Casseres, 1994). Because competing firms

    possess relevant resources and face similar pressures, collab-

    oration with competitors enables firms to acquire and create

    new technological knowledge and use the knowledge in pur-

    suit of innovations (Quintana-Garca and Benavides-Velasco,2004; Ritala et al., 2009). Despite its increased importance, lim-

    ited research has systematically examined why and how firms

    engage in co-opetition and how co-opetition impacts innova-

    tion. This paper aims to address this critical gap by focusing

    on the following questions: (a) what factors drive co-opetition

    in the context of technological innovation? and (b) how does

    Corresponding author. Tel.: +1 540 231 5021; fax: +1 540 231 3076.

    E-mail addresses:[email protected](D.R. Gnyawali),[email protected](B.-J. Park).1 Tel.: +1 540 231 2749; fax: +1 540 231 3076.

    co-opetition impact the participating firms and the indus-

    try?

    We address these questions in two phases. First,we reviewrele-

    vant literature to develop conceptual arguments regarding drivers,

    dynamics, and consequences of co-opetition. Second, we discuss

    our study of a unique and exemplar case of co-opetition between

    giants, i.e., a joint venture called S-LCD between two rivals Sam-

    sungElectronics and Sony Corporation to develop and manufacture

    flat-screen LCD TV panels. The case study was instrumental in

    illuminating critical factors relevant to the drivers, dynamics, and

    outcomes of co-opetition described in the conceptual discussion.

    By blending the conceptual arguments and the findings from the

    case study, we develop a multi-level conceptual framework of co-

    opetitionthat consistsof multipledrivers,dynamics, andoutcomes.

    Our framework also underscores the role of firms co-opetition

    capability in creating common benefits by the partners as well as

    in leveraging the benefits by the individual firms.This paper contributes to both co-opetition and innovation lit-

    eratures. First, it enriches our understanding of why and how

    co-opetition between giants could be driven by factors at multi-

    ple levels, how the co-opetition relationship evolves, and how the

    leadingfirms co-opetitionmight impactthe participatingfirms and

    the industry as a whole. Second, we demonstrate that co-opetition

    between leading firms often helps the firms to achieve better out-

    comes in terms of market shares, technological development, and

    technological standards in the industry. We also articulate why co-

    opetition may not generate benefits for participating firms unless

    the firms possess necessary capabilities to anticipate and manage

    0048-7333/$ see front matter 2011 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

    doi:10.1016/j.respol.2011.01.009

    http://localhost/var/www/apps/conversion/tmp/scratch_5/dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2011.01.009http://localhost/var/www/apps/conversion/tmp/scratch_5/dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2011.01.009http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/journal/00487333http://www.elsevier.com/locate/respolmailto:[email protected]:[email protected]://localhost/var/www/apps/conversion/tmp/scratch_5/dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2011.01.009http://localhost/var/www/apps/conversion/tmp/scratch_5/dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2011.01.009mailto:[email protected]:[email protected]://www.elsevier.com/locate/respolhttp://www.sciencedirect.com/science/journal/00487333http://localhost/var/www/apps/conversion/tmp/scratch_5/dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2011.01.009
  • 8/10/2019 Co-opetition Between Giants- Collaboration With

    2/14

    D.R. Gnyawali, B.-J. Park / Research Policy 40 (2011) 650663 651

    challenges and opportunities in co-opetition. Finally, we articulate

    unique dynamics of co-opetition between giants and explain how

    it changes the dynamics in the industry. Ourfindings show that co-

    opetition between giants causes subsequent co-opetition among

    other firms, whichchanges the competition structure in the indus-

    try andresults in advancedtechnological development. We suggest

    that co-opetitionbetween bigrivals canbe instrumental not just to

    push technological advancements but also to provide consumers

    with better products and lower prices.

    2. Co-opetition for technological innovation

    In this section, we provide an overview of the co-opetition

    literature and discuss why co-opetition is important for techno-

    logical innovation. We then discuss key drivers and outcomes of

    co-opetition between leading firms (giants). The conceptual foun-

    dation laid in this section provides the basis for the case study

    described in the next section.

    2.1. Role of co-opetition in innovation

    Based on the core idea of the dynamic interplay between col-

    laboration and competition (Chen, 2008; Gnyawali and Madhavan,2001; Gnyawali et al., 2006; Lado et al., 1997), co-opetition is

    considered a unique strategy that capitalizes on the benefits

    of collaboration and competition (Brandenburger and Nalebuff,

    1996; Bengtsson and Kock, 2000)and necessitates management

    approaches that can address the tension caused by the inter-

    play. Increased popularity of co-opetition is evident by the fact

    that over 50% of collaborative relations (strategic alliances) are

    between firms within the same industry, that is, among competi-

    tors (Harbison and Pekar, 1998).

    While elements of both competition and collaboration are

    essential for the conceptualization of co-opetition, scholars have

    used a wide variety of definitions and perspectives in examin-

    ing co-opetition (Yami et al., 2010).Some definitions are focused

    and others are rather broad.Brandenburger and Nalebuff (1996)adopt a broad view of co-opetition and define it as relationships

    in a value-net in which two competitors (e.g. computer manu-

    facturers) can be complementors through their cooperation with

    a third firm (e.g. software producers). Co-opetition is viewed by

    them as the sum of many different relationships and the cooper-

    ative and competitive parts are divided between different actors

    (Bengtsson et al., 2010).On the other hand, Bengtsson and Kock

    (1999, 2000) narrowly define co-opetition as simultaneous col-

    laboration and competition between two firms and the different

    parts of the relationship are divided between activities. For exam-

    ple, competitors cooperate within activities far from the customer,

    while competing in activities that are close to customer interac-

    tion (Bengtsson and Kock, 2000).Gnyawali et al. (2008)provide a

    framework that explains how co-opetition occurs very intensely(when a dyad engages in simultaneous collaboration and competi-

    tion) and much less intensely (when several firms engage in some

    forms of collaboration and competition at different time periods).

    They suggest that the most intellectually intriguing and manageri-

    ally challenging form of co-opetition is dyadic inter-firm. Along the

    same lines, Bengtssonand Kock(1999) suggest thatscholars should

    more narrowly define co-opetition in order to deeply understand

    co-opetition and its implications. Accordingly, we adopt a focused

    definition of co-opetition, i.e., simultaneous pursuit of collabora-

    tion and competition between a pair of firms.

    Although co-opetition is considered a win-win strategy, firms

    struggle with a dilemma between the need to work together in

    order to create value and the temptation to be opportunistic in

    order to appropriate a greater share of the created value (Lavie,

    2007; Gnyawaliand Park,2009; Ritala andHurmelinna-Laukkanen,

    2009). Co-opetitive relationships thus involve high degree of inter-

    dependence with each other and are full of conflict, and yet the

    potential for payoff is also high. Therefore, it is important to

    examine conditions in whichfirms engage in co-opetition, how co-

    opetition evolves, and how firms can achieve positive outcomes

    through co-opetition.

    Another important inquiry is how co-opetition could impact

    innovation. Innovation has long been seen as a source of com-

    petitive advantage (Abernathy and Clark, 1985; Ahuja and Katila,

    2001; Schumpeter, 1942; Teece, 1996; Utterback andSuarez,1993).

    Research shows that alliance partners and network help firms to

    access, acquire, and leverage important resources in pursuing inno-

    vation (Ahuja, 2000; Ahuja et al., 2008; Lei, 2003; Powell et al.,

    1996; Sampson, 2007; Tether, 2002; Tsai, 2009). Collaborations

    provide timely access to knowledge and resources that are oth-

    erwise unavailable, and firms can combine each others resources

    in pursing innovation projects that involve high risks and require

    heavy investments. Because the relational resources and advan-

    tages that stem from such relationships are important (Dyer and

    Singh, 1998), firms actively pursue inter-firm alliances to create

    new knowledge and capabilities so that they can enhance their

    innovation outcomes(Sampson,2007). Verylimitedresearch,how-

    ever, has addressed how co-opetition impacts innovation. Jordeand Teece (1990)argue that cooperation among competitors is

    essential if innovating firms are to compete in todays global mar-

    kets. Quintana-Garca and Benavides-Velasco (2004) empirically

    show that collaboration with direct competitors is important not

    only to acquire new technological knowledge and skills from the

    partner, but also to create and access other capabilities based on

    intensive exploitation of the existing ones. Considering that co-

    opetition is popular in high-tech industries (Dagnino and Rocco,

    2009; Gnyawali and Park, 2009), it is necessary to examine the

    role of co-opetition in innovation in high-techindustries and under

    what conditions firms might generate positive innovation perfor-

    mance in co-opetitive relationships.

    Collaboration with competitors also raises public policy con-

    cerns with the potential for collaborating competitors to engagein collusion that may hurt innovativeness as well as consumer

    welfare. Collusion concern could be high when giants with strong

    market power engage in co-opetition.To address thisconcern,Jorde

    and Teece (1990)suggest that cooperation among competitors for

    technological innovation might not necessarily be anticompeti-

    tive because of the potential to bring unique products, create new

    markets, and develop integrative technologies that will ultimately

    benefit consumers.Ingram and Yue (2008)argue that the oppor-

    tunity for cooperation between competitors should not be seen as

    violating antitrust issues, but rather as a legitimate business prac-

    tice. They argue that deflating the taboo against the cooperation

    between competitors also contributes to the policy makers deci-

    sion when designing policies that aim at developing a more viable

    business community (Ingram andYue, 2008, p. 296). An importantneed in the literature therefore is to examine if and when cooper-

    ation among competitors could promote competition and, in turn,

    innovation as suggested byTeece (1992).

    2.2. Drivers of co-opetition in high technology industries

    As notedearlier,high technology industries seem to face unique

    challenges and opportunities and therefore are more conducive to

    co-opetition. FollowingGnyawali and Park (2009)and other prior

    research (Chen and Li, 1999; Palmberg and Martikainen, 2006;

    Quintana-Garca and Benavides-Velasco, 2004; Sampson, 2007),

    we identify key industry-level factors that drive co-opetition.

    Gnyawali and Park (2009) argue that three major technological

    challenges shorter product life cycles, convergence of multi-

  • 8/10/2019 Co-opetition Between Giants- Collaboration With

    3/14

    652 D.R. Gnyawali, B.-J. Park / Research Policy 40 (2011) 650663

    ple technologies, and increasing R&D and capital expenditures

    serve as important drivers for firms in high technology industries

    to engage in co-opetition. As product life cycles are dramat-

    ically shrinking (Chen and Li, 1999) due to rapidly changing

    customer preferences and speed and magnitude of technological

    changes, firms need to speed-up their innovation efforts (Lynn

    and Akgn, 1998).Technological convergence provides both risks

    and opportunities to firms, which facilitates co-opetition. Conver-

    gence increases risks and uncertainty aboutmarket and technology

    and pushes firms to reach out to other firms, including competi-

    tors, to share the risk and to access and combine a variety of

    sophisticated technologies. Technological convergence also offers

    companies (especially for leading firms)opportunities to set indus-

    try standards. Besides competing to develop new technologies,

    companies try to shape emergingindustrystructures andstandards

    required to support their development and diffusion(Garud, 1994).

    As technological standards and platforms lay the foundation for

    new products and services (Lei, 2003), competitors cooperate with

    each other to win battles for industry standards (Gomes-Casseres,

    1994) and to create industry-wide norms (Mione, 2008).Finally,

    R&D intensity (R&D expenditures as percent sales) is very high in

    high technology sectors (BIS, 2009).Such high R&D costs provide

    strong incentives for companiesto cooperate withcompetitors that

    have a large resource base. Creating a co-opetitive relationship isan effective way to combine R&D expenses, expertise, and other

    resources (Zineldin, 2004).

    In addition to the industry and technological trends discussed

    above, firm strategies and resources are likely to motivate giants

    to engage in co-opetition. From the firm strategy perspective,

    leading firms aspire to lead their industry and constantly pursue

    technological innovations to establish industry standards and gain

    competitive advantages (Ahuja et al., 2008; Lei, 2003). From the

    resource/capability perspective, large rival partners haveresources

    and capabilities superior to many other potential partners in the

    industry. Resources and capabilities of competitors are also likely

    to be directly relevant because competitors confrontcommonchal-

    lenges. Superior and relevant resources and capabilities will be

    critical for speeding up R&D process or pursuing industry (or tech-nology) standards.

    2.3. Dynamics of co-opetition between leading firms

    Co-opetitive relationships are unstable (Park and Russo, 1996)

    and dynamic in nature (Luo, 2007), which cause high level of

    tension for firms. Leading firms pursuing co-opetition with rivals

    confront a dilemma: the existence of attractive opportunities and

    risks of misappropriation by the partner. That is, co-opetition

    between leading players involves high levels of tension for var-

    ious reasons. As Ingram and Yue (2008) note that competition

    and cooperation derive from the same relationships to resources,

    the very characteristics of partners that are critical for pursuing

    opportunities may also cause competitive tension. Tension inten-sifies because direct competitors may be aware of, motivated to

    pursue, and be capable of confronting each other (Chen et al.,

    2007).Also, firms competitive goals conflict because of their aspi-

    rations to become market leaders. Any opportunistic behavior by

    the competitor-partnercould result in serious knowledge and mar-

    ket loss. These conditions coupled with potential for high payoff

    from co-opetition simultaneously lead to instability in and rein-

    forcement of the relationship. Such tension and instability also

    underscore the need to have a more balancedpartnershipbetween

    the partners and the importance of balancing competition and

    cooperation by the firms.

    The abovementioned conditions are illustrative of how co-

    opetition forms and evolves over time and thereby help explain

    the dynamics of co-opetition. In the co-opetition formation stage,

    firms will actively seek a way toreduce thehazardsof opportunism.

    Transaction cost economics suggests that adopting an equity joint

    venture structure mitigates the hazards of opportunism because

    incentives are more closely aligned (Oxley, 1997; Sampson, 2004).

    Narrowing the scope of cooperation is an alternative to reduce the

    risk of partner opportunism (Oxley and Sampson, 2004).Mutual

    commitment of partners top management to co-opetition would

    be an important factor in dealing with opportunism.

    Participating firms need for value creation and appropriation

    and balance of competition and collaboration lead to dynamism

    in co-opetition. Value creation occurs through cost sharing,

    economies of scale, standard setting, and use of relational-specific

    routines.Luo (2007)implies that firms will get more opportuni-

    ties to create greater common value and benefit from it when the

    industryor thebusinesssegmentis growing.Leading firmscan even

    create new markets. Being able to balance competition and cooper-

    ation is critical to maintain stability in relationships (Das and Teng,

    2000).Dynamics of co-opetition would be thus shaped by indus-

    try and partner conditions as well as firms capabilities to pursue a

    win-win approach, manage the tension, and balance the relation-

    ships. We explicitly discuss the role of firm capability in Section

    4.4.

    2.4. Outcomes of co-opetition between leading firms

    We suggest that the outcomes of co-opetition between lead-

    ing firms should be analyzed at multiple levels (focal firm, dyadic

    or combined, and industry levels) to explore the effects of value

    creation and appropriation and address the concern of scholars

    and policy makers on the industry impact of co-opetition. Fur-

    ther, participating firms capability to manage co-opetition could

    be important for firms to generate benefits from co-opetition.

    Value creation and value appropriation are central to co-opetition

    (Brandenburger and Nalebuff, 1996).Cooperation is based on the

    expectation to enlarge and/or protect the size of value through

    joint efforts, but competition is driven by the desire to capture a

    bigger proportion of the value privately. Private benefits depend

    on the distribution of common benefits and the effects go beyondthecollaboration boundary.Commonbenefits aredistributed based

    on the resource dependency; the partners who bring the more

    critical resources to the relationship can appropriate a higher per-

    centage of the benefits (Pfeffer and Salancik, 1978). By learning

    from partners, firms can facilitate their own product/technological

    development andleverage theknowledge across related businesses

    within the firms. Such effects may be intensified by competition in

    co-opetition relationships. When competing firms cooperate, they

    have a strong incentive to benchmark each other and prepare for

    the consequences of competition (Tsai, 2002).Capability of firms

    to effectively manage co-opetition would be helpful in generating

    higher common benefits and in appropriating a greater share of

    such benefits. A firm possessing the mindset and experience rele-

    vant forco-opetition may be able to handle conflicts, creategreatervalue, and appropriate bigger private benefits.

    We suggest that co-opetition between leading firms in high-

    tech industries, especially in the upstream aspects of a value chain

    suchas R&D andtechnological innovation, leadsto a strong positive

    impact on the industry. Co-opetition between major players may

    promote innovationthrough competition.Teece (1992) argues that

    complex forms of cooperation are usually necessary to promote

    competition. We note that co-opetition between leading firms

    may cause subsequent co-opetition among other firms because

    many followers typically imitate and respond to industry leaders

    actions. Thus, co-opetition between giants may change competi-

    tive dynamics to more intensified form of competitionand leads to

    group-to-group competition. Co-opetition can also enable firms to

    overcome the appropriability (spillover) problems (Teece, 1992).

  • 8/10/2019 Co-opetition Between Giants- Collaboration With

    4/14

    D.R. Gnyawali, B.-J. Park / Research Policy 40 (2011) 650663 653

    Teece (1992, p. 12)points out that coupling to competitors often

    promotes innovation because the set of firms receiving the bene-

    fitsis likelyto include a greater portion offirmswhich have incurred

    R&D costs. Finally, co-opetition is more likely to promote price

    decline and better products in the market. Co-opetition between

    giants may let consumers enjoy multi-feature products at reason-

    able price due to economies of scale, pulling of complementary

    resources to develop more integrative technologies, reduction of

    duplication efforts, as well as intensified competition.

    So far, we have reviewed the relevant literature and developed

    conceptual arguments regarding the drivers, dynamics, and out-

    comes of co-opetition between leading firms. Now we turn to an

    exemplar case to illuminate and expand conceptual arguments.

    After a thorough discussion of the case, we will propose a multi-

    levelconceptualmodel by blendingthe literature-based conceptual

    arguments and findings from the case.

    3. In-depth case study

    Case-based exploratory methods are best suited for investigat-

    ing new and poorly understood phenomena (Eisenhardt, 1989)

    that have multiple and complex elements (Dodgson et al., 2008)

    and that evolve over time (Langley, 1999).Since co-opetition is amulti-faceted and paradoxical phenomenon, a thoroughcase study

    spanningmultiple yearswouldprovidea goodunderstandingof the

    drivers, dynamics, and consequences of co-opetition. Accordingly,

    we conducted an in-depth study of an exemplar case with the goal

    of providing richer anddeeper insightson thephenomenon to bring

    key dimensions to light (Yin, 1984).

    3.1. Research design and case selection

    The research design employed an exploratory approach in order

    to provide meaningful insights on the drivers, dynamics, and out-

    comes of co-opetition between powerful large players. With the

    goal of an exemplar case, we chose a much publicized joint ven-

    ture between two major and large rivals in the electronics industry Samsung Electronics and Sony Corporation spanning a seven

    year period (20032009).

    Formanyyears, Samsung Electronicskey mission was to unseat

    Sony Corporation as the worlds top electronics maker (Dvorak

    and Ramstad, 2006),and both Sony and Samsung competed vig-

    orously in many product-market segments. Despite their fierce

    rivalry, the two firms established a joint venture (called S-LCD) in

    April 2004 to develop and produce 7th generation (motherglass

    size of 1870mm2200mm) liquid crystal display (LCD) panels

    for flat screen TVs. The initial investment was US$1 billion from

    each firm, and they tripled their investment and moved on to

    the 8th generation technology within a few years. Samsung con-

    tributed its technological strengths in the LCD technology while

    Sony contributed its technological strengths and brand recognitionin television.

    We believe that the co-opetitionbetween these giant and fierce

    rivals is probablythe bestexemplarcase to understand co-opetition

    and its impact. These two firms are largely matched in their size

    and resources (refer toTable 1for details) and they have overlap-

    ping products and markets worldwide. In 2003 when they agreed

    to establish S-LCD, the annual revenue of Samsung Electronics was

    US$54.1 billion and that of Sony was US$67.2 billion and global

    brand rankings were 25th and 20th respectively. They have been

    competing in various product markets, suchas TV, computer,video,

    audio, and handset, as well as in various geographic markets in the

    US, Europe, and Asia. This highly matched resources and capabili-

    ties, as well as a past history of competition, make SamsungSony

    co-opetition an intriguing case.

    Table 1

    Comparison between Sony Corporation and Samsung Electronics.

    Resources Samsung

    ElectronicsaSony Corporation

    2003 2008 2003 2008

    Total assets (US$ mi llion) 32,751 83,771 83,786 126,260

    Sales (US$ million) 54,114 96,495 67,178 77,688

    Oper at ing incom e (US$ mill io n) 5,258 4,799 1,188 ( 2, 289)

    Net income 4,978 4,686 790 (1,027)

    R&D investment (US$ million) 2,900 5,489 4,590 4,998

    R&D intensity (%) 5.36 5.69 6.83 6.43

    Number of patents registered in US 1,306 4,237 1,513 1,723

    Global brand (ranking) 25 21 20 25

    Source: Annual Reports of Sony and Samsung Electronics, USPTO, Business Week.a Samsung Electronics datais basedon consolidated financialstatements.In 2008,

    Samsung Electronics R&D investment is 9.5% of parent company sales. Total assets

    in 2003 are based on non-consolidated financial data.

    Because it is a joint venture between two market leaders and

    has had tremendous impact on the industry, the case provides a

    useful context to understand whyand howco-opetitionfor techno-

    logical innovation between giants or large powerful players occurs

    and how such co-opetition could impact the participating firms,

    other players in the industry, and the industry as a whole over

    time. It is an interesting setting for our study also because trendsin the past several years suggest that the flat panel TV industry

    has the characteristics of short product life cycles, a massive capi-

    tal investment requirement, and a broad range of products. As the

    TV technology changed from analog (CRT TV) to digital such as

    liquid crystal display (LCD) and plasma display panel (PDP), rela-

    tionships and dynamics among major players have also changed.

    During the transition period, competition surrounding technolog-

    ical standards has become intense. Thus, this is an intriguing case

    to examine co-opetition because the firms are fierce rivals, have

    matched resources and overlapping markets, and operate in a

    rapidly changing and technology-intensive industry.

    3.2. Sources of data

    This study primarily relies on secondary data for two reasons.First, because the joint venture was widely publicized in media

    outlets, it was possible to collect relevant information from pub-

    lished sources. Compared to interview data, published secondary

    data arelikely tobe more objectiveandallowfor cross-checks using

    multiple sources. Second, ourattemptsto interview managers of S-

    LCDdid notsucceed mainly because internal working details of the

    venture are kept secret. Even though we informally interviewed a

    few managers, it was difficult to get first hand information of the

    intents, strategies, and positions of the partners. Data collection

    involved two primary approaches. First, we collected data using

    the two firms annual reports, industry research firms such as Dis-

    playSearch, and other publicly available information.These sources

    helped us develop a better understandingof the companies, various

    technologies and trends, the industry, and related aspects. Second,using the Factiva database we downloaded and analyzed all news

    reports related to the S-LCD, covering the period of 2003 (a year

    prior to the formation of the S-LCD) to 2009. The Factiva database

    covers thousands of newspapers from around the world. We made

    sure thatthe reports containedmajor Japanese and Korean publica-

    tionssuch as Nikkei, NikkeiWeekly, Korea Times,and Korea Herald.

    One of the authors is a native Korean and was able to analyze news

    reports published in the Korean language and gained additional

    insights about the joint venture.

    4. Results from the case study

    We organize results from the case study in the following man-

    ner: what factors led Samsung and Sony to engage in co-opetition;

  • 8/10/2019 Co-opetition Between Giants- Collaboration With

    5/14

    654 D.R. Gnyawali, B.-J. Park / Research Policy 40 (2011) 650663

    howthe co-opetition evolved over time; andhow this co-opetition

    impacted the participating firms, other players, and the industry

    as a whole. Data collected from the various sources noted above

    are used to illustrate relevant points. We provide in theappendix

    a summary of relevant quotes from the Factiva database and illus-

    trate how they relateto the various aspects of ourdiscussion in this

    section.

    4.1. Drivers of co-opetition

    What made two large and fierce rivals pursue the co-opetitive

    partnership? Our examination showed that multi-level factors

    were drivingthis relationship. In the TV industry,flat panel displays

    have replaced Cathode-ray tube (CRT), which was the predominant

    display technology for a long time. In addition to the prominent

    LCD and PDP, firms introduced other technologies such as electro-

    luminescent display (ELD), light emitting diode (LED), and organic

    light-emitting diode (OLED). Such efforts of firms to introduce

    new technologies have shortened product life cycles. The indus-

    try shifted from analog to digital technology. The digital era also

    required huge capital expenditures for the mass production of flat

    panel displays. Moreover, technological convergence forced firms

    to develop new products, such as LED TV and 3D TV. Understand-

    ing complex technologiesand engagingin massproduction becamecritical in the digital era (Sony Annual Report, 2008).Thus, at the

    technology or industry levels, key forces leading to the forma-

    tion of the S-LCD were rapid change in the technology, the cost

    of developing newtechnologies, and the complicated nature of the

    technology.

    Atthe firmlevel,bothSamsungand Sony areveryaggressiveand

    proactive in terms of their technological development and market-

    ing. Both are either leaders or close followers in many consumer

    electronics technologies and products. The firms have not only

    remained a step ahead of the competition but have also aimed to

    lead in their major segments.They also established several techno-

    logical standards. As a recent example, the Sony group, including

    Samsung, won the DVD battle with the Blu-ray technology over

    the Toshiba groups HD-DVD. The battle for the standard betweenLCD and PDP is intriguing. PDP technology led by Matsushita (now

    Panasonic) and LG Electronics was dominant in large screen TVs

    (over 40 in.) segment until Samsung and Sony worked together to

    produce large LCD panels through S-LCD. Samsung stated that S-

    LCDs industry-leading production capacity will be leveraged to

    standardize and popularize LCD TVs with panel sizes in both the

    40 and 50 ranges (Samsung Electronics Annual Report, 2006,p.

    47).

    Feeling of vulnerability in the face of changing industry and

    technological dynamics prompted the firms to join hands with

    competitors possessing complementary resources. When it con-

    sidered the alliance, Sony needed to address a critical gap. Sony

    had leadership in the traditional CRT TV market for a long time,

    but it lagged far behind in the rapidly growing flat-screen TV mar-ket. Sony suffered a massive loss in 2003, which caused anxiety

    in the stock market. The Sony Shock was attributed to the weak

    performance of its main electronics business, which accounted for

    about 66% of total sales (Uranaka, 2003).The TV business, which

    accounted for about 20% of Sonys revenue, was undergoing mas-

    sive restructuring to escape from the shock (Uranaka, 2003; Sony

    Annual Report, 2004). In shifting its business focus to flat panel TV,

    Sony executives realized that a stable supply of LCD panels was

    critical for it to quickly catch-up on the flat-panel TV segment.

    In 2003, Samsung was one of the strongest LCD panel producers

    (Kim, 2006),even though it was not the largest LCD TV maker. For

    Samsung, securing a large partner like Sony was critical to achieve

    economies of scale and win the battle for the technological stan-

    dard.Sonys precise and highstandards for technology and product

    quality helped to push Samsungs panel technology ahead of oth-

    ers. Each firm had unique characteristics and capabilities that the

    other one needed. Sony benefited from Samsung in terms of strong

    capability in the LCD technology, drive for pushing the LCD tech-

    nology, and overall resource base. Samsung benefited from Sony in

    terms of TV makingexpertise,brand name,and large andcontinued

    demand for LCD panels (Dvorak and Ramstad, 2006).

    In additionto the complementarities noted above, the two rivals

    shared the massive capital investment needed to develop and

    produce LCD panels. The total investment of approximately US$6

    billion in 7th and 8th generation LCD panel plants was possible

    because the two leading firms pursued the same goal of focusing

    on large-size and high value-added models. It is hard to invest in

    large-scale LCD facilities alone, and it holds a lot of attraction to

    make investment in a place of strong infrastructure like this, said

    Idei, CEOof Sony Corporation (Yonhap English News, 2004, refer to

    Appendix A).Partnering with competitors with strong technolog-

    ical capabilities was critical as the firms also faced time pressure

    and could not develop the technology on their own. By collaborat-

    ingwithSamsung, Sony could launch itsBravia series in the market

    within one year after establishing S-LCD, and Samsung soon fol-

    lowed with its own Bordeaux series. In summary, main reasons

    for the formation of this co-opetition relationship included impor-

    tant factors related to the industry and technology, the nature andstrategies of the firms, and resources and capabilities they had to

    offer to each other. The firms not only felt that they could over-

    cometheir vulnerabilitybut alsoenhance theirindividual strengths

    and combine their strengths to create a positive impact on the LCD

    technology and the flat-screen TV industry.

    4.2. Dynamics of SamsungSony co-opetition

    As discussed in Section2.3,dynamics relates to formation and

    evolution of co-opetition. We observed that the governance mode

    and the commitment of top management were important factors in

    the formationof co-opetition. The firms established a joint venture,

    a governance mode that provided strong safeguards and balance.

    Each party owns 50% of the venture, with the CEO from Sam-sung and the CFO from Sony. Top management from the two firms

    already had close relationships and made strong commitments to

    the joint venture. For example, at Sonys request, Mr. Jae-Yong Lee,

    the current vice president of Samsung Electronics and the eldest

    son of the Samsung Group chairman, became a member of S-LCDs

    board of directors. As Samsung was involved in both LCD and PDP

    technologies, Sony wanted a strong commitment to S-LCD from

    Samsungs top management.

    The co-opetitive relationship has evolved over time. In Fig. 1,

    we present areas of collaboration and competition mainly through

    S-LCD and illustrate how the co-opetition between the two rivals

    has evolved. The upper part ofFig. 1illustrates areas of competi-

    tion and the lower part illustrates collaboration; moving from left

    to right provides the evolution of co-opetition over the period of20032009.

    Since the establishment of S-LCD in 2004, Samsung and Sony

    have deepened their resource commitments to the venture. S-LCD

    started 7th generation LCD panel production in April 2005 and the

    production capacity increased from 60,000 to 100,000 panels per

    month through additional investments. Based on their tremendous

    success in the 7th generation technology, they have invested in

    the 8th generation plant, which produces LCD panels of 46 in. and

    larger. S-LCD started its 8th generation production in August 2007

    with a production capacity of 50,000 substrates per month. In June

    2009, S-LCD started production from its second 8thgeneration line

    with a production capacity of 70,000 substrates per month.

    While collaboratingthroughthe S-LCD, Samsung and Sonywere

    simultaneouslycompetingfiercelyin the flatscreen TV market (and

  • 8/10/2019 Co-opetition Between Giants- Collaboration With

    6/14

    D.R. Gnyawali, B.-J. Park / Research Policy 40 (2011) 650663 655

    Fig. 1. Evolution of co-opetition between Sony Corporation and Samsung Electronics.

    in other aspects of their business but not depicted in Fig. 1).For

    instance, while Sony was the first one to introduce a LCD TV with

    its Bravia model in summer 2005 and became the industry leader

    (unseating Sharp Corporation), Samsung countered with its Bor-

    deaux model and overtook Sony in the 3rd quarter of 2006. Since

    then, competition between the two companies for market lead-ership has become more intense, which in turn caused Samsung

    and Sony to emerge as leading TV makers. Further, they competed

    in developing new technologies and products while cooperating

    in LCD panel production. For example, in December 2007, Sony

    launched first 11 in. OLED TV in Japan and Samsung responded by

    showing 31in. OLED TV at the Consumer Electronics Show in Jan-

    uary 2008. In February 2008, Sony announced a joint venture with

    SharpCorporation, the3rdlargestLCDTV makerat thattime,forthe

    10th generation LCD panels. With an investment of around US$4.2

    billion, the production capacity of the JV is planned to be 72,000

    substrates per monthand Sony plans to have 34% equity and Sharp

    will have 66%.

    We observed that in the dynamics of the co-opetitive rela-

    tionship the two rivals followed the fundamental principle ofco-opetitioncreating a bigger value together while competing to

    gain a largerportion of thevalue. They could create andsharevalue

    through cost sharing (US$6 billion investment), economiesof scale,

    andstandard setting (LCD versusPDP). They also sharedtheirinter-

    ests through a stronggovernance mode (equity jointventure)and a

    strong commitment to the venture. Theyalso balancedcompetition

    and cooperation. For example, they cross-licensed their patents

    (11,000 patents from Samsung and 13,000 patents from Sony) in

    November 2004, which facilitated knowledge sharing and product

    development. On the otherhand, theytried to maintainuniqueness

    of each company and promote healthy competition in the mar-

    ket. So-called Differentiated Technology Patents, such as Sonys

    PlayStation architecture and Samsungs home networking technol-

    ogy, are excluded in the cross-licensing agreement. The agreement

    also does not apply to TFT-LCD and OLED display patents. Cross-

    licensing not only facilitated knowledge sharing but also kept their

    core knowledge protected.

    4.3. Impact of SamsungSony co-opetition

    Co-opetition between Samsung and Sony had a tremendous

    impact on both firms, the LCD segment, and the TV industry as a

    whole. We focus on howthisco-opetition enabled thefirms to both

    create andappropriate value and howit changed the technological

    and industry landscapes.

    4.3.1. Value creation for the partners

    SamsungSony co-opetition created a substantial value for the

    firms. First, the success of S-LCD and its impact on the part-

    ners are evident when we look at the market shares (refer to

    Figs. 2 and 3for trends in market shares). Before S-LCD produced

    LCD panels, Sony and Samsung were ranked as the 3rd and 4th

    LCD TV makers (behind Sharp and Philips). In the 4th quarter of

    2008, however, Samsung and Sony were ranked as the 1st and

    0

    5

    10

    15

    20

    25

    2008Q4 '07Q4 '06Q4 '05Q4 '04

    MarketShare(%)

    Samsung

    Sony

    Sharp

    LGE

    Philips

    Fig. 2. Market share (revenue basis) of top five firms in the LCD TV segment.

    Source: DisplaySearch.

  • 8/10/2019 Co-opetition Between Giants- Collaboration With

    7/14

  • 8/10/2019 Co-opetition Between Giants- Collaboration With

    8/14

    D.R. Gnyawali, B.-J. Park / Research Policy 40 (2011) 650663 657

    Fig.5. (a) Cooperative relationships amongmajor competing firmsin theflat panelTV industry(as of December 2004).(b) Cooperativerelationshipsamong majorcompeting

    firms in theflat panel TV industry (asof December 2009).Circleswith solid line: FirmsproducingbothLCD TVsand PDPTVs;Circles with dottedline:Firms producing mainly

    LCD TVs; Shaded circles: Firms producing mainly PDP TVs; Boxes: JVs producing LCD panels; Solid line between circles: collaboration between firms.

    the benefits and have such an impact on the industry? While co-

    opetitionentails the risk of being out-learned and out-competed by

    the competitor-partner, Samsung and Sony were able to manage

    the risk and generate tremendous benefits from the co-opetition.

    We now turn to discuss the critical role of firm capabilities to deal

    with co-opetition, which is rarely discussed in the co-opetition lit-

    erature.

    As noted earlier, each firm had resources and capabilities that

    the other one needed, which helped to prompt the firms toengage in co-opetition. However, each firms own internal capa-

    bility played an important role in enabling the participating firms

    to create greater common benefits and appropriate a greater share

    fromthe benefits.The relationship has evolved withbalance mainly

    due to firm capabilities and subsequent strategic initiatives under-

    taken by the firms. Sony had internal strengths in TV making and

    had achieved market leadership and technological prowess in the

    industry. As a result, it was able to instantly introduce LCD TV and

    gain leadership. Its internal strengths and reputation also helped

    to attract other potential partners. Sonys strengths were instru-

    mental in leading to its collaboration withSharp mentionedearlier.

    Sony was able to show to Samsung that it had other partners

    (options); and therefore, the SamsungSony collaboration stayed

    in balance. Even though such Sonys move raised questions about

    S-LCDs future, the relationship continued because of mutual inter-

    dependence and gains. While Samsung needs Sonys market power

    to get benefits of economies of scale, Sony needs S-LCD because

    8th generation is the most popular one for the time being. Also,

    a win-win approach of open-minded executives was critical for

    the success. Mr. Murayama says that, in consumer electronics, its

    hard to keep secrets long anyway, and being open with Samsung is

    key to making the joint venture work. If we put up barriers, theyll

    close up too (WSJ, 2006,refer to Appendix B). The SonySamsungalliance is certainly a win-win, declares Sang Wan Lee, president

    of Samsungs LCD unit (BusinessWeek, 2006, refer toAppendix C).

    While comparing the benefits to Samsung and Sony, it appears

    that Samsung benefited more from the co-opetition as shown

    in Fig. 2. We suggest that Samsungs internal capability for co-

    opetition contributed to its gain. Samsung has long tried to learn

    from and cooperate with other firms. Samsung has evolved itself

    from a firm producing key parts such as semiconductor to a major

    manufacturer of consumer electronics. In the process, Samsung

    had cooperated with customers that were competitors in the

    final products. Samsungs internal structure was also instrumen-

    tal. Samsungs different businesses, such as semiconductor, mobile

    communication, and LCD,competewith eachother (Chang, 2008, p.

    133). Further, Samsung Electronics LCD unit produces LCD panels

  • 8/10/2019 Co-opetition Between Giants- Collaboration With

    9/14

    658 D.R. Gnyawali, B.-J. Park / Research Policy 40 (2011) 650663

    Dynamics of co-opetition

    between giants

    Formation of co-opetitive

    relationship

    Evolution of co-opetitive

    relationship

    Outcomes of co-opetition

    between giants

    Partners value creation &

    appropriation

    Industry technological

    development & standards

    Industry competitive

    dynamics

    Drivers of co-opetition

    between giants

    Industry and technological

    challenges & opportunities

    Superior and relevant

    partners resources &

    capabilities

    Firm strategies and

    aspirations

    Co-opetition capability

    Co-opetition mindset

    Co-opetition experience

    Resources & capabilities

    Fig. 6. A conceptual model of co-opetition between giants.

    while Samsung SDI, an affiliate of Samsung Group, produces PDPs.

    Both supply to Samsungs TV manufacturing business and compete

    fiercely with each other (Chang, 2008).Also, design was one of the

    Samsungs key strengths which improved subsequentto S-LCDfor-mation. While Samsung used the same panel as Sony did, Samsung

    paid more attention to improving its own TV designs. Its launch of

    Bordeaux TV with a wine-glass shape design helped Samsung to

    catch-up with Sony and then to take the lead. Further, Samsung

    succeeded in creating the LED technology on its own, which was a

    critical factor in solidifying Samsungs position. Such co-opetition

    mindset and co-opetition-driven internal structure enabled Sam-

    sung to effectively engage in co-opetition with Sony and reap large

    benefits from it.

    It is possible that Sonys past strengths and history of in-house

    technological development may have somewhat hindered its gain

    compared to Samsungs. Sony has historically taken pride in its

    reputation as a do-it-yourselfinnovator.Rapid declineof oldtech-

    nologies and the introduction of new ones have challenged Sonys

    ability to keep up with all the latest trends (Luh, 2003, p. 242). Per-

    haps this was a reason why Sony was slow in investing in LCD or

    PDP while competitors were already working on it. Instead, Sony

    tried to develop the OLED technology (Luh, 2003).Involvement in

    S-LCD shows that Sony realized its limitations and the importance

    of co-opetition to catch up with other leading players.

    5. Discussion and conclusion

    Our conceptual discussion followed by insights from the in-

    depth case study led us to propose a conceptual framework of

    co-opetition between giants. We depict such a framework inFig. 6

    and summarize the core points here. In terms of drivers of co-

    opetition, our research has identified factors at multiple levels:challenges and opportunities in the industry and technological

    conditions (such as rate of technological change, convergence of

    technologies,investment in research and development), useful and

    superior resourcesand capabilities of potential partners,and strate-

    gies and aspirations of the firms. Even a giant cannot go it alone

    given the technological trends. Firms seek appropriate partners,

    including rivals, to pursue the opportunities (e.g. setting technol-

    ogy standards) or defend their positions. Our study of the S-LCD

    case showed that the two leading firms engaged in co-opetition

    to deal with technological challenges and opportunities and they

    brought together relevant and complementary resources. These

    factors, whencombined, provided a strong motivation for the firms

    to collaborate with each other althoughtheyhave been fierce rivals

    for a long time.

    The abovementioned drivers of co-opetition are alsoinstrumen-

    tal for the relationships to stay in balance and for co-opetition

    to evolve over time. Continued expectations of greater benefits

    increase firms commitment to the relationship and work togetherto create more benefits as well as strive for a larger share of

    the benefits. As giants engage in co-opetition and evolve in their

    relationships, they generate positive impacts for each other and

    the entire industry. While firms can access the knowledge and

    resourcesof partners andshare the risksand costs, competitor part-

    ners benchmark each other and prepare for the consequences of

    competition (Tsai, 2002)as well as foster a competitive culture for

    developing distinctive competencies (Luo et al., 2007).The S-LCD

    case clearly shows that two rival firms got benefits from the co-

    opetitive relationship (refer toFigs. 2 and 3).Further, co-opetition

    between giants impacts the whole industry,in terms of technologi-

    cal development and competitive dynamics. The S-LCD case shows

    that co-opetition between leading firms influenced subsequent

    co-opetition among other major players led to possible group-

    to-group competition. The new industry competitive landscape

    shaped by firms engaged in co-opetition facilitates further inno-

    vation, thus providing support forSchumpeters (1942)argument

    that innovative performance is enhanced when a small number of

    large firms vigorously compete with each other to develop new

    processes and products.

    Our conceptual model also illuminates the importance of firm

    capabilities in managingco-opetition. Co-opetition between strong

    rivals is a very challenging relationship (Gnyawali et al., 2008)as

    managers confront higher levels of tension, risk loss of knowl-

    edge to a competitor-partner, and might subsequently turn a

    weak competitor-partner into a strong competitor. Managers

    ability to anticipate and manage such a relationship by deal-

    ing with the paradoxical factors in co-opetition would therefore

    be important in managing co-opetition and generating posi-tive outcomes (Gnyawali et al., 2006). As evidenced in the

    S-LCD case, co-opetition mindset of executives was critical for

    the formation of co-opetition. In addition, superior and com-

    plementary resources and balance of such resources between

    the partners were critical for firms to develop their relation-

    ship in a more balanced way, to maintain interdependence, and

    subsequently generate substantial positive outcomes from the

    relationship.

    5.1. Contributions

    This study contributes to bothco-opetitionand innovation liter-

    atures. First, we contribute to the innovation literature by showing

  • 8/10/2019 Co-opetition Between Giants- Collaboration With

    10/14

    D.R. Gnyawali, B.-J. Park / Research Policy 40 (2011) 650663 659

    the need for and implications of co-opetition for technological

    innovation. While the role of strategic alliances on innovation has

    been extensively studied (Ahuja, 2000; Powell et al., 1996), lit-

    tle is known about how co-opetition might impact innovation.

    We showed that co-opetition is extremely challenging yet nec-

    essary in addressing major technological changes. The win-win

    outcomes from the exemplar case demonstrated how co-opetition

    between giants could be instrumental for technological innova-

    tion. Such positive outcomes are motivating factors for firms to

    actively consider co-opetition as a viable strategy for technolog-

    ical advancements. Second, our study explains why and how the

    most intense and challenging form of co-opetition could occur,

    evolve, and impact the participating firms and the entire indus-

    try. We have offered an integrative framework of drivers, process,

    and outcomes of co-opetition (Fig. 6), which is expected to provide

    a strong foundation for further research on this topic. Third, as a

    part of development of the conceptual framework, we developed

    the concept of co-opetition capability and demonstrated its critical

    role in the formation and evolution of co-opetition, and, in turn,

    value creation and value appropriation. This co-opetition capabil-

    ity is very important in understanding how firms could anticipate

    and manage the benefits and risks in co-opetition and, therefore,

    create higher value and appropriate a greater share from the value.

    Executives with a co-opetition mindset are more likely to pursuethe opportunities and could manage the complicated relationship

    in positive ways and create greater value. Firms with co-opetition

    capability could also manage the relationship with partners in

    a more balanced way, which is critical for interdependence and

    continued partnership. Fourth, we showed that co-opetition does

    have positive impact on the entire industry. The leading firms

    engagement in co-opetition by cooperating in the up-stream (LCD

    panel development and production) while fiercely competing in

    the downstream TV market led to the advancement of the tech-

    nology, creation of greater demand for large flat screen TVs, and

    increase of customers welfare through better quality products

    with reasonable prices. Moreover, we showed that co-opetition

    between leading firms led to subsequent co-opetition among other

    firms, which might result in group-to-group competition. Suchdynamic changes of industry landscapes in high-tech industries

    may cause inter-firm relationships complex and unstable, which

    can be a significant barrier to collusion. That is, collaboration in

    upstream, including R&D, technological innovation, and develop-

    ment of key devices, and competition in the downstream aspect

    of the value chain could be beneficial to consumers by improving

    the value of market offerings and by lowering prices. Finally, and

    as a result of the above, our research suggests that public policy

    makers and anti-trust regulators would need to develop a more

    nuanced understanding of co-opetition and its implications before

    dismissing it as simple end-market collusion that undeniably hurts

    consumers.

    5.2. Limitations and directions for future research

    This study has some limitations that also offer opportunities

    for future research. First, our case study focused on only one case

    within an industry and thereforethe findings should be interpreted

    with caution and need to be tested through large scale empirical

    studies. Second, while we focused on the positive effects of co-

    opetition, co-opetition could have downsides as well which need

    to be investigated in future research. Co-opetition between leading

    firms hasthe potentialto push an inferior technology to the market

    and set that as the standard, especially when the degree of compe-

    tition between partners is weak. These downsides are even more

    likely in a concentratedindustry, i.e.,an industrydominated by only

    a fewlargeplayers.Third, at this stage of ourstudy, we were unable

    to disentangle competition and collaboration at domestic versus

    global markets. While cross-national co-opetition is more com-

    plex than domestic one, cross-national co-opetition with global

    scope may offer more opportunities than domestic ones do. Future

    researchers could compare two different cases, one global and one

    domestic, to draw similarities and differences. Fourth, our case

    study depended mainly on secondary data. Although we could

    obtain ample dataof the exemplar caseand generatedinsights from

    the secondary data, future research could conduct interviews and

    collect first-hand data to generate insights on the management of

    co-opetition and the role of firm capability. Finally, future research

    could examine our arguments and the model through large scale

    empirical studies. Building on the conceptual arguments and find-

    ings in this study, future research could develop and conduct

    empiricalstudies related to the drivers, dynamics, andoutcomes of

    co-opetition.

    5.3. Managerial implications

    Our study helps managers to better understand how com-

    panies use co-opetition strategy to deal with rapidly changing

    technological environment. Leading firms need to consider co-

    opetitionto pursue opportunities(e.g. technologicalstandards) and

    deal with threats stemming from environmental changes. Whenleading firms engage in co-opetition, other firms also need to

    consider co-opetition with other competitors. Our research also

    underscores the need for firms to develop co-opetition capabil-

    ities in order to create value and capture a greater share from

    the created value. Based on the findings of this paper, we sug-

    gest that firms in high-tech industries need to explicitly consider

    co-opetition as part of their strategy tool set. Just as strate-

    gists think about how to outcompete a rival in their industry

    (competitive strategy) and about how to pursue and manage

    collaborations (cooperative strategy), they need to pursue ways

    in which they can simultaneously engage in collaboration and

    competition with other firms in the industry. Overall, this paper

    provides a framework for researchers to more systematically

    examine co-opetition and its implications and equips managerswith a set of important concepts and approaches they could use

    in their attempt to create competitive advantages through co-

    opetition.

    In conclusion, while prior research has recognized the

    importance of co-opetition for technological innovation (e.g.

    Quintana-Garca and Benavides-Velasco, 2004; Teece, 1992; Von

    Hippel, 1987), we know little about what induces co-opetition,

    how it evolves, and how it might generate positive innovation

    effects. Further, co-opetition research has not examined how

    firms manage the paradoxical relationship and how firm capa-

    bility influences the dynamics and outcomes of co-opetition.

    We hope that our examination of both ex ante drivers and ex

    post evolution and outcomes of co-opetition between leading

    firms has provided an important foundation for future concep-tual and empirical research on this very important and evolving

    topic.

    Acknowledgements

    We thank the anonymous reviewers and the editor for their

    helpful comments and suggestions. An earlier version of this

    research was presented at the 2008 EIASM Workshop on Co-

    opetition Strategy: Stretching the Boundaries of Co-opetition held

    in Madrid, Spain, and received the Best Paper Award. This paper

    also benefited from the feedback received from thepanel at the 5th

    Annual Mid-Atlantic Strategy Colloquium held at the University of

    Maryland, USA, in November 2010.

  • 8/10/2019 Co-opetition Between Giants- Collaboration With

    11/14

    660 D.R. Gnyawali, B.-J. Park / Research Policy 40 (2011) 650663

    Appendix A. Summary quotes from Factiva news reports on key drivers of S-LCD formation

    Date Source Quotes Drivers

    October 17 03 Nikkei The agreement with Samsung will enable Sony to

    comprehensively address flat-panel and picture-quality

    technologies,fostering speedier improvementin its

    product line.

    Shorten development

    time

    June 1 07 Nikkei Weekly The ability to expand production capacity quicklywhen a

    business opportunity presents itself is essential in the LCD

    business.Septemb er 23 03 Wall Street Journal . . .Sony said it wanted its own line of large LCD panels, but

    . . .seek an alliance rather than come up with the

    estimated$2 billionan LCD plant would cost.

    Massive R&D and

    Capital Expenditure

    July 15 04 Yonhap English News It is hard to invest in large-scale LCD facilities alone,

    and it holds a lot of attraction to make investment in a

    place of strong infrastructure like this, said Idei. As

    Toyota gets steel from outside, Sony will secure LCD

    supplies. . .

    October 17 03 Reuters It costs $3 billion to make a new LCD line and the

    cooperation is toshare benefits and risks and to

    maximize synergies, Samsungs Chu told reporters

    Cost sharing and risk

    reduction

    March 8 04 Dow Jones For Samsung, which is already one of the worlds biggest

    manufacturers of liquid-crystal displays, the deal secures

    extra investment money as well as a big customerin a

    flat-panel TV market . . .

    September 3 04 Nikkei Report . . .more electronics manufacturers are allying with each

    other toshare the cost of building new plants making

    LCD panels . . .and semiconductors.

    October 23 06 Dow Jones Newswires Panel makers are spending a lot of money on big

    factories. Its very important for them to maximize

    utilization so if they can align with a TV brand to

    guarantee some percentage of their supply, they are

    much better off, said Ross Young, president and founder

    of DisplaySearch.

    July 14 04 AFX UK Focus The cooperation . . .offers an opportunity to lead the

    rapidly growing LCD TV market and standardization of

    glass substrate and LCD TV sizes, president and CEO of

    Samsung Electronics LCD business SW Lee said.

    Pursue industry leading

    position/Industry

    standard

    July 16 04 Nikkei Report Industry standard: S-LCD aims to usethis position to take

    the initiative indevising industry standardsfor image

    resolutions and sizes, Yun Jong-yong, deputy chairman

    and chief executive officer of Samsung Electronics.

    August 28 07 Business Wire We haveremained a step ahead of the competition in

    terms of production scale and timing, said Won-Kie

    Chang, CEO of S-LCD. Our sights are now on LCD TVs inthe 50-inch class and we aim to lead that segment .

    November 22 05 AP Newswires Sony fell behind rivals in liquid crystal displays, and the

    JV with Samsung was a way for it to ensure a stable panel

    supply for its newer TV models.

    Vulnerability

    December 2 05 AP Newswires Sonys relianceon Samsung to produce the display panels

    showshow far behindthe Japanese company, once the

    industrys king, has fallen. . .

    January 3 06 The Wall Street Journal When Sony considered a joint venture with Samsung

    around 2003, itsTV business was in serious trouble. . .

    Samsung had developed a huge lead in the LCD technology

    while Sony lagged behind

    February 9 07 Nikkei Report In the past, Sony was proud of standing alone in product

    development. . .But to catch up with its rivals in the digital

    age, the company finally changed course, joining hands

    with Samsung Electronics Co. in LCD production.Faced

    withthe need to introduce a never-ending supply of

    advanced products, Sonys collaboration with othercompanies will likely continue to expand in the future.

    April 24 03 Joins.com Samsung executives reportedly found they had much to

    learn from Sonys technical know-how and global

    marketing skills.

    Partners technological

    capability

    October 17 03 Reuters Samsung would be the best choice, given itsability to

    supply a large amount of high-quality panels in a stable

    manner

    October 17 03 Asahi Shimbun News With the new partnership,Sony expects to capitalize on

    the technological prowess of Samsung, the worlds

    leading LCD manufacturer.

    July 16 04 Nikkei Report The alliance . . .is ideal because it combines our abilities

    to develop large LCD panels into flat-panel TVs and

    market them.

  • 8/10/2019 Co-opetition Between Giants- Collaboration With

    12/14

    D.R. Gnyawali, B.-J. Park / Research Policy 40 (2011) 650663 661

    Appendix B. Summary quotes from Factiva news reports on the dynamics of co-opetition

    Date Source Quotes Process

    January 3 06 The Wall Street Journal The new alliances dont come without conflict. Inside Sony, some engineers

    worried that Samsung will eventually use Sonys TV expertise to beat the

    Japanese company. At Samsung, some executives wondered whether its smart

    to help such a big rival . . .Executives at both companies had concerns about

    working so closely with a direct rival. Would this joint venture help us, as a

    company that is competing in the TV sector? Mr. Chang recalls wondering.

    Internal conflicts

    July 11 08 The Japan Times Sony, other firms team up to develop organic displays: Sony Corp. and nineother domestic companies have decided to jointly develop with government

    support technology by 2013 to mass produce large energy-efficient organic

    flat-panel screens.

    Competition for newtechnology and

    products

    July 16 08 The Korea Herald Samsung companies join for OLED venture: Samsung Electronics Co. and its

    display affiliate Samsung SDI Co. are moving to set up a joint venture for

    organic displays. . .

    September 24 09 The Nikkei Weekly Samsung ridesLED-backlitTVs to the bank: . . .referring to LED TVs, the

    name Samsung has coined for its LCD TVs that use white light-emitting diodes

    instead of fluorescent tubes for the backlight . . .Samsung succeeded in

    building an image of itself as a company with strong environmental

    technologies. . .

    January 8 10 Korea Times Korean, Japanese TV GiantsRenew Rivalry in 3D: Major manufacturers such

    as Samsung Electronics, LG Electronics, and Sony have announced plans to sell

    3D televisions to consumers in 2010. . .

    February 27 08 Korea Times Challenge or Opportunity? Samsung Electronics . . .is concerned over a

    partnership between Sony and Sharp. The two Japanese firms announced a

    plan to team up to make flat panels for LCD television. . . .It can be interpreted

    that efforts by Japanese companies to check the rise of their Korean rivals have

    allegedly forced Sony to join hands with Sharp.

    Cooperation with another rival

    January 3 06 The Wall Street Journal . . .Mr. Murayama . . .concedes that Samsung could eventually use Sonys

    technology to compete against him. But he adds that in consumer electronics,

    its hard to keep secrets long anyway, and being open with Samsung is key to

    making the joint venture work. If we put up barriers, theyll close up too,

    he says.

    Open-minded/win-win approach

    November 29 06 Business Week Online Our alliance with Sony allowed us to benefit from a virtuous circle: Bravias

    success boosted sales of LCD panels, and volume meant lower costs which fed

    greater sales of LCD TVs, says Cho Yeong Duk, vice-president at Samsung.

    January 18 07 Business Week Online At leastSonys success isnt necessarily bad news for Samsung. The two have

    a joint venture in LCD panels, which means Sonys gains also benefit its Korean

    partner.

    Appendix C. Summary quotes from Factiva news reports on the outcomes of co-opetition

    Date Source Quotes Outcomes

    Octo ber 29 03 New Yor k Tim es The all iance.. sh ould lead th e way t owardstandardizing the global TV

    monitor format, the companies saidIndustry:

    Standardization battle

    between LCD and PDP

    TVs

    July 15 04 Dow Jones Intl News The cooperation offers an opportunity to lead the rapidly growing LCD TV

    market andstandardization of glass substrate and LCD TV sizes, S.W. Lee,

    president and chief executive of Samsungs LCD business said. . .

    November 29 06 Business Week Online The alliance has also had an industry-wide impact, especially in the TV

    market for sets in the 40-inch screen class. The large screen segment had

    been dominated by plasma TVs until S-LCD started providing LCD screens . . .

    In thethird quarter of 2006, . . .for the first timeovertook plasma TV sets. . .

    August 21 07 Dow Jones Newswires Currently, PDP technology is well suited for big flat TV panel of over 40 inches,

    butits competitive edge in that segment has been slipping as large LCD

    screens become cheaper to produce.

    September 22 03 Joins.com A sense of alarm that they cannot survive without cooperation seems to have

    encouraged Samsung and Sony to come together, the industry official said.

    There will bemore alliances among rivalsto ensure mutual survival.

    Industry: More

    alliances among other

    competitorsOctober 20 03 Nikkei Weekly Sonys move from being a corporate customer to a producer will likelyforce

    smaller LCD makers into alliances.

    June 30 04 Asia Pulse As competition increases in the market, the companies will try to increase

    their shares bycooperating with each other. Its a trend that can be seen in

    other countries as well, an industry official said.

    July 15 04 AFX Asia He said that increased production of LCD panels will result in lower prices

    and in turn boost demand for LCD TVs . . .Industry: Price decline

    July 15 04 AFX Asia We are highly positive about our businesses outlook.If LCD TV prices fall to

    levels, the LCD TV market will grow and the oversupply will change to a

    supply shortage, Chang said.

    August 29 07 The Electronic Times In response, Samsung SDI announced that it developed the worlds first

    50-inch Full HD PDP using single scan technology . . .This technology enables

    to reduce the manufacturing costas much as 30 percent . . .

    Industry:

    Technological

    developmentSeptember 20 07 The Korea Herald To win over LCD TVs,PDP TVs have evolved in technology, as well.

    June 25 07 The Korea Herald Samsung Electronics will create various app lications to meet the demand and

    become a market creator rather than a market leader,Common: Market

    creation

  • 8/10/2019 Co-opetition Between Giants- Collaboration With

    13/14

    662 D.R. Gnyawali, B.-J. Park / Research Policy 40 (2011) 650663

    Appendix C (Continued)

    Date Source Quotes Outcomes

    June 13 05 Nikkei Weekly . . .the steep drop in LCD panel prices has made the retail cost of computer LCD

    monitors andLCD TVs seem more reasonable to consumers, and this has

    begun to stimulate demand.

    November 5 06 AP Newswires We created the 40-inch LCD TV market with Sony . . .Sonys role in opening

    that market and realizing growth in the market . . .is important.

    September 3 07 Korea Times According to DisplaySearch, the competition between LCD and PDP makers

    would boost the demand for 50-inch LCDs. . .

    July 16 04 Korea The cooperation between Samsung and Sony is awin-win situationfor both

    companies, said Chang Won-kie, President and CEO of S-LCD Corp.Common: Win-win

    outcome

    November 29 06 Herald Business Week Online The Sony-Samsung alliance is certainlya win-win, declares Sang Wan Lee,

    president of Samsungs LCD unit.

    January 3 06 The Wall Street Journal Mr. Chang (Samsung executive) says . . .competition with Sony is helping

    Samsung hone its own TVdesigns.Private: Better product

    development

    November 28 06 Business week . . .says Cho Yeong Duk, vice-president at Samsung in charge of the companys

    LCD business strategy. The rivalry with Sony also helped Samsung to bring

    outbetter LCD productsto the market, he said.

    References

    Abernathy, W.J., Clark, K.B., 1985. Innovationmapping the winds of creative

    destruction. Research Policy 14 (1), 322.Ahuja, G., 2000. Collaboration networks, structural holes, and innovation: a longi-tudinal study. Administrative Science Quarterly 45 (3), 425455.

    Ahuja, G., Katila, R., 2001. Technological acquisitions and the innovation perfor-mance of acquiring firms: a longitudinal study. Strategic Management Journal22 (3), 197220.

    Ahuja, G., Lampert, C.M., Tandon, V., 2008. Moving beyond Schumpeter: manage-ment research on the determinants of technological innovation. The Academyof Management Annals 2 (1), 198.

    Bengtsson, M., Eriksson, J., Wincent, J., 2010. Coopetition: new ideas for a newparadigm. In: Yami, S., Castaldo, S., Dagnino, G.B., Le Roy, F. (Eds.), Coopetition:Winning Strategies for the 21st Century. Edward Elgar, Northampton, MA, pp.1939.

    Bengtsson, M.,Kock, S.,1999. Cooperation andcompetition in relationshipsbetweencompetitors in business networks. Journal of Business and Industrial Marketing14 (3), 178190.

    Bengtsson, M., Kock, S., 2000. Coopetition in business networksto cooper-ate and compete simultaneously. Industrial Marketing Management 29 (5),411426.

    Brandenburger, A.M., Nalebuff, B.J., 1996. Co-opetition. Doubleday, New York.Chang,S.J., 2008.Sony vs. Samsung: TheInside Story of theElectronics Giants Battle

    for Global Supremacy. John Wiley & Sons (Asia) Pte. Ltd., Singapore.Chen, M.J., 2008. Reconceptualizing the competition-cooperation relation-

    ship: a transparadox perspective. Journal of Management Inquiry 17 (4),288305.

    Chen,M.J., Su, K.H., Tsai,W., 2007. Competitivetension: the awareness-motivation-capability perspective. Academy of Management Journal 50 (1), 101118.

    Chen, R., Li, M., 1999. Strategic alliances and new product development: an empiri-cal study of the US semiconductor start-up firms. Advances in CompetitivenessResearch 7 (1), 3561.

    Dagnino, G., Padula, G., 2002. Coopetition strategy: a new kind of interfirm dynam-ics for value creation. In: Proceedings of the EURAM The European Academyof Management Second Annual Conference Innovative Research in Manage-ment Stockholm , May 2002, pp. 911.

    Dagnino, G., Rocco, E., 2009. Introductioncoopetition strategy. In: Dagnino, D.,Rocco, E. (Eds.), Coopetition Strategy. Routledge, New York, pp. 121.

    Das, T.K., Teng, B.S., 2000. A resource-based theory of strategic alliances. Journal ofManagement 26 (1), 3161.

    Dodgson,M., Mathews,J., Kastelle,T., Hu,M.C., 2008.The evolvingnature ofTaiwansnational innovation system: the case of biotechnology innovation networks.Research Policy 37, 430445.

    Dvorak, P., Ramstad, E., 2006. TV marriage: behind SonySamsung rivalry, anunlikely alliance developselectronicsgiantsjoin forceson flat-paneltechnology.The Wall Street Journal (January 3), A1.

    Dyer, J.H., Singh, H., 1998. The relational view: cooperative strategy and sources ofinterorganizational competitive advantage. Academy of Management Review23 (4), 660679.

    Eisenhardt, K.M., 1989. Building theories from case study research. Academy ofManagement Review 14 (4), 532550.

    Garud, R., 1994. Cooperative and competitive behaviors during the process of cre-ative destruction. Research Policy 23 (4), 385394.

    Gnyawali, D.R., He, J., Madhavan, R., 2008. Co-Opetition: promises and challenges.In: Wankel, C. (Ed.), 21st Century Management: A Reference Handbook. SagePublications, Thousand Oaks, CA, pp. 386398.

    Gnyawali, D.R.,Madhavan, R., 2001. Cooperativenetworksand competitivedynam-ics: a structural embeddedness perspective. Academy of Management Review

    26 (3), 431445.

    Gnyawali, D.R., He, J.Y., Madhavan, R., 2006. Impact of co-opetition on firm com-petitive behavior: An empirical examination. Journal of Management 32 (4),507530.

    Gnyawali, D.R., Park, B.J., 2009. Co-opetition and technological innovation in smalland medium-sized enterprises: a multilevel conceptual model. Journal of SmallBusiness Management 47 (3), 308330.

    Gomes-Casseres, B., 1994. Group versus group: how alliance networks compete.Harvard Business Review 72 (4), 6274.

    Harbison, J.R., Pekar Jr., P., 1998. Smart Alliances. Jossey-Bass, San Francisco.Ingram, P., Yue, L.Q., 2008. Structure, affect and identity as bases of organiza-

    tional competition and cooperation. The Academy of ManagementAnnals 2 (1),275303.

    Jorde, T.M., Teece, D.J., 1990. Innovation and cooperation: implications for compe-tition and antitrust. The Journal of Economic Perspective 4 (3), 7596.

    Kim, B.W., 2006. Samsung vs. Sony. Seoul Media, Seoul, Korea, written in Korean.Lado, A.A., Boyd, N.G., Hanlon, S.C., 1997. Competition, cooperation, and the search

    foreconomic rents:a syncreticmodel. Academy of Management Review22 (1),110141.

    Langley, A., 1999. Strategies for theorizing from process data. Academy of Manage-ment Review 24 (4), 691710.

    Lavie, D., 2007. Alliance portfolios and firm performance: a study of value creationand appropriation in the US software industry. Strategic Management Journal

    28, 11871212.Lei, D., 2003. Competition, cooperation and learning: the new dynamics of strat-

    egy and organization design for the innovation net. International Journal ofTechnology Management 26 (7), 694716.

    Luh, S.S., 2003. Business the Sony Way: Secrets of the Worlds Most InnovativeElectronics Giant. John Wiley & Sons, Oxford.

    Luo,X., Rindfleisch, A., Tse,D.K., 2007.Workingwith rivals: theimpact of competitoralliances on financial performance. Journal of MarketingResearch44 (1),7383.

    Luo, Y., 2004. Co-opetition in International Business. Copenhagen Business SchoolPress, Copenhagen, Denmark.

    Luo, Y., 2007. A coopetition perspective of global competition. Journal of WorldBusiness 42 (2), 129144.

    Lynn,G.S.,Akgn, A.E.,1998. Innovationstrategiesunder uncertainty: a contingencyapproach for new product development. Engineering Management Journal 10(3), 1117.

    Mione, A., 2008. When entrepreneurship requires co-opetition: the need of normsto create a market. In: Proceedings of the3rd Workshopon Coopetition Strategyof the European Institute for Advanced Studies in Management , Madrid, Spain.

    Oxley, J.E., 1997. Appropriability hazards and governance in strategic alliances: a

    transaction cost approach. Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 13 (2),387409.

    Oxley, J.E., Sampson, R.C., 2004. The scope and governance of international R&Dalliances. Strategic Management Journal 25 (89), 723749.

    Palmberg, C., Martikainen, O., 2006. Diversification in response to ICTconvergenceindigenous capabilities versus R&D alliances of the Finnishtelecom industry. The Journal of Policy, Regulation and Strategy forTelecommunications, Information and Media 8 (4), 6784.

    Park, S.H., Russo, M.V., 1996. When competition eclipses cooperation: anevent history analysis of joint venture failure. Management Science 42 (6),875890.

    Pfeffer, J., Salancik, G.R., 1978. The External Control of Organizations: A ResourceDependence Perspective. Harper & Row, New York.

    Powell, W.W., Koput, K.W., Smith-Doerr, L., 1996. Interorganizational collaborationand the locusof innovation: networks of learning in biotechnology.Administra-tive Science Quarterly 41 (1), 116144.

    Quintana-Garca, C., Benavides-Velasco, C., 2004. Cooperation, competition, andinnovative capability: a panel data of European dedicated biotechnology firms.

    Technovation 24 (12), 927938.

  • 8/10/2019 Co-opetition Between Giants- Collaboration With

    14/14

    D.R. Gnyawali, B.-J. Park / Research Policy 40 (2011) 650663 663

    Ritala, P., Hurmelinna-Laukkanen, P., 2009. Whats in it for me? Creating andappropriating value in innovation-related coopetition. Technovation 29 (12),819828.

    Ritala, P., Hurmelinna-Laukkanen, P., Blomqvist, K., 2009. Tug of war ininnovationcoopetitive service development. International Journal of ServicesTechnology and Management 12 (3), 255272.

    Sampson, R.C., 2004. The cost of misaligned governance in R&D alliances. Journal ofLaw, Economics and Organization 20 (2), 484526.

    Sampson, R.C., 2007. R&D alliances and firm performance: the impact of tech-nological diversity and alliance organization on innovation. The Academy ofManagement Journal 50 (2), 364386.

    Schumpeter, J.A., 1942. Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy. Harper & Brothers,New York.

    Teece, D.J.,1992. Competition, cooperation, and innovation: organizational arrange-ments forregimesof rapidtechnologicalprogress. Journal of EconomicBehavior& Organization 18 (1), 125.

    Teece, D.J, 1996. Firm organization, industrial structure, and technological innova-tion. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 31 (2), 193224.

    Tether, B.S., 2002. Who co-operates for innovation, and why: an empirical analysis.Research Policy 31 (6), 947967.

    Tsai, W.P., 2002. Social structure of coopetition within a multiunit organization:coordination, competition, and intraorganizational knowledge sharing. Organi-zation Science 13 (2), 179190.

    Tsai, K.-H., 2009. Collaborative networks and product innovation performance:toward a contingency perspective. Research Policy 38 (5), 765778.

    Utterback, J.M., Suarez, F.F., 1993. Innovation, competition, and industry structure.Research Policy 22 (1), 121.

    Von Hippel, E., 1987. Cooperation between rivals: informal know-how trading.Research Policy 16, 291302.

    Walley, K., 2007. Coopetition: an introduction to the subject and an agenda forresearch. International Studies of Management & Organization 37 (2), 1131.

    Yami, S., Castaldo, S., Dagnino, G.B., Le Roy, F., 2010. Editors introduction. In: Yami,S., Castaldo, S., Dagnino, G.B., Le Roy, F. (Eds.), Coopetition: Winning Strategiesfor the 21st Century. Edward Elgar, Northampton, MA, pp. 116.

    Yin, R., 1984. Case Study Research. Sage Publications, Beverly Hills, CA.Zineldin, M., 2004. Co-opetition: the organization of the future. Marketing Intelli-

    gence & Planning 22 (7), 780789.

    BIS (UK Department for Business, Innovation & Skills), 2009. The 2009 R&D Score-board.http://www.innovation.gov.uk/rd scoreboard(accessed 20.11.10).

    Samsung Electronics Co., Ltd., 2007. Samsung Electronics Annual Report 2006.http://www.samsung.com/us/aboutsamsung/corporateprofile/download/AnnualReport 2006 Eng.pdf(accessed 25,1,11).

    Sony Corporation, 2004. Sony Annual Report 2004. http://www.sony.net/SonyInfo/IR/financial/ar/2004/qfhh7c000000g7xm-att/SonyAR04-E.pdf(accessed 25,1,11).

    Sony Corporation, 2008. Sony Annual Report 2008. http://www.sony.net/SonyInfo/IR/financial/ar/2008/qfhh7c00000htn6x-att/SonyAR08-E.pdf(accessed 25,1,11).

    Uranaka, T., 2003.Sony unveils massive restructuring plans. The JapanTimes Online(May29). http://search.japantimes.co.jp/cgi-bin/nb20030529a1.html(accessed20.11.10).

    http://www.innovation.gov.uk/rd_scoreboardhttp://www.samsung.com/us/aboutsamsung/corporateprofile/download/AnnualReport_2006_Eng.pdfhttp://www.samsung.com/us/aboutsamsung/corporateprofile/download/AnnualReport_2006_Eng.pdfhttp://www.sony.net/SonyInfo/IR/financial/ar/2004/qfhh7c000000g7xm-att/SonyAR04-E.pdfhttp://www.sony.net/SonyInfo/IR/financial/ar/2004/qfhh7c000000g7xm-att/SonyAR04-E.pdfhttp://www.sony.net/SonyInfo/IR/financial/ar/2008/qfhh7c00000htn6x-att/SonyAR08-E.pdfhttp://www.sony.net/SonyInfo/IR/financial/ar/2008/qfhh7c00000htn6x-att/SonyAR08-E.pdfhttp://search.japantimes.co.jp/cgi-bin/nb20030529a1.htmlhttp://search.japantimes.co.jp/cgi-bin/nb20030529a1.htmlhttp://www.sony.net/SonyInfo/IR/financial/ar/2008/qfhh7c00000htn6x-att/SonyAR08-E.pdfhttp://www.sony.net/SonyInfo/IR/financial/ar/2008/qfhh7c00000htn6x-att/SonyAR08-E.pdfhttp://www.sony.net/SonyInfo/IR/financial/ar/2004/qfhh7c000000g7xm-att/SonyAR04-E.pdfhttp://www.sony.net/SonyInfo/IR/financial/ar/2004/qfhh7c000000g7xm-att/SonyAR04-E.pdfhttp://www.samsung.com/us/aboutsamsung/corporateprofile/download/AnnualReport_2006_Eng.pdfhttp://www.samsung.com/us/aboutsamsung/corporateprofile/download/AnnualReport_2006_Eng.pdfhttp://www.innovation.gov.uk/rd_scoreboard