Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both...

99
Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods

Transcript of Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both...

Page 1: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Chapter Thirty-Five

Public Goods

Page 2: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Public Goods -- Definition

A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption.

– Nonexcludable -- all consumers can consume the good.

– Nonrival -- each consumer can consume all of the good.

Page 3: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Public Goods -- Examples

Broadcast radio and TV programs. National defense. Public highways. Reductions in air pollution. National parks.

Page 4: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Reservation Prices

A consumer’s reservation price for a unit of a good is his maximum willingness-to-pay for it.

Consumer’s wealth is Utility of not having the good isU w( , ).0

w.

Page 5: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Reservation Prices

A consumer’s reservation price for a unit of a good is his maximum willingness-to-pay for it.

Consumer’s wealth is Utility of not having the good is Utility of paying p for the good is

U w( , ).0w.

U w p( , ). 1

Page 6: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Reservation Prices

A consumer’s reservation price for a unit of a good is his maximum willingness-to-pay for it.

Consumer’s wealth is Utility of not having the good is Utility of paying p for the good is

Reservation price r is defined by

U w( , ).0w.

U w p( , ). 1

U w U w r( , ) ( , ).0 1

Page 7: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Reservation Prices; An ExampleConsumer’s utility is U x x x x( , ) ( ).1 2 1 2 1 Utility of not buying a unit of good 2 is

V wwp

wp

( , ) ( ) .0 0 11 1

Utility of buying one unit of good 2 atprice p is

V w pw pp

w pp

( , ) ( )( )

.

1 1 12

1 1

Page 8: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Reservation Prices; An ExampleReservation price r is defined by

V w V w r( , ) ( , )0 1 I.e. by

wp

w rp

rw

1 1

22

( )

.

Page 9: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

When Should a Public Good Be Provided?

One unit of the good costs c. Two consumers, A and B. Individual payments for providing

the public good are gA and gB.

gA + gB c if the good is to be provided.

Page 10: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

When Should a Public Good Be Provided?

Payments must be individually rational; i.e.

andU w U w gA A A A A( , ) ( , )0 1

U w U w gB B B B B( , ) ( , ).0 1

Page 11: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

When Should a Public Good Be Provided?

Payments must be individually rational; i.e.

and

Therefore, necessarily and

U w U w gA A A A A( , ) ( , )0 1

U w U w gB B B B B( , ) ( , ).0 1

g rA A g rB B .

Page 12: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

When Should a Public Good Be Provided?

And ifand

then it is Pareto-improving to supply the unit of good

U w U w gA A A A A( , ) ( , )0 1

U w U w gB B B B B( , ) ( , )0 1

Page 13: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

When Should a Public Good Be Provided?

And ifand

then it is Pareto-improving to supply the unit of good, so is sufficient for it to be efficient to supply the good.

U w U w gA A A A A( , ) ( , )0 1

U w U w gB B B B B( , ) ( , )0 1

r r cA B

Page 14: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Private Provision of a Public Good?

Suppose and . Then A would supply the good even

if B made no contribution. B then enjoys the good for free; free-

riding.

r cA r cB

Page 15: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Private Provision of a Public Good?

Suppose and . Then neither A nor B will supply the

good alone.

r cA r cB

Page 16: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Private Provision of a Public Good?

Suppose and . Then neither A nor B will supply the

good alone. Yet, if also, then it is Pareto-

improving for the good to be supplied.

r cA r cB

r r cA B

Page 17: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Private Provision of a Public Good?

Suppose and . Then neither A nor B will supply the

good alone. Yet, if also, then it is Pareto-

improving for the good to be supplied. A and B may try to free-ride on each

other, causing no good to be supplied.

r cA r cB

r r cA B

Page 18: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Free-Riding

Suppose A and B each have just two actions -- individually supply a public good, or not.

Cost of supply c = $100. Payoff to A from the good = $80. Payoff to B from the good = $65.

Page 19: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Free-Riding

Suppose A and B each have just two actions -- individually supply a public good, or not.

Cost of supply c = $100. Payoff to A from the good = $80. Payoff to B from the good = $65. $80 + $65 > $100, so supplying the

good is Pareto-improving.

Page 20: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Free-Riding

-$20, -$35 -$20, $65

$100, -$35 $0, $0

Buy

Don’tBuy

BuyDon’tBuy

Player A

Player B

Page 21: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Free-Riding

-$20, -$35 -$20, $65

$100, -$35 $0, $0

Buy

Don’tBuy

BuyDon’tBuy

Player A

Player B

(Don’t’ Buy, Don’t Buy) is the unique NE.

Page 22: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Free-Riding

-$20, -$35 -$20, $65

$100, -$35 $0, $0

Buy

Don’tBuy

BuyDon’tBuy

Player A

Player B

But (Don’t’ Buy, Don’t Buy) is inefficient.

Page 23: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Free-Riding

Now allow A and B to make contributions to supplying the good.

E.g. A contributes $60 and B contributes $40.

Payoff to A from the good = $40 > $0. Payoff to B from the good = $25 > $0.

Page 24: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Free-Riding

$20, $25 -$60, $0

$0, -$40 $0, $0

Contribute

Don’tContribute

ContributeDon’tContribute

Player A

Player B

Page 25: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Free-Riding

$20, $25 -$60, $0

$0, -$40 $0, $0

Contribute

Don’tContribute

ContributeDon’tContribute

Player A

Player B

Two NE: (Contribute, Contribute) and (Don’t Contribute, Don’t Contribute).

Page 26: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Free-Riding

So allowing contributions makes possible supply of a public good when no individual will supply the good alone.

But what contribution scheme is best?

And free-riding can persist even with contributions.

Page 27: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Variable Public Good Quantities

E.g. how many broadcast TV programs, or how much land to include into a national park.

Page 28: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Variable Public Good Quantities

E.g. how many broadcast TV programs, or how much land to include into a national park.

c(G) is the production cost of G units of public good.

Two individuals, A and B. Private consumptions are xA, xB.

Page 29: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Variable Public Good Quantities

Budget allocations must satisfyx x c G w wA B A B ( ) .

Page 30: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Variable Public Good Quantities

Budget allocations must satisfy

MRSA & MRSB are A & B’s marg. rates of substitution between the private and public goods.

Pareto efficiency condition for public good supply is

x x c G w wA B A B ( ) .

MRS MRS MCA B ( ).G

Page 31: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Variable Public Good Quantities

Pareto efficiency condition for public good supply is

Why?MRS MRS MCA B ( ).G

Page 32: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Variable Public Good Quantities

Pareto efficiency condition for public good supply is

Why? The public good is nonrival in

consumption, so 1 extra unit of public good is fully consumed by both A and B.

MRS MRS MCA B ( ).G

Page 33: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Variable Public Good Quantities

Suppose MRSA is A’s utility-preserving

compensation in private good units for a one-unit reduction in public good.

Similarly for B.

MRS MRS MCA B ( ).G

Page 34: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Variable Public Good Quantities

is the total payment to A & B of private good that preserves both utilities if G is lowered by 1 unit.

MRS MRSA B

Page 35: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Variable Public Good Quantities

is the total payment to A & B of private good that preserves both utilities if G is lowered by 1 unit.

Since , making 1 less public good unit releases more private good than the compensation payment requires Pareto-improvement from reduced G.

MRS MRS MCA B ( )G

MRS MRSA B

Page 36: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Variable Public Good Quantities

Now suppose MRS MRS MCA B ( ).G

Page 37: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Variable Public Good Quantities

Now suppose is the total payment

by A & B of private good that preserves both utilities if G is raised by 1 unit.

MRS MRS MCA B ( ).G

MRS MRSA B

Page 38: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Variable Public Good Quantities

Now suppose is the total payment

by A & B of private good that preserves both utilities if G is raised by 1 unit.

This payment provides more than 1 more public good unit Pareto-improvement from increased G.

MRS MRS MCA B ( ).G

MRS MRSA B

Page 39: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Variable Public Good Quantities

Hence, necessarily, efficient public good production requires

MRS MRS MCA B ( ).G

Page 40: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Variable Public Good Quantities

Hence, necessarily, efficient public good production requires

Suppose there are n consumers; i = 1,…,n. Then efficient public good production requires

MRS MRS MCA B ( ).G

MRS MCii

nG

1

( ).

Page 41: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Efficient Public Good Supply -- the Quasilinear Preferences Case

Two consumers, A and B. U x G x f G ii i i i( , ) ( ); , . A B

Page 42: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Efficient Public Good Supply -- the Quasilinear Preferences Case

Two consumers, A and B. Utility-maximization requires

U x G x f G ii i i i( , ) ( ); , . A BMRS f G ii i ( ); , .A B

MRSpp

f G p iiG

xi G ( ) ; , .A B

Page 43: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Efficient Public Good Supply -- the Quasilinear Preferences Case Two consumers, A and B. Utility-maximization requires

is i’s public good demand/marg. utility curve; i = A,B.

U x G x f G ii i i i( , ) ( ); , . A BMRS f G ii i ( ); , .A B

MRSpp

f G p iiG

xi G ( ) ; , .A B

p f GG i ( )

Page 44: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Efficient Public Good Supply -- the Quasilinear Preferences Case

MUA

MUB

pG

G

Page 45: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Efficient Public Good Supply -- the Quasilinear Preferences Case

MUA

MUB

MUA+MUB

pG

G

Page 46: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Efficient Public Good Supply -- the Quasilinear Preferences Case

pG

MUA

MUB

MUA+MUB

MC(G)

G

Page 47: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Efficient Public Good Supply -- the Quasilinear Preferences Case

G

pG

MUA

MUB

MUA+MUB

MC(G)

G*

Page 48: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Efficient Public Good Supply -- the Quasilinear Preferences Case

G

pG

MUA

MUB

MUA+MUB

MC(G)

G*

pG*

Page 49: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Efficient Public Good Supply -- the Quasilinear Preferences Case

G

pG

MUA

MUB

MUA+MUB

MC(G)

G*

pG*

p MU G MU GG* ( *) ( *) A B

Page 50: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Efficient Public Good Supply -- the Quasilinear Preferences Case

G

pG

MUA

MUB

MUA+MUB

MC(G)

G*

pG*

p MU G MU GG* ( *) ( *) A B

Efficient public good supply requires A & Bto state truthfully their marginal valuations.

Page 51: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Free-Riding Revisited

When is free-riding individually rational?

Page 52: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Free-Riding Revisited

When is free-riding individually rational?

Individuals can contribute only positively to public good supply; nobody can lower the supply level.

Page 53: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Free-Riding Revisited

When is free-riding individually rational?

Individuals can contribute only positively to public good supply; nobody can lower the supply level.

Individual utility-maximization may require a lower public good level.

Free-riding is rational in such cases.

Page 54: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Free-Riding Revisited

Given A contributes gA units of public good, B’s problem is

subject to

max,x gB B

U x g gB B A B( , )

x g w gB B B B , .0

Page 55: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Free-Riding Revisited

G

xB

gA

B’s budget constraint; slope = -1

Page 56: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Free-Riding Revisited

G

xB

gA

B’s budget constraint; slope = -1

gB 0

gB 0 is not allowed

Page 57: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Free-Riding Revisited

G

xB

gA

B’s budget constraint; slope = -1

gB 0

gB 0 is not allowed

Page 58: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Free-Riding Revisited

G

xB

gA

B’s budget constraint; slope = -1

gB 0

gB 0 is not allowed

Page 59: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Free-Riding Revisited

G

xB

gA

B’s budget constraint; slope = -1

gB 0

gB 0 is not allowedgB 0 (i.e. free-riding) is best for B

Page 60: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Demand Revelation

A scheme that makes it rational for individuals to reveal truthfully their private valuations of a public good is a revelation mechanism.

E.g. the Groves-Clarke taxation scheme.

How does it work?

Page 61: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Demand Revelation

N individuals; i = 1,…,N. All have quasi-linear preferences. vi is individual i’s true (private)

valuation of the public good. Individual i must provide ci private

good units if the public good is supplied.

Page 62: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Demand Revelation

ni = vi - ci is net value, for i = 1,…,N. Pareto-improving to supply the

public good if

v ci ii

N

i

N

11

Page 63: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Demand Revelation

ni = vi - ci is net value, for i = 1,…,N. Pareto-improving to supply the

public good if

v c ni i ii

N

i

N

i

N

0

111.

Page 64: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Demand Revelation

If and

or and

then individual j is pivotal; i.e. changes the supply decision.

nii j

N

0 n ni j

i j

N

0

nii j

N

0 n ni j

i j

N

0

Page 65: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Demand Revelation

What loss does a pivotal individual j inflict on others?

Page 66: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Demand Revelation

What loss does a pivotal individual j inflict on others?

If then is the loss.nii j

N

0,

nii j

N0

Page 67: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Demand Revelation

What loss does a pivotal individual j inflict on others?

If then is the loss.

If then is the loss.

nii j

N

0,

nii j

N0

nii j

N

0, ni

i j

N

0

Page 68: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Demand Revelation

For efficiency, a pivotal agent must face the full cost or benefit of her action.

The GC tax scheme makes pivotal agents face the full stated costs or benefits of their actions in a way that makes these statements truthful.

Page 69: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Demand Revelation

The GC tax scheme: Assign a cost ci to each individual. Each agent states a public good net

valuation, si. Public good is supplied if

otherwise not.

sii

N

01

;

Page 70: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Demand Revelation

A pivotal person j who changes the outcome from supply to not supply

pays a tax of sii j

N.

Page 71: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Demand Revelation

A pivotal person j who changes the outcome from supply to not supply

pays a tax of

A pivotal person j who changes the outcome from not supply to supply

pays a tax of

sii j

N.

sii j

N.

Page 72: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Demand Revelation

Note: Taxes are not paid to other individuals, but to some other agent outside the market.

Page 73: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Demand Revelation

Why is the GC tax scheme a revelation mechanism?

Page 74: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Demand Revelation

Why is the GC tax scheme a revelation mechanism?

An example: 3 persons; A, B and C. Valuations of the public good are:

$40 for A, $50 for B, $110 for C. Cost of supplying the good is $180.

Page 75: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Demand Revelation

Why is the GC tax scheme a revelation mechanism?

An example: 3 persons; A, B and C. Valuations of the public good are:

$40 for A, $50 for B, $110 for C. Cost of supplying the good is $180. $180 < $40 + $50 + $110 so it is

efficient to supply the good.

Page 76: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Demand Revelation

Assign c1 = $60, c2 = $60, c3 = $60.

Page 77: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Demand Revelation

Assign c1 = $60, c2 = $60, c3 = $60. B & C’s net valuations sum to

$(50 - 60) + $(110 - 60) = $40 > 0. A, B & C’s net valuations sum to $(40 - 60) + $40 = $20 > 0.

Page 78: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Demand Revelation

Assign c1 = $60, c2 = $60, c3 = $60. B & C’s net valuations sum to

$(50 - 60) + $(110 - 60) = $40 > 0. A, B & C’s net valuations sum to $(40 - 60) + $40 = $20 > 0. So A is not pivotal.

Page 79: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Demand Revelation If B and C are truthful, then what net

valuation sA should A state?

Page 80: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Demand Revelation If B and C are truthful, then what net

valuation sA should A state?

If sA > -$20, then A makes supply of the public good, and a loss of $20 to him, more likely.

Page 81: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Demand Revelation If B and C are truthful, then what net

valuation sA should A state?

If sA > -$20, then A makes supply of the public good, and a loss of $20 to him, more likely.

A prevents supply by becoming pivotal, requiring sA + $(50 - 60) + $(110 - 60) < 0;I.e. A must state sA < -$40.

Page 82: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Demand Revelation Then A suffers a GC tax of

-$10 + $50 = $40, A’s net payoff is

- $20 - $40 = -$60 < -$20.

Page 83: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Demand Revelation Then A suffers a GC tax of

-$10 + $50 = $40, A’s net payoff is

- $20 - $40 = -$60 < -$20. A can do no better than state the

truth; sA = -$20.

Page 84: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Demand Revelation

Assign c1 = $60, c2 = $60, c3 = $60.

Page 85: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Demand Revelation

Assign c1 = $60, c2 = $60, c3 = $60. A & C’s net valuations sum to

$(40 - 60) + $(110 - 60) = $30 > 0. A, B & C’s net valuations sum to $(50 - 60) + $30 = $20 > 0.

Page 86: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Demand Revelation

Assign c1 = $60, c2 = $60, c3 = $60. A & C’s net valuations sum to

$(40 - 60) + $(110 - 60) = $30 > 0. A, B & C’s net valuations sum to $(50 - 60) + $30 = $20 > 0. So B is not pivotal.

Page 87: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Demand Revelation What net valuation sB should B state?

Page 88: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Demand Revelation What net valuation sB should B state?

If sB > -$10, then B makes supply of the public good, and a loss of $10 to him, more likely.

Page 89: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Demand Revelation What net valuation sB should B state?

If sB > -$10, then B makes supply of the public good, and a loss of $10 to him, more likely.

B prevents supply by becoming pivotal, requiring sB + $(40 - 60) + $(110 - 60) < 0;I.e. B must state sB < -$30.

Page 90: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Demand Revelation Then B suffers a GC tax of

-$20 + $50 = $30, B’s net payoff is

- $10 - $30 = -$40 < -$10. B can do no better than state the

truth; sB = -$10.

Page 91: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Demand Revelation

Assign c1 = $60, c2 = $60, c3 = $60.

Page 92: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Demand Revelation

Assign c1 = $60, c2 = $60, c3 = $60. A & B’s net valuations sum to

$(40 - 60) + $(50 - 60) = -$30 < 0. A, B & C’s net valuations sum to $(110 - 60) - $30 = $20 > 0.

Page 93: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Demand Revelation

Assign c1 = $60, c2 = $60, c3 = $60. A & B’s net valuations sum to

$(40 - 60) + $(50 - 60) = -$30 < 0. A, B & C’s net valuations sum to $(110 - 60) - $30 = $20 > 0. So C is pivotal.

Page 94: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Demand Revelation What net valuation sC should C state?

Page 95: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Demand Revelation What net valuation sC should C state?

sC > $50 changes nothing. C stays pivotal and must pay a GC tax of -$(40 - 60) - $(50 - 60) = $30, for a net payoff of $(110 - 60) - $30 = $20 > $0.

Page 96: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Demand Revelation What net valuation sC should C state?

sC > $50 changes nothing. C stays pivotal and must pay a GC tax of -$(40 - 60) - $(50 - 60) = $30, for a net payoff of $(110 - 60) - $30 = $20 > $0.

sC < $50 makes it less likely that the public good will be supplied, in which case C loses $110 - $60 = $50.

Page 97: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Demand Revelation What net valuation sC should C state?

sC > $50 changes nothing. C stays pivotal and must pay a GC tax of -$(40 - 60) - $(50 - 60) = $30, for a net payoff of $(110 - 60) - $30 = $20 > $0.

sC < $50 makes it less likely that the public good will be supplied, in which case C loses $110 - $60 = $50.

C can do no better than state the truth; sC = $50.

Page 98: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Demand Revelation GC tax scheme implements efficient

supply of the public good.

Page 99: Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.

Demand Revelation GC tax scheme implements efficient

supply of the public good. But, causes an inefficiency due to

taxes removing private good from pivotal individuals.