Chapter Malthusian Model

download Chapter Malthusian Model

of 22

Transcript of Chapter Malthusian Model

  • 8/18/2019 Chapter Malthusian Model

    1/22

      1

    The Malthusian Model

    After reviewing the key development and growth facts, it is clear that we need a theory

    that can generate a period of constant living standards, followed by a transition period

    with modest increases in the living standard, followed by a period of modern economic

    growth. We already have a model that can account for the period of modern economic

    growth; the Solow Model with technological change generates constant growth of per

    capita output. It is true that the Solow Model can generate a steady state with a constant

    level of per capita output. This is the Solow Model absent technological change. One

    possibility is to interpret the pre-1700 era of constant livings standards as the steady state

    of the Solow Model absent technological change. The problem with this interpretation isthat technology was not stagnant before 1700. Joel Mokyr a noted economic historian at

    Northwestern University has documented in his book The Lever of Riches that numerous

    and important technological innovations occurred well before 1700.

    In light of the historical record on technological change, we proceed to alternative

    theory and model of this pre-1700 era. This is the Malthusian model that goes back to

    David Ricardo and the classical economists. There are two key components of the

    model. The first is a production function with a fixed factor of production. By fixed, we

    mean that its supply cannot be changed over time. Labor and capital are not fixed

    factors as both can be increased over time. In the Malthusian model, the fixed factor is

    land. The second key component is a population growth function that is an increasing

    function of per capita consumption. These two elements ensure that the steady state is

    characterized by a constant living standard even when there is technological change.

    We first proceed by studying the Malthusian model with no capital and absent

    technological change to help develop intuition for the model. We solve the equilibrium

    of the model graphically. We then follow this up with an algebraic study of the

    Malthusian model with capital accumulation and exogenous technological change.

  • 8/18/2019 Chapter Malthusian Model

    2/22

      2

    Figure (1) below is a plot of per capita income from 3000 BC to 2000 AD. The

    feature of the plot is that the standard of living displayed no trend for the first 4800 years

    (this period includes Malthusian and Post-Malthusian regimes) and then exploded

    subsequent to 1800 (Modern regime). These notes are concerned with a theory of the

    period prior to 1800.

    Figure 1

    I. Model with No Capital or Technological Change

    People.  Initially, there are N0 people alive. We use Nt to denote the number of people in

    the economy at date t. People prefer more consumption to less.

    Demographics: Population growth is determined by the death rate and birth rate of the

    population. Thomas Malthus proposed a theory of population dynamics in which the birth

    rate was independent of peoples’ living standard. The death rate however was a

    decreasing function of the amount people consumed. This assumption followed from the

    idea that if people had more to eat they would be stronger and thus their bodies would be

    more able to successfully fight off disease. Graphically, we have

    Income per Capita

    0

    10

    20

    30

    year

    1

    3000 BC 2000 BC 1000 BC 1 AD 1000 2000

  • 8/18/2019 Chapter Malthusian Model

    3/22

      3

    The population growth rate for a given level of consumption is the difference between the

    birth rate and the death rate. We denote this function by g(c). When the birth rate equals

    the death rate, the population does not change, namely Nt+1=Nt. More generally,

    Nt+1=Nt[1+g(c)].

    consumption

    Birth rate

    death rate

    Birth and Death Rates as functions

    of per capita consumption

  • 8/18/2019 Chapter Malthusian Model

    4/22

      4

    In what follows we will use the gross population growth rate function G(c) which is equal

    to 1+g(c). Consequently,

    )(1   t t t    cG N  N    =+ .

    Graphically, we have

    consumption

    11 −+

     N 

     N  

    Population Growth Rate Function (Net)

    0

    g(c)

  • 8/18/2019 Chapter Malthusian Model

    5/22

      5

    Endowments: Each person in the economy is endowed with one unit of time each period

    which he or she can use to work. All individuals own an equal share of the land and the

    total amount of land is fixed at L. Land does not depreciate.

    Production Function: The economy produces a single final good using labor and land.

    The production function is given by

    α α    −=

    1

    t t t    N  L AY   

    The letter A is again the Total Factor Productivity (TFP). 

    consumption

    Gross Population Growth Rate Function

    1

    G(c)

     N 

     N  1+  

  • 8/18/2019 Chapter Malthusian Model

    6/22

      6

    Notice that this production function looks the same as the production function in the

    Solow model except that (1-α) is labor’s share and there is land and not capital. The

    production function is still characterized by constant returns to scale, and is increasing in

    each of its two input. Moreover, the law of diminishing returns applies to each factor

    separately. The increases in output associated with an additional unit of labor input

    decrease as labor increases holding the land input fixed.

    The key feature is that land is essential in production. (Note the last point means that

    doubling population while keeping land fixed less than doubles the output).

    General Equilibrium:

    There are three markets that must clear in each period for the economy to be equilibrium:

    the labor market, the land rental market, and the goods market. Equilibrium quantities

    are trivially determined in this model, as they were in the Solow Growth model. This is

    because the supply of labor and the supply of land are both vertical. People supply their

    entire time endowment to the market and their entire land endowment to the market. As

    Nt and L

     

    are the equilibrium inputs, it is trivial to determine the equilibrium amount ofoutput. This is α α    −= 1t t t    N  L AY  . For the goods market to clear, Ntct=Yt.

    The equilibrium prices are the rental price of land rLt  and the real wage rate, wt. To

    determine these we need to use the firm’s labor demand and its demand for land services.

    Once again, these are the marginal product of land and the marginal product of labor.

    These follow from the profit maximization problem of the firm. This is

    Profits: t  Lt t t t t    Lr  N w N  L Aofits  −−=

      −α ε  1

    Pr

    Labor Demand:t 

    t t t  N 

    Y  N  L Aw )1()1(   α α    α α  −=−=   −  

    Capital Demandt 

    t t t  Lt 

     L

    Y  N  L Ar    α α    α α  ==   −− 11  

  • 8/18/2019 Chapter Malthusian Model

    7/22

      7

    Steady State Analysis 

    We begin with characterizing the steady state equilibrium. First note that there can not be

    any sustained growth in per capita output or consumption in this model. The reason for

    this is that the only way a person’s output could be increased in this world is by

    increasing the amount of land he uses. But land is fixed and so cannot be increased on a

    per person basis. Thus, a steady state equilibrium is characterized by a path of per capita

    consumption and per capita output that are constant, i.e. zero growth. Once we recognize

    this fact, it must be the case that the population is constant in a steady state. Otherwise,

    with diminishing returns, per capita output and per capita consumption would have to fall

    as we add more people to work the land.

    Now, that we recognize this we can be more formal in solving out the steady state

    equilibrium. First, we can exploit the result that Nt+1 = Nt = Nss

     in the steady state with

    the population growth rate function to solve for the steady state living standard, css

      .

    Graphically this is just

  • 8/18/2019 Chapter Malthusian Model

    8/22

  • 8/18/2019 Chapter Malthusian Model

    9/22

      9

    Algebraically, what we have done in solving for the steady state is first use the population

    growth rate function to solve for css

     when Nt+1 /Nt=1. This is )(1  ss

    cG= . The next step,

    which uses the hands and mouth graph, is to solve for Nss using the goods market clearing

    condition and the production function equation. Namely, α α    −= 1 N  AL Ncss . The left hand

    side of the goods market clearing condition is the mouth curve while the right hand side

    is the hands.

    Comparitive Statics

    We can use the diagrams for the population growth function and the hand-mouth to show

    how the steady state of the economy is affected by various factors. As the birth and death

    rates determine the function G(c), anything that affects either the death rate or the birth

    α α    −=

    1 N  ALY 

     

    N

    Determining the Steady State Population

     N t css

    Nss

  • 8/18/2019 Chapter Malthusian Model

    10/22

      10

    rate will affect the steady state consumption level and population by changing the

    position of the mouths curve. Anything that changes the production function will change

    the steady state population through its affect of the Hands curve. The production

    function change will not have any effect on the steady state consumption level, however.

    Transitional Dynamics

    For an economy to be on its steady state it must start out with the right initial population

    size, namely, N0=Nss. Suppose and economy fails to start with such a population. Will it

    converge to the steady state both in terms of consumption and population? The answer is

    yes, it will. This can be seen by using the Hands and Mouth Diagram. Suppose an

    economy starts with a population below the steady state level. According to the Hands

    equation, output is at Y0. The Mouth equation tells us the amount of output needed to

    give each person the steady state consumption level. It is clear that total output exceeds

    the required amount. Hence, c0  > css

    . Now consider what happens to population in

    period 1. Here we use the population growth function. As c0 > css, the population growth

    function implies that N1 /N0 > 1, so population expands. Now at N1, it is still the case that

    the Hands output exceeds the Mouth output, so that the living standard, c1>css. However,

    c1 is smaller than c0. This can be seen in the Hands and Mouth diagram by noting that the

    ray from the origin to any point on the hands curve is equal to per capita output, Y/N,

    which is equal to per capita consumption. As N increases, the slope of this ray declines.

  • 8/18/2019 Chapter Malthusian Model

    11/22

      11

    We thus have the following time paths for population and consumption. The

    convergence property is again the result of the law of diminishing returns and the

    increasing nature of the population growth function. If population is low, the marginal

    product of labor is high. People will therefore

    II. Adding Technological change and Capital

    Thus far we have shown that the steady state of the Malthusian model is characterized by

    a constant living standard and zero population growth. How do these properties change if

    we allow for capital accumulation and technological change? Recall, that we are after a

    model of the pre-1700 era that generates a constant living standard and population

    growth.

    PopulationConsumption

  • 8/18/2019 Chapter Malthusian Model

    12/22

      12

    With the addition of capital it is no longer possible to characterize the properties

    of the model graphically. For this reason we will proceed by deriving algebraically the

    steady state of the model. It is possible to give some intuition for the algebraic results

    that will be derived, however. First, let us think back to the Solow model without

    technological change. Was there sustained growth in the per capita consumption and

    output in that model without technological change? We showed that sustained growth

    was not possible on account of the law of diminishing returns. In the Malthus model the

    law of diminishing returns still holds so adding capital to the Malthus model will do

    nothing to change the result of a constant living standard. How about the affect of adding

    capital accumulation on population growth: Would it change the result of zero population

    growth in the steady state? Again, it would not; you could double all the people and

    machines and output would less than double because land is fixed. Here we see the

    importance of the fixed factor property of land.

    What happens when we add technological change? To gain some intuition here,

    let us return to the Malthus model without technological change or capital accumulation

    and ask what happens to the steady state following an increase in TFP. This is shown

    below. As can be seen, the population is higher. The living standard, however, does not

    change since that is determined by the population dynamics of the model. We can think

    of technological change therefore, as a sequence of increases in TFP. Consequently, in

    the case of technological change we will have a steady state with constant population

    growth and a constant living standard- the pre-1700 facts.

  • 8/18/2019 Chapter Malthusian Model

    13/22

      13

    General Equilibrium:

    The set of conditions that an equilibrium satisfies are listed below. In addition to the land

    and labor market, there is now a capital rental market. Thus, there is its rental price and

    the firm’s demand for capital services given by equation (7). As there is now capital,

    there is also savings (as seen in equation 1) and the law of motion for capital (equation 3).

    (1) t t t    Y sc N  )1(   −=  

    (2) φ α α φ  γ     −−+= 1])1[( t t 

    mt t t    N  LK  AY   

    (3) t t t    sY K K    +−=+ )1(1   δ   

    (4) )(1   t t t    cG N  N    =+  

    (5) t t t t t t 

    mt    N Y  N  LK  Aw  / )1()1)(1()1( φ α γ  φ α    φ α α φ φ α  −−=+−−=   −−−−  

    (6) t t t t 

    mt t  Lt    LY  N  LK  Ar   / ])1[(11 α γ  α    φ α α φ  =+=   −−−  

    α α    −=

    1 N  ALY 

     

    N

    Increase in TFP

     N t c

    ss

    Nss

  • 8/18/2019 Chapter Malthusian Model

    14/22

      14

    (7) t t t t 

    mt t kt    K Y  N  LK  Ar   / ])1[(11 φ γ  φ    φ α α φ  =+=   −−−  

     Balananced Growth Path Equilibrium.  A Balanced Growth path equilibrium is an

    equilibrium such that for the right initial population and capital stock endowment, all

    variables grow at constant rates, with the possibility that this rate is zero for some

    variables. Notationally, given K0  and N0, ct+1 /ct=1+gc, yt+1 /yt=1+gy, Yt+1 /Yt=1+gY,

    Kt+1 /Kt=1+gK, Nt+1 /Nt= 1+gn, rLt+1 /rLt=1+grL, wt+1 /wt=1+gw, rkt+1 /rke=1+grk .

    We divide the solution of the balanced growth path into two parts. In the first, we derive

    the growth rates of each of the key variables along the balanced growth path. This is Part

    I. In the second part, we actually solve for the paths of the population and the total capital

    stock, as well as their initial values.

    Part 1. Solving for the growth rates along the balanced growth

    path.

    Step 1. Use equation (4) to conclude that gc= 0 and ct=css.

    Step 2: Use equation (1) to conclude that gn=gY.

    Step 3. Use equation (3) to conclude that gK=gY. First divide both sides by Kt. This is

    t t t t    K sY K K   / )1( / 1   +−=+   δ  .

    Next invoke the steady state condition that Kt+1 /Kt=1+gK. This is

    K K 

    Y sg   +−=+ )1(1   δ   

  • 8/18/2019 Chapter Malthusian Model

    15/22

      15

    As the left hand side of the equation is constant, it follows that Y and K must grow at the

    same rate along the balanced growth path.

    Step 4. We now use the above results, that g K= gn = gY ≡ g with equation (2) to solve for

    g. First take the date t+1 output. This is

    φ α α φ  γ     −−+

    +

    +++  +=

    1

    1

    1

    111 ])1[( t t 

    mt t t    N  LK  AY   

    Next take the date t+1 output as a ratio of the date t output. This is

    φ α α φ 

    φ α α φ 

    γ  

    γ  −−

    −−

    +

    +

    +++

    +

    +=

    1

    1

    1

    1

    111

    ])1[(

    ])1[(

    mt t 

    mt t 

     N  L AK 

     N  L AK 

    Y  

    Rearranging terms, we arrive atφ α φ 

    φ α γ  

    −−

    ++−−+

     

      

      

      

     +=

    1

    1111 )1(t 

    t m

     N 

     N 

    Y  

    Now invoke the steady state growth rates

    φ α φ  γ     −−+++=+ 1)]1)(1[()1()1(   ggg m  

    Lastly, solve for (1+g)

    (8) α φ α γ    / )1(, )1(1  −−

    +=+ mg  

    Part II. Solving for the Balanced growth path of K and N.

    Step 1. Now that we have solved for the growth rate of the population, we can solve for

    css using from the population growth rate function,

    Step 2. Use equation (1) to solve for Y as a function of Nt and css

    . This is

    (9)s

    c N Y 

    ss

    t −

    =

    1.

    Step 3. Substitute for Yt in equation (3) using equation (9).

  • 8/18/2019 Chapter Malthusian Model

    16/22

      16

    ss

    t t    N s

    scK K 

    +−=+

    1)1(1   δ  .

    Step 4. Use the BGP condition that K t+1=(1+g)K t  to solve for Kt. This is

    (10) t ss

    t    N gs

    scK 

    ))(1(   δ +−=  

    Step 5. Next take equation (3) substituting for Yt using equation (2). This is

    (11) φ α α φ  γ  δ    −−+

      ++−=1

    1 ])1[()1( t t 

    mt t t t    N  LK sAK K  .

    Step 6: We again invoke the BGP condition K t+1=(1+g)K t  and use equation (10) in (11).

    φ α α φ 

    φ 

    γ  δ 

    δ    −−−−

    +

    +−

    =+11

    1

    ])1[())(1(

    )( t t 

    mt t 

    ss

     N  L N gs

    scsAg  

    This gives us a single equation in a single unkown, Nt. Solving for Nt yields

    (12)

    α φ 

    φ α 

    δ δ γ  

     / 11

    )1(

    ))(1()1(

    +−+

    +=

    −−

    gs

    sc

    g

    sA L N 

    sst 

    m

    ss

    t  .

    Using equation (12) with (10), gives us the solution for sst K   

    III. Computing the Equilibrium path when ss N  N  00   ≠ orssK K  00   ≠ .

    Convergence

    If ss N  N  00   ≠ orss

    K K  00   ≠ , the economy will not be on its balanced growth path. We

    showed graphically for the Malthusian model without capital accumulation and

    technological change that an economy which does not begin on its steady will converge

    to its steady state. Although we cannot show it graphically for this more complex version

    of the model, the convergence result holds.

  • 8/18/2019 Chapter Malthusian Model

    17/22

      17

    It is easy to compute the transitional path for the model economy via a

    spreadsheet once we assign parameter values to the model. This is discussed in the last

    section. The equilibrium consists of a path for the following set of variables:

    ),,,,,,,( Kt  Lt t t t t t t    r r wK  LY  N c .

    The equilibrium quantities are trivial to find because the supply of land, labor and

    capital are all vertical. That is to say in period t, the amount of capital used is Kt; the

    amount of labor used is the population, Nt; and the amount of land used is just the

    endowment L. We therefore know what Yt and ct  are. We also know what the margina

    products of all the inputs are, so we know all of the prices. We can then figure out next

    period’s population and capital stock using the population growth rate function and the

    capital stock law of motion. The period t=0 quantities of Land, capital and people are

    given.

    More specifically, we compute the equilibrium path as follows. , K0  , and an

    initial population N0, we find the equilibrium path in each period as follows:

    1.  Determine Yt from the aggregate production function, Equation(2).

    2.  Determine ct from the

    IV. Calibration to pre-1700 Observations

    We can calibrate the model so that it matches the pre-1700 growth facts. We need to

    assign values to the following list of parameters:  Asm ,,,,,   δ γ  φ α  . In addition we need to

    specify the population growth function and assign parameter values to that function. In

    what follows, we assign parameter values so that the model matches the following pre-

    1700 observations associated with England’s experience.

  • 8/18/2019 Chapter Malthusian Model

    18/22

      18

    1.  an average annual population growth rate of .003 per year.

    2.  Historians’ estimates of labor’s share of income equal to 2/3.

    3.  Historians’ estimates of Land’s share of income at 3/12.

    4.  Historians’ estimates of capital’s share of income at 1/12.

    We continue to set the savings rates, s= .20 that we used for the Solow model.

    Additionally, we continue to use the depreciation rate that we used for the Solow model,

    namely, δ  = .05. Just as in the Solow model, an input’s share of income equals its

    coefficient in the production function. For land, this coefficient is α; for capital, this

    coefficient is φ ; and for labor this coefficient is just φ α  −−

    1 . Thus, 12 / 3=

    α    and

    12 / 1=φ  . We can determine the value of γm using the balanced growth relation between

    population growth and the exogenous growth rate of technological change. This is

    α φ α γ    / )1(, )1(1  −−

    +=+ mg .

    Using the observation that g=.003 and the values for 12 / 3=α    and 12 / 1=φ  , we can

    solve for the value of γm. This is 001.=

    mγ   . The last technology parameter, A, is just

    normalized for one as it determines the units in which output is measured. The

    parameterized production function is thus

    3 / 212 / 312 / 1 ])001.1[( t t 

    t t t    N  L AK Y   = .

    The Population growth function

    For the predictions of Malthus to hold, we need a population growth function that is

    increasing in the living standards that governed the pre-1700 era. As the model predicts a

    constant population growth along the balanced growth path, it is clear that we need an

    episode where the English economy was not on its balanced growth path. Such an

    episode is the Black Death that occurred between 1347 and 1350. The effect of the Black

  • 8/18/2019 Chapter Malthusian Model

    19/22

      19

    Death on Europe’s population was dramatic; historians estimate that one half to one third

    of Europe’s population died in this three year period. While deaths were concentrated in

    this three year period, it took nearly 200 years for the population to return to its pre 1346

    level in Europe.

    Our strategy is thus to use the data on living standards (actually real wages) and

    population growth for available years in the 1350 to 1550 period to estimate a linear

    equation for population growth. Namely,

    t t t    c N  N  101 /    β  β    +=+ .

    β0  is the y-intercept of this linear relation and β1  is the slope. The observations for the

    English economy for living standards and population growth are shown in the following

    figure:

  • 8/18/2019 Chapter Malthusian Model

    20/22

      20

    Population Growth Rate for England between 1350 and 11550

    0.99

    0.995

    1

    1.005

    1.01

    1.015

    80 90 100 110 120 130 140 150 160 170

    real wage

     

    The estimated slope line is also depicted. This line is t t t    c N  N  00004.999. / 1   +=+ . This is

    the function G(c).

    V. Empirical Support for the Malthusian TheoryWe conclude this chapter by presenting some evidence in support of the Malthusian

    theory.

    The English Economy From 1250 to the Present

     A. The Period 1275–1800

    The behavior of the English economy from the second half of the 13th  century

    until nearly 1800 is described well by the Malthusian model. Real wages and, more

    generally, the standard of living display little or no trend. This is illustrated in Figure 1,

  • 8/18/2019 Chapter Malthusian Model

    21/22

      21

    which shows the real farm wage and population for the period 1275–1800.i  During this

    period, there was a large exogenous shock, the Black Death, which reduced the

    population significantly below trend for an extended period of time. This dip in

    population, which bottoms out sometime during the century surrounding 1500, is

    accompanied by an increase in the real wage. Once population begins to recover, the real

    wage falls. This observation is in conformity with the Malthusian theory, which predicts

    that a drop in the population due to factors such as plague will result in a high labor

    marginal product, and therefore real wage, until the population recovers.

    Population and Real Farm Wage

    0

    50

    100

    150

    200

    250

    300

    1275 1350 1425 1500 1575 1650 1725 1800

    Population

    Wage

     

    Figure 1

    Another prediction of Malthusian theory is that land rents rise and fall with

    population. Figure 2 plots real land rents and population for England over the same

    1275–1800 period as in Figure 1.ii  Consistent with the theory, when population was

    falling in the first half of the sample, land rents fell. When population increased, land

    rents also increased until near the end of the sample when the industrial revolution had

    already begun.

  • 8/18/2019 Chapter Malthusian Model

    22/22

    Population and Real Land Rent

    0

    50

    100

    150

    200

    250

    300

    1275 1350 1425 1500 1575 1650 1725 1800

    Population

    Rent

     

    Figure 2

    i The English population series is from Clark (1998a) for 1265–1535 (data from parish records in 1405-

    1535 is unavailable, so we use Clark’s estimate that population remained roughly constant during this

    period) and from Wrigley et al. (1997) for 1545–1800. The nominal farm wage series is from Clark

    (1998b), and the price index used to construct the real wage series is from Phelps-Brown and Hopkins

    (1956). We have chosen units for the population and real wage data so that two series can be shown on the

    same plot.

    ii The English population series and the price index used to construct the real land rent series are the same

    as in Figure 1. The nominal land rent series is from Clark (1998a).