Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

174
Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games

Transcript of Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Page 1: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Chapter 3:The Mathematics of Sharing3.1 Fair to Division Games

Page 2: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 2Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-2

The underlying elements of every fair-division game are as follows:

Basic Elements of a Fair-Division Game

The goods (or “booty”).

This is the informal name we will give to the item or items being divided. Typically, these items are tangible physical objects with a positive value, such as candy, cake, pizza, jewelry, art, land, and so on.

Page 3: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 3Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-3

In some situations the items being divided may beintangible things such as rights– water rights, drilling rights, broadcast licenses, and so on– or things with a negative value such as chores, liabilities, obligations, and so on. Regardless of the nature of the items being divided, we will use the symbol S throughout this chapter to denote the booty.

Basic Elements of a Fair-Division Game

Page 4: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 4Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-4

The players.In every fair-division game there is a set of parties withthe right (or in some cases the duty) to share S. They are the players in the game. Most of the time the players in a fair-division game are individuals, but it isworth noting that some of the most significant applications of fair division occur when the players are institutions (ethnic groups, political parties, states, and even nations).

Basic Elements of a Fair-Division Game

Page 5: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 5Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-5

The value systems.The fundamental assumption we will make is that each player has an internalized value system that gives the player the ability to quantify the value of the booty or any of its parts. Specifically, this means that each player can look at the set S or any subset of S and assign to it a value – either in absolute terms (“to me, that’s worth $147.50”) or in relative terms (“to me, that piece is worth 30% of the total value of S”).

Basic Elements of a Fair-Division Game

Page 6: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 6Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-6

Like most games, fair-division games are predicated on certain assumptions about the players. For the purposes of our discussion, we will make the followingfour assumptions:

Basic Assumptions

Page 7: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 7Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-7

Rationality

Each of the players is a thinking, rational entity seeking to maximize his or her share of the booty S. We will further assume that in the pursuit of this goal, aplayer’s moves are based on reason alone (we are taking emotion, psychology, mind games, and all other non-rational elements out of the picture.)

Basic Assumptions

Page 8: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 8Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-8

Cooperation

The players are willing participants and accept the rules of the game as binding. The rules are such that after a finite number of moves by the players, the game terminates with a division of S. (There are no outsiders such as judges or referees involved in these games – just the players and the rules.)

Basic Assumptions

Page 9: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 9Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-9

Privacy

Players have no useful information on the other players’ value systems and thus of what kinds of moves they are going to make in the game. (This assumption does not always hold in real life, especially if the players are siblings or friends.)

Basic Assumptions

Page 10: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 10Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-10

Symmetry

Players have equal rights in sharing the set S. A consequence of this assumption is that, at a minimum, each player is entitled to a proportional share of S – then there are two players, each is entitled to at least one-half of S, with three players each is entitled to at least one-third of S, and so on.

Basic Assumptions

Page 11: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 11Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-11

Given the booty S and players P1, P2, P3,…, PN, each

with his or her own value system, the ultimate goal of the game is to end up with a fair division of S, that is, to divide S into N shares and assign shares to players in such a way that each player gets a fair share. This leads us to what is perhaps the most important definition of this section.

Fair Share

Page 12: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 12Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-12

Fair Share

Suppose that s denotes a share of the booty S

and that P is one of the players in a fair-division

game with N players. We will say that s is a fair

share to player P if s is worth at least 1/Nth of the

total value of S in the opinion of P. (Such a share is

often called a proportional fair share, but for

simplicity we will refer to it just as a fair share.)

FAIR SHARE

Page 13: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 13Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-13

We can think of a fair-division method as the set of rules that define how the game is to be played. Thus, in a fair-division game we must consider not only the booty S and the players P1, P2, P3,…, PN (each with his or her own opinions about how S should be divided), but also a specific method by which we plan to accomplish the fair division.

Fair Division Methods

Page 14: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 14Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-14

There are many different fair-division methods known, but in this chapter we will only discuss a few of the classic ones. Depending on the natureof the set S, a fair- division game can be classified as one of three types: continuous, discrete, or mixed, and the fair-division methods used depend on which of these types we are facing.

Fair Division Methods

Page 15: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 15Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-15

Continuous

In a continuous fair-division game the set S is divisible in infinitely many ways, and shares can be increased or decreased by arbitrarily small amounts. Typical examples of continuous fair-division games involve the division of land, a cake, a pizza, and so forth.

Types of Fair Division Games

Page 16: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 16Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-16

Discrete

A fair-division game is discrete when the set S is made up of objects that are indivisible like paintings, houses, cars, boats, jewelry, and so on. (One might argue that with a sharp enough knife a piece of candy could be chopped up into smaller and smaller pieces. As a semantic convenience let’s agree that candy is indivisible, and therefore dividing candy is a discrete fair-division game.)

Types of Fair Division Games

Page 17: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 17Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-17

Mixed

A mixed fair-division game is one in which some ofthe components are continuous and some are discrete. Dividing an estate consisting of jewelry, ahouse, and a parcel of land is a mixed fair-division game.

Types of Fair Division Games

Page 18: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 18Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-18

Fair-division methods are classified according tothe nature of the problem involved. Thus, there are discrete fair-division methods (used when the set S is made up of indivisible, discrete objects), and there are continuous fair-division methods (used when the set S is an infinitely divisible, continuous set). Mixed fair-division games can usually be solved by dividing the continuous and discrete parts separately, so we will not discuss them in this chapter.

Types of Fair Division Games

Page 19: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 19Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-19

Chapter 3:The Mathematics of Sharing3.2 The Divider to Chooser Method

Page 20: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 20Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-20

The divider-chooser method is undoubtedly the best known of all continuous fair-division methods. This method can be used anytime the fair-division game involves two players and a continuous set S (a cake, a pizza, a plot of land, etc.). Most of us have unwittingly used it at some time or another, and informally it is best known as the you cut–I choose method. As this name suggests, one player, called the divider, divides S into two shares, and the second player, called the chooser, picks the share he or she wants, leaving the other share to the divider.

Divider-Chooser Method

Page 21: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 21Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-21

Under the rationality and privacy assumptions we introduced in the previous section, this method guarantees that both divider and chooser will get a fair share (with two players, this means a share worth 50% or more of the total value of S). Not knowing the chooser’s likes and dislikes (privacy assumption), the divider can only guarantee himself a 50% share by dividing S into two halves of equal value (rationality assumption); the chooser is guaranteed a 50% or better share by choosing the piece he or she likes best.

Divider-Chooser Method

Page 22: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 22Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-22

On their first date, Damian and Cleo go to the county fair. They buy jointly a raffle ticket, and as luck would have it, they win a half chocolate–half strawberry cheesecake. Damian likes chocolate and strawberry equally well, so in his eyes the chocolate and strawberry

Example 3.1 Damian and Cleo Divide a Cheesecake

halves are equal in value.

Page 23: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 23Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-23

On the other hand, Cleo hates chocolate–she is allergic to it and gets sick if she eats any– so in her eyes the value of the cake is 0% for the chocolate

Example 3.1 Damian and Cleo Divide a Cheesecake

half, 100% for the strawberry part.

Once again, to ensure a fair division, we will assume that neither of them knows anything about the other’s likes and dislikes.

Page 24: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 24Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-24

Damian volunteers to go first (the divider). He cuts the cake in a perfectly rational division of the cake based on his value system–each piece is half of the cake and to him worth one-half of the total value of the cake. It is now Cleo’s turn to choose, and her choice is obvious she will pick the piece having the larger strawberry part.

Example 3.1 Damian and Cleo Divide a Cheesecake

Page 25: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 25Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-25

The final outcome of this division is that Damian gets a piece that in his own eyes is worth exactly half of the cake, but Cleo ends up with a much sweeter deal–a piece that in her own eyes is worth about two-thirds of the cake. This is, nonetheless, a fair division of the cake–both players get pieces worth 50% or more.

Example 3.1 Damian and Cleo Divide a Cheesecake

Page 26: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 26Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-26

Example 3.1 illustrates why, given a choice, it is always better to be the chooser than the divider–the divider is guaranteed a share worth exactly 50% of the total value of S, but with just a little luck the chooser can end up with a share worth more than 50%. Since a fair-division method should treat all players equally, both players should have an equal chance of being the chooser. This is best done by means of a coin toss, with the winner of the coin tossgetting the privilege of making the choice.

Better to be the Chooser

Page 27: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 27Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-27

Chapter 3:The Mathematics of Sharing3.3 The Lone to Divider Method

Page 28: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 28Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-28

The first important breakthrough in the mathematics of fair division came in 1943, when Steinhaus came up with a clever way to extend some of the ideas in the divider-chooser method to the case of three players, one of whom plays the role of the divider and the other two who play the role of choosers. Steinhaus’ approach was subsequently generalized to any number of players N (one divider and N – 1 choosers) by Princeton mathematician Harold Kuhn.

Lone-Divider Method

Page 29: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 29Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-29

Preliminaries

One of the three players will be the divider; the other two players will be choosers. Since it is better to be a chooser than a divider, the decision of who is what is made by a random draw (rolling dice, drawing cards from a deck, etc.). We’ll call the divider D and the choosers C1 and C2.

Lone-Divider Method for Three Players

Page 30: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 30Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-30

Step 1 (Division)

The divider D divides the cake into three shares (s1,

s2, and s3). D will get one of these shares, but at this point does not know which one. (Not knowing which share will be his is critical – it forces D to divide the cake into three shares of equal value.)

Lone-Divider Method for Three Players

Page 31: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 31Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-31

Step 2 (Bidding)

C1 declares (usually by writing on a slip of paper) which of the three pieces are fair shares to her. Independently, C2 does the same. These are the bids. A chooser’s bid must list every single piece that he or she considers to be a fair share (i.e., worth one-third or more of the cake)–it may be tempting to bid only for the very best piece, but this is a strategy that can easily backfire. To preserve the privacy requirement, it is important that the bids be made independently, without the choosers being privy to each other’s bids.

Lone-Divider Method for Three Players

Page 32: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 32Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-32

Step 3 (Distribution)

Who gets which piece? The answer, of course,

depends on which pieces are listed in the bids. For

convenience, we will separate the pieces into two

types: C-pieces (these are pieces chosen by either

one or both of the choosers) and U-pieces (these are

unwanted pieces that did not appear in either of the

bids).

Lone-Divider Method for Three Players

Page 33: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 33Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-33

Step 3 (Distribution) continued

Expressed in terms of value, a U-piece is a piece that both choosers value at less than 33 1/3% of thecake, and a C-piece is a piece that at least one ofthe choosers (maybe both) value at 33 1/3% or more. Depending on the number of C-pieces, thereare two separate cases to consider.

Lone-Divider Method for Three Players

Page 34: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 34Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-34

Case 1

When there are two or more C-pieces, there is alwaysa way to give each chooser a different piece from among the pieces listed in her bid. (The details will be covered in Examples 3.2 and 3.3.) Once each chooser gets her piece, the divider gets the last remaining piece. At this point every player has received a fair share, and a fair division has been accomplished.

Lone-Divider Method for Three Players

Page 35: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 35Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-35

Case 1

(Sometimes we might end up in a situation in which C1 likes C2’s piece better than her own and

vice versa. In that case it is perfectly reasonable toadd a final, informal step and let them swap pieces–this would make each of them happier than they already were, and who could be against that?)

Lone-Divider Method for Three Players

Page 36: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 36Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-36

Case 2

When there is only one C-piece, we have a bit of a problem because it means that both choosers are bidding for the very same piece.

Lone-Divider Method for Three Players

The solution requires a little more creativity. First, we take care of the divider D–to whom all pieces are equal in value – by giving him one of the pieces that neither chooser wants.

Page 37: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 37Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-37

Case 2

After D gets his piece, the two pieces left (the C-piece and the remaining U-piece) are recombined into one piece that we call the B-piece.

Lone-Divider Method for Three Players

We can revert to the divider-chooser method to finish the fair division: one player cuts the B-piece into two pieces; the other player chooses the piece she likes better.

Page 38: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 38Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-38

Case 2

This process results in a fair division of the cake because it guarantees fair shares for all players. We know that D ends up with a fair share by the very fact that D did the original division, but what about C1 and C2? The key

observation is that in the eyes of both C1 and C2 the B-piece is worth more than two-thirds of the value of the original cake (think of the B-piece as 100% of the original cake minus a U-piece worth less than 33 1/3%), so when we divide it fairly into two shares, each party is guaranteed more than one-third of the original cake.

Lone-Divider Method for Three Players

Page 39: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 39Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-39

Dale, Cindy, and Cher are dividing a cake using Steinhaus’s lone-divider method. They draw cards from a well-shuffled deck of cards, and Dale draws the low card(bad luck!) and has to be the divider.

Example 3.2 Lone Divider with 3 Players (Case 1, Version 1)

Step 1 (Division)

Dale divides the cake into three pieces s1, s2, and s3. Table 3-1 shows the values of the three pieces in the eyes of each of the players.

Page 40: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 40Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-40

Step 2 (Bidding)We can assume that Cindy’s bid list is {s1, s3} and Cher’s bid list is also {s1, s3}.

Example 3.2 Lone Divider with 3 Players (Case 1, Version 1)

Page 41: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 41Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-41

Step 3 (Distribution)

The C-pieces are s1 and s3. There are two possible

distributions. One distribution would be: Cindy gets s1,

Cher gets s3, and Dale gets s2. An even better

distribution (the optimal distribution) would be: Cindy gets s3, Cher gets s1, and Dale gets s2. In the case of the first distribution, both Cindy and Cher would benefit by swapping pieces, and there is no rational reason why they would not do so.

Example 3.2 Lone Divider with 3 Players (Case 1, Version 1)

Page 42: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 42Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-42

Step 3 (Distribution) continued

Thus, using the rationality assumption, we can conclude that in either case the final result will be the same: Cindy gets s3, Cher gets s1, and Dale gets s2.

Example 3.2 Lone Divider with 3 Players (Case 1, Version 1)

Page 43: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 43Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-43

We’ll use the same setup as in Example 3.2–Dale is the divider, Cindy and Cher are the choosers.

Example 3.3 Lone Divider with 3 Players (Case 1, Version 2)

Step 1 (Division)

Dale divides the cake into three pieces s1, s2, and s3. Table 3-2 shows the values of the three pieces in the eyes of each of the players.

Page 44: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 44Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-44

Step 2 (Bidding)

Here Cindy’s bid list is {s2} only, and Cher’s bid list is {s1} only.

Example 3.3 Lone Divider with 3 Players (Case 1, Version 2)

Page 45: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 45Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-45

Step 3 (Distribution)

This is the simplest of all situations, as there is only one possible distribution of the pieces: Cindy gets s2, Cher gets s1, and Dale gets s3.

Example 3.3 Lone Divider with 3 Players (Case 1, Version 2)

Page 46: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 46Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-46

The gang of Examples 3.2 and 3.3 are back at it again.

Example 3.4 Lone Divider with 3 Players (Case 2)

Step 1 (Division)

Dale divides the cake into three pieces s1, s2, and s3. Table 3-3 shows the values of the three pieces in the eyes of each of the players.

Page 47: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 47Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-47

Step 2 (Bidding)

Here Cindy’s and Cher’s bid list consists of just {s3}.

Example 3.4 Lone Divider with 3 Players (Case 2)

Page 48: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 48Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-48

Step 3 (Distribution)

The only C-piece is s3. Cindy and Cher talk it over, and without giving away any other information agree that of the two U-pieces, s1 is the least desirable, so they all agree that Dale gets s1. (Dale doesn’t care which of the three pieces he gets, so he has no rational objection.) The remaining pieces (s2 and s3) are then recombined to form the B-piece, to be divided between Cindy and Cher using the divider-chooser method (one of them divides

Example 3.4 Lone Divider with 3 Players (Case 2)

Page 49: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 49Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-49

Step 3 (Distribution) continued

the B-piece into two shares, the other one chooses the share she likes better). Regardless of how this plays out, both of them will get a very healthy share of the cake: Cindy will end up with a piece worth at least 40% of the original cake (the B-piece is worth 80% of the original cake to Cindy), and Cher will end up with a piece worth at least 45% of the original cake (the B-piece is worth 90% of the original cake to Cher).

Example 3.2 Lone Divider with 3 Players (Case 1, Version 1)

Page 50: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 50Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-50

The first two steps of Kuhn’s method are a straightforward generalization of Steinhaus’s lone-divider method for three players, but the distribution step requires some fairly sophisticated mathematical ideas and is rather difficult to describe in full generality, so we will only give an outline here and will illustrate the details with a couple of examples for N = 4 players.

The Lone-Divider Method for More Than Three Players

Page 51: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 51Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-51

Preliminaries

One of the players is chosen to be the divider D, and the remaining N – 1 players are all going to be choosers. As always, it’s better to be a chooser than a divider, so the decision should be made by a random draw.

The Lone-Divider Method for More Than Three Players

Page 52: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 52Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-52

Step 1 (Division)

The divider D divides the set S into N shares s1, s2, s3, ..., sN. D is guaranteed of getting one of these shares, but doesn’t know which one.

The Lone-Divider Method for More Than Three Players

Page 53: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 53Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-53

Step 2 (Bidding)

Each of the N – 1 choosers independently submits a bid list consisting of every share that he or she considers to be a fair share (i.e., worth 1/Nth or more of the booty S).

The Lone-Divider Method for More Than Three Players

Page 54: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 54Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-54

Step 3 (Distribution)

The bid lists are opened. Much as we did with three players, we will have to consider two separate cases, depending on how these bid lists turn out.

The Lone-Divider Method for More Than Three Players

Page 55: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 55Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-55

Case 1.

If there is a way to assign a different share to each of the N – 1 choosers, then that should be done. (Needless to say, the share assigned to a chooser should be from his or her bid list.) The divider, to whom all shares are presumed to be of equal value, gets the last unassigned share. At the end, players may choose to swap pieces if they want.

The Lone-Divider Method for More Than Three Players

Page 56: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 56Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-56

Case 2.

There is a standoff–in other words, there are two choosers both bidding for just one share, or three choosers bidding for just two shares, or K choosers bidding for less than K shares. This is a much more complicated case, and what follows is a rough sketch of what to do. To resolve a standoff, we first set aside the shares involved in the standoff from the remaining shares.

The Lone-Divider Method for More Than Three Players

Page 57: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 57Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-57

Case 2.

Likewise, the players involved in the standoff are temporarily separated from the rest. Each of the remaining players (including the divider) can be assigned a fair share from among the remaining shares and sent packing. All the shares left are recombined into a new booty S to be divided among the players involved in the standoff, and the process starts all over again.

The Lone-Divider Method for More Than Three Players

Page 58: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 58Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-58

We have one divider, Demi, and three choosers, Chan, Chloe, and Chris.

Example 3.5 Lone Divider with 4 Players (Case 1)

Step 1 (Division)

Demi divides the cake into four shares s1, s2, s3, and s4.

Table 3-4 shows how each of the players values each of the four shares. Remember that the information on each row of Table 3-4 is private and known only to that player.

Page 59: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 59Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-59

Step 2 (Bidding)

Chan’s bid list is {s1, s3}; Chloe’s bid list is {s3} only; Chris’s bid list is {s1, s4}.

Example 3.5 Lone Divider with 4 Players (Case 1)

Page 60: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 60Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-60

Step 3 (Distribution)

The bid lists are opened. It is clear that for startersChloe must get s3 – there is no other option. This

forces the rest of the distribution: s1 must then go toChan, and s4 goes to Chris. Finally, we give the last remaining piece, s2, to Demi.

Example 3.5 Lone Divider with 4 Players (Case 1)

Page 61: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 61Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-61

This distribution results in a fair division of the cake, although it is not entirely “envy-free” Chan wishes he had Chloe’s piece (35% is better than 30%) but Chloe is not about to trade pieces with him, so he is stuck with s1. (From a strictly rational point of view, Chan

has no reason to gripe–he did not get the best piece, but got a piece worth 30% of the total, better than the 25% he is entitled to.)

Example 3.5 Lone Divider with 4 Players (Case 1)

Page 62: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 62Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-62

Once again, we will let Demi be the divider and Chan, Chloe, and Chris be the three choosers (same players, different game).

Example 3.6 Lone Divider with 4 Players (Case 2)

Step 1 (Division)

Demi divides the cake into four shares s1, s2, s3, and s4. Table 3-5 shows how each of the players values each of the four shares.

Page 63: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 63Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-63

Step 2 (Bidding)

Chan’s bid list is {s4}; Chloe’s bid list is {s2, s3} only;

Chris’s bid list is {s4}.

Example 3.6 Lone Divider with 4 Players (Case 2)

Page 64: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 64Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-64

Step 3 (Distribution)

The bid lists are opened, and the players can see that there is a standoff brewing on the horizon–Chan and Chris are both bidding for s4. The first step is to

set aside and assign Chloe and Demi a fair share from s1, s2, and s4. Chloe could be given either s2 or

s3. (She would rather have s2,of course, but it’s not for her to decide.)

Example 3.6 Lone Divider with 4 Players (Case 2)

Page 65: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 65Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-65

Step 3 (Distribution)

A coin toss is used to determine which one. Let’s say Chloe ends up with s3 (bad luck!). Demi could be now

given either s1 or s2. Another coin toss, and Demi ends up with s1. The final move is ... you guessed it! –

recombine s2 and s4 into a single piece to be divided

between Chan and Chris using the divider-chooser method.

Example 3.6 Lone Divider with 4 Players (Case 2)

Page 66: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 66Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-66

Step 3 (Distribution)

Since (s2 + s4) is worth 60% to Chan and 58% to Chris (you can check it out in Table 3-5), regardless of how this final division plays out they are both guaranteed a final share worth more than 25% of the cake.

Mission accomplished! We have produced a fair division of the cake.

Example 3.6 Lone Divider with 4 Players (Case 2)

Page 67: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 67Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-67

A completely different approach for extending the divider-chooser method was proposed in 1964 by A.M.Fink, a mathematician at Iowa State University. In this method one player plays the role of chooser, all the other players start out playing the role of dividers. For this reason, the method is known as the lone-chooser method. Once again, we will start with a description of the method for the case of three players.

The Lone-Chooser Method

Page 68: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 68Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-68

Preliminaries

We have one chooser and two dividers. Let’s call the chooser C and the dividers D1 and D2. As usual, we decide who is what by a random draw.

The Lone-Chooser Method for 3 Players

Page 69: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 69Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-69

Step 1 (Division)

D1 and D2 divide S between themselves into two fair shares. To do this, they use the divider-chooser method. Let’s say that D1 ends up s1 with D2 and ends up with s2.

The Lone-Chooser Method for 3 Players

Page 70: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 70Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-70

Step 2 (Subdivision)

Each divider divides his share into three subshares. Thus, D1 divides s1 into three subshares, which we will call s1a, s1b, and s1c. Likewise, D2 divides s2 into three subshares, which we will call s2a, s2b, and s2c.

The Lone-Chooser Method for 3 Players

Page 71: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 71Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-71

Step 3 (Selection)

The chooser C now selects one of D1’s three subshares and one of D2’s three subshares (whichever she likes best). These two subshares make up C’s final share. D1 then keeps the remaining two subshares from s1, and D2 keeps the remaining two subshares from s2.

The Lone-Chooser Method for 3 Players

Page 72: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 72Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-72

Why is this a fair division of S? D1 ends up with two-

thirds of s1. To D1, s1 is worth at least one-half of the

total value of S, so two-thirds of s1 is at least one-

third–a fair share. The same argument applies to D2.

What about the chooser’s share? We don’t know what s1 and s2 are each worth to C, but it really

doesn’t matter–a one-third or better share of s1 plus

a one-third or better share of s2 equals a one-third or

better share of (s1 + s2) and thus a fair share of the

cake.

The Lone-Chooser Method for 3 Players

Page 73: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 73Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-73

David, Dinah, and Cher are dividing an orange-pineapple cake using the lone-chooser method. The cake is valued by each of them at $27, so each of them expects to end up with a share worth at least $9. Their individual value systems (not known to one another, but available to us as outside observers) are as follows:

Example 3.7 Lone Chooser with 3 Players

Page 74: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 74Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-74

■ David likes pineapple and orange the same.

■ Dinah likes orange but hates pineapple.

■ Cher likes pineapple twice as much as she likes orange.

Example 3.7 Lone Chooser with 3 Players

Page 75: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 75Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-75

After a random selection, Cher gets to be the chooser and thus gets to sit out Steps 1 & 2.

Example 3.7 Lone Chooser with 3 Players

Step 1 (Division)

David and Dinah start by dividing the cake between themselves using the divider-chooser method. After a coin flip, David cuts the cake into two pieces.

Page 76: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 76Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-76

Step 1 (Division) continued

Since Dinah doesn’t like pineapple, she will take the share with the most orange.

Example 3.7 Lone Chooser with 3 Players

Step 2 (Subdivision)

David divides his share into three subshares that in his opinion are of equal value (all the same size).

Page 77: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 77Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-77

Step 2 (Subdivision) continued

Dinah also divides her share into three smaller subshares that in her opinion are of equal value. (Remember that Dinah hates pineapple. Thus, she has made her cuts in such a way as to have one-third of the orange in each of the subshares.)

Example 3.7 Lone Chooser with 3 Players

Page 78: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 78Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-78

Step 3 (Selection)

It’s now Cher’s turn to choose one sub-share from David’s three and one subshare from Dinah’s three. She will choose one of the two pineapple wedges from David’s subshares and the big orange-pineapple wedge from Dinah’s subshares.

Example 3.7 Lone Chooser with 3 Players

Page 79: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 79Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-79

Step 3 (Selection)

The final fair division of the cake is shown. David gets a final share worth $9, Dinah gets a final share worth $12, and Cher gets a final share worth $14. David is satisfied, Dinah is happy, and Cher is ecstatic.

Example 3.7 Lone Chooser with 3 Players

Page 80: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 80Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-80

In the general case of N players, the lone-chooser method involves one chooser C and N – 1 dividers D1, D2,…, DN–1. As always, it is preferable to be a chooser than a divider, so the chooser is determined by a random draw. The method is based on an inductive strategy. If you can do it for three players, then you can do it for four players; if you can do it for four, then you can do it for five; and we can assume that we can use the lone-chooser methodwith N – 1 players.

The Lone-Chooser Method for N Players

Page 81: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 81Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-81

Step 1 (Division)

D1, D2,…, DN–1 divide fairly the set S among themselves, as if C didn’t exist. This is a fair division among N – 1 players, so each one gets a share he or she considers worth at least of 1/(N –1)th of S.

The Lone-Chooser Method for N Players

Page 82: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 82Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-82

Step 2 (Subdivision)

Each divider subdivides his or her share into N sub-shares.

The Lone-Chooser Method for N Players

Page 83: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 83Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-83

Step 3 (Selection)

The chooser C finally gets to play. C selects one sub-share from each divider – one subshare from D1, one

from D2, and so on. At the end, C ends up with N – 1

subshares, which make up C’s final share, and each divider gets to keep the remaining N – 1 subshares in his or her subdivision.

The Lone-Chooser Method for N Players

Page 84: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 84Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-84

When properly played, the lone-chooser methodguarantees that everyone, dividers and chooseralike, ends up with a fair share

The Lone-Chooser Method for N Players

Page 85: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 85Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-85

Chapter 3:The Mathematics of Sharing3.4 The Lone to Chooser Method

Page 86: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 86Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-86

The first important breakthrough in the mathematicsof fair division came in 1943, when Steinhaus cameup with a clever way to extend some of the ideas inthe divider-chooser method to the case of three players, one of whom plays the role of the divider and the other two who play the role of choosers. Steinhaus’ approach was subsequently generalizedto any number of players N (one divider and N – 1 choosers) by Princeton mathematician Harold Kuhn.

Lone-Divider Method

Page 87: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 87Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-87

Preliminaries

One of the three players will be the divider; the other two players will be choosers. Since it is better to be a chooser than a divider, the decision of who is what is made by a random draw (rolling dice, drawing cards from a deck, etc.). We’ll call the divider D and the choosers C1 and C2.

Lone-Divider Method for Three Players

Page 88: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 88Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-88

Step 1 (Division)

The divider D divides the cake into three shares (s1, s2,

and s3). D will get one of these shares, but at this

point does not know which one. (Not knowing which share will be his is critical – it forces D to divide the cake into three shares of equal value.)

Lone-Divider Method for Three Players

Page 89: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 89Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-89

Step 2 (Bidding)

C1 declares (usually by writing on a slip of paper) which of the three pieces are fair shares to her. Independently, C2 does the same. These are the bids. A chooser’s bid must list every single piece that he or she considers to be a fair share (i.e.,worth one-third or more of the cake)–it may be tempting to bid only for the very best piece, but this is a strategy that can easily backfire. To preserve the privacy requirement, it is important that the bids be made independently, without the choosers being privy to each other’s bids.

Lone-Divider Method for Three Players

Page 90: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 90Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-90

Step 3 (Distribution)

Who gets which piece? The answer, of course,

depends on which pieces are listed in the bids. For

convenience, we will separate the pieces into two

types: C-pieces (these are pieces chosen by either one

or both of the choosers) and U-pieces (these are

unwanted pieces that did not appear in either of the

bids).

Lone-Divider Method for Three Players

Page 91: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 91Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-91

Step 3 (Distribution) continued

Expressed in terms of value, a U-piece is a piece that both choosers value at less than 33 1/3% of the cake, and a C-piece is a piece that at least one of the choosers (maybe both) value at 33 1/3% or more. Depending on the number of C-pieces, there are two separate cases to consider.

Lone-Divider Method for Three Players

Page 92: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 92Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-92

Case 1

When there are two or more C-pieces, there is always a way to give each chooser a different piece from among the pieces listed in her bid. (Thedetails will be covered in Examples 3.2 and 3.3.) Once each chooser gets her piece, the divider gets the last remaining piece. At this point every player has received a fair share, and a fair division has been accomplished.

Lone-Divider Method for Three Players

Page 93: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 93Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-93

Case 1

(Sometimes we might end up in a situation in which C1 likes C2’s piece better than her own and vice

versa. In that case it is perfectly reasonable to add a final, informal step and let them swap pieces–this would make each of them happier than they already were, and who could be against that?)

Lone-Divider Method for Three Players

Page 94: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 94Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-94

Case 2When there is only one C-piece, we have a bit of a problem because it means that both choosers are bidding for the very same piece.

Lone-Divider Method for Three Players

The solution requires a little more creativity. First, we take care of the divider D–to whom all pieces are equal in value–by giving him one of the pieces that neither chooser wants.

Page 95: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 95Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-95

Case 2After D gets his piece, the two pieces left (the C-piece and the remaining U-piece) are recombined into one piece that we call the B-piece.

Lone-Divider Method for Three Players

We can revert to the divider-chooser method to finish the fair division: one player cuts the B-piece into two pieces; the other player chooses the piece she likes better.

Page 96: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 96Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-96

Case 2

This process results in a fair division of the cake because it guarantees fair shares for all players. We know that D ends up with a fair share by the very fact that D did the original division, but what about C1 and C2? The key observation is

that in the eyes of both C1 and C2 the B-piece is worth more than two-thirds of the value of the original cake (think of the B-piece as 100% of the original cake minus a U-piece worth less than 33 1/3%), so when we divide it fairly into two shares, each party is guaranteed more than one-third of the original cake.

Lone-Divider Method for Three Players

Page 97: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 97Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-97

Dale, Cindy, and Cher are dividing a cake using Steinhaus’s lone-divider method. They draw cards from a well-shuffled deck of cards, and Dale draws the low card (bad luck!) and has to be the divider.

Example 3.2 Lone Divider with 3 Players (Case 1, Version 1)

Step 1 (Division)

Dale divides the cake into three pieces s1, s2, and s3. Table 3-1 shows the values of the three pieces in the eyes of each of the players.

Page 98: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 98Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-98

Step 2 (Bidding)We can assume that Cindy’s bid list is {s1, s3} and Cher’s bid list is also {s1, s3}.

Example 3.2 Lone Divider with 3 Players (Case 1, Version 1)

Page 99: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 99Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-99

Step 3 (Distribution)

The C-pieces are s1 and s3. There are two possible

distributions. One distribution would be: Cindy gets s1, Chergets s3, and Dale gets s2. An even better distribution (the optimal distribution) would be: Cindy gets s3, Cher gets s1,

and Dale gets s2. In the case of the first distribution, both Cindy and Cher would benefit by swapping pieces, and there is no rational reason why they would not do so.

Example 3.2 Lone Divider with 3 Players (Case 1, Version 1)

Page 100: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 100Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-100

Step 3 (Distribution) continued

Thus, using the rationality assumption, we can conclude that in either case the final result will be the same: Cindy gets s3, Cher gets s1, and Dale gets s2.

Example 3.2 Lone Divider with 3 Players (Case 1, Version 1)

Page 101: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 101Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-101

We’ll use the same setup as in Example 3.2–Dale is the divider, Cindy and Cher are the choosers.

Example 3.3 Lone Divider with 3 Players (Case 1, Version 2)

Step 1 (Division)

Dale divides the cake into three pieces s1, s2, and s3. Table 3-2 shows the values of the three pieces in the eyes of each of the players.

Page 102: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 102Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-102

Step 2 (Bidding)Here Cindy’s bid list is {s2} only, and Cher’s bid list is {s1} only.

Example 3.3 Lone Divider with 3 Players (Case 1, Version 2)

Page 103: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 103Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-103

Step 3 (Distribution)

This is the simplest of all situations, as there is only one possible distribution of the pieces: Cindy gets s2, Cher gets s1, and Dale gets s3.

Example 3.3 Lone Divider with 3 Players (Case 1, Version 2)

Page 104: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 104Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-104

The gang of Examples 3.2 and 3.3 are back at it again.

Example 3.4 Lone Divider with 3 Players (Case 2)

Step 1 (Division)

Dale divides the cake into three pieces s1, s2, and s3. Table 3-3 shows the values of the three pieces in the eyes of each of the players.

Page 105: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 105Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-105

Step 2 (Bidding)Here Cindy’s and Cher’s bid list consists of just {s3}.

Example 3.4 Lone Divider with 3 Players (Case 2)

Page 106: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 106Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-106

Step 3 (Distribution)

The only C-piece is s3. Cindy and Cher talk it over, and without giving away any other information agree that of the two U-pieces, s1 is the least desirable, so they all

agree that Dale gets s1. (Dale doesn’t care which of the three pieces he gets, so he has no rational objection.) The remaining pieces (s2 and s3) are then recombined to form the B-piece, to be divided between Cindy and Cher using the divider-chooser method (one of them divides

Example 3.4 Lone Divider with 3 Players (Case 2)

Page 107: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 107Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-107

Step 3 (Distribution) continued

the B-piece into two shares, the other one chooses the share she likes better). Regardless of how this plays out, both of them will get a very healthy share of the cake: Cindy will end up with a piece worth at least 40% of the original cake (the B-piece is worth 80% of the original cake to Cindy), and Cher will end up with a piece worth at least 45% of the original cake (the B-piece is worth 90% of the original cake to Cher).

Example 3.2 Lone Divider with 3 Players (Case 1, Version 1)

Page 108: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 108Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-108

The first two steps of Kuhn’s method are a straightforward generalization of Steinhaus’s lone-divider method for three players, but the distributionstep requires some fairly sophisticated mathematical ideas and is rather difficult to describein full generality, so we will only give an outline hereand will illustrate the details with a couple of examples for N = 4 players.

The Lone-Divider Method for More Than Three Players

Page 109: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 109Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-109

Preliminaries

One of the players is chosen to be the divider D, and the remaining N – 1 players are all going to be choosers. As always, it’s better to be a chooser than a divider, so the decision should be made by a random draw.

The Lone-Divider Method for More Than Three Players

Page 110: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 110Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-110

Step 1 (Division)

The divider D divides the set S into N shares s1, s2, s3, ..., sN. D is guaranteed of getting one of these shares, but doesn’t know which one.

The Lone-Divider Method for More Than Three Players

Page 111: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 111Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-111

Step 2 (Bidding)

Each of the N – 1 choosers independently submits a bid list consisting of every share that he or she considers to be a fair share (i.e., worth 1/Nth or more of the booty S).

The Lone-Divider Method for More Than Three Players

Page 112: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 112Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-112

Step 3 (Distribution)

The bid lists are opened. Much as we did with three players, we will have to consider two separate cases, depending on how these bid lists turn out.

The Lone-Divider Method for More Than Three Players

Page 113: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 113Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-113

Case 1.

If there is a way to assign a different share to each of the N – 1 choosers, then that should be done. (Needless to say, the share assigned to a chooser should be from his or her bid list.) The divider, to whom all shares are presumed to be of equal value, gets the last unassigned share. At the end, players may choose to swap pieces if they want.

The Lone-Divider Method for More Than Three Players

Page 114: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 114Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-114

Case 2.

There is a standoff–in other words, there are two choosersboth bidding for just one share, or three choosers bidding for just two shares, or K choosers bidding for less than K shares. This is a much more complicated case, and what follows is a rough sketch of what to do. To resolve a standoff, we first set aside the shares involved inthe standoff from the remaining shares.

The Lone-Divider Method for More Than Three Players

Page 115: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 115Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-115

Case 2.

Likewise, the players involved in the standoff are temporarily separated from the rest. Each of the remaining players (including the divider) can be assigned a fair share from among the remaining shares and sent packing. All the shares left are recombined intoa new booty S to be divided among the players involved in the standoff, and the process starts all over again.

The Lone-Divider Method for More Than Three Players

Page 116: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 116Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-116

We have one divider, Demi, and three choosers, Chan, Chloe, and Chris.

Example 3.5 Lone Divider with 4 Players (Case 1)

Step 1 (Division)

Demi divides the cake into four shares s1, s2, s3, and s4. Table 3-4 shows how each of the players values each of the four shares. Remember that the information on each row of Table 3-4 is private and known only to that player.

Page 117: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 117Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-117

Step 2 (Bidding)Chan’s bid list is {s1, s3}; Chloe’s bid list is {s3} only; Chris’s bid list is {s1, s4}.

Example 3.5 Lone Divider with 4 Players (Case 1)

Page 118: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 118Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-118

Step 3 (Distribution)

The bid lists are opened. It is clear that for starters Chloe must get s3 – there is no other option. This

forces the rest of the distribution: s1 must then go to Chan, and s4 goes to Chris. Finally, we give the last remaining piece, s2, to Demi.

Example 3.5 Lone Divider with 4 Players (Case 1)

Page 119: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 119Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-119

This distribution results in a fair division of the cake, although it is not entirely “envy-free” Chan wishes he had Chloe’s piece (35% is better than 30%) but Chloe is not about to trade pieces with him, so he is stuck with s1. (From a strictly rational point of view, Chan has no reason to gripe–he did not get the best piece, but got a piece worth 30% of the total, better than the 25% he is entitled to.)

Example 3.5 Lone Divider with 4 Players (Case 1)

Page 120: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 120Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-120

Once again, we will let Demi be the divider and Chan, Chloe, and Chris be the three choosers (same players, different game).

Example 3.6 Lone Divider with 4 Players (Case 2)

Step 1 (Division)

Demi divides the cake into four shares s1, s2, s3, and s4.

Table 3-5 shows how each of the players values eachof the four shares.

Page 121: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 121Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-121

Step 2 (Bidding)Chan’s bid list is {s4}; Chloe’s bid list is {s2, s3} only; Chris’s bid list is {s4}.

Example 3.6 Lone Divider with 4 Players (Case 2)

Page 122: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 122Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-122

Step 3 (Distribution)

The bid lists are opened, and the players can see that there is a standoff brewing on the horizon–Chan and Chris are both bidding for s4. The first step is to set aside and assign Chloe and Demi a fair share from s1, s2, and s4. Chloe could be given either s2 or s3. (She would rather have s2,of course, but it’s not for her to decide.)

Example 3.6 Lone Divider with 4 Players (Case 2)

Page 123: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 123Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-123

Step 3 (Distribution)

A coin toss is used to determine which one. Let’s say Chloe ends up with s3 (bad luck!). Demi could be

now given either s1 or s2. Another coin toss, and Demi ends up with s1. The final move is ... you guessed it!– recombine s2 and s4 into a single piece to be divided

between Chan and Chris using the divider-chooser method.

Example 3.6 Lone Divider with 4 Players (Case 2)

Page 124: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 124Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-124

Step 3 (Distribution)

Since (s2 + s4) is worth 60% to Chan and 58% to Chris (you can check it out in Table 3-5), regardless of how this final division plays out they are both guaranteed a final share worth more than 25% of the cake.

Mission accomplished! We have produced a fair division of the cake.

Example 3.6 Lone Divider with 4 Players (Case 2)

Page 125: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 125Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-125

Chapter 3:The Mathematics of Sharing3.5 The Method of Sealed Bids

Page 126: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 126Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-126

As a general rule of thumb, discrete fair division is harder to achieve than continuous fair division because there isa lot less flexibility in the division process, and discrete fairdivisions that are truly fair are only possible under a limitedset of conditions. Thus, it is important to keep in mind that while both of the methods we will discuss in the next two sections have limitations, they still are the best methods we have available. Moreover, when they work, both methods work remarkably well and produce surprisingly good fair divisions.

Discrete versus Continuous

Page 127: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 127Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-127

The method of sealed bids was originally proposedby Hugo Steinhaus and Bronislaw Knaster around1948. The best way to illustrate how this method works is by means of an example.

The Method of Sealed Bids

Page 128: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 128Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-128

In her last will and testament, Grandma plays a little joke on her four grandchildren (Art, Betty, Carla, and Dave) by leaving just three items–a cabin in the mountains, a vintage 1955 Rolls Royce,and a Picasso painting– with the stipulation that the items must remain with the grandchildren (not sold to outsiders) and must be divided fairly in equal shares among them. How can we possibly resolve this conundrum? The method of sealed bidswill give an ingenious and elegant solution.

Example 3.9 Settling Grandma’s Estate

Page 129: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 129Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-129

Step 1 (Bidding)Each of the players makes a bid (in dollars) for each of the items in the estate, giving his or her honest assessment of the actual value of each item. To satisfy the privacy assumption, it is important that thebids are done independently, and no player should be privy to another player’s bids before making his or her own. The easiest way to accomplish this is for each player to submit his or her bid in a sealed envelope. When all the bids are in, they are opened.

Example 3.9 Settling Grandma’s Estate

Page 130: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 130Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-130

Step 1 (Bidding)Table 3-6 shows each player’s bid on each item in the estate.

Example 3.9 Settling Grandma’s Estate

Page 131: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 131Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-131

Step 2 (Allocation)Each item will go to the highest bidder for that item. (If there is a tie, the tie can be broken with a coin flip.)In this example the cabin goes to Betty, the vintageRolls Royce goes to Dave, and the Picasso painting goes to Art. Notice that Carla gets nothing. Not to worry–it all works out at the end! (In this method it is possible for one player to get none of the items and another player to get many or all of the items. Much like in a silent auction, it’s a matter of who bids the highest.)

Example 3.9 Settling Grandma’s Estate

Page 132: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 132Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-132

Step 3 (First Settlement)It’s now time to settle things up. Depending on what items (if any) a player gets in Step 2, he or she will owe money to or be owed money by the estate. To determine how much a player owes or is owed, we first calculate each player’s fair-dollar share of the estate. A player’s fair-dollar share is found by adding that player’s bids and dividing the total by the number of players.

The last row of Table 3-7 shows the fair-dollar share of each player.

Example 3.9 Settling Grandma’s Estate

Page 133: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 133Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-133

Step 3 (First Settlement)

Example 3.9 Settling Grandma’s Estate

Page 134: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 134Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-134

Step 3 (First Settlement)

For example, Art’s bids on the three items add up to$540,000. Since there are four equal heirs, Art realizes he is only entitled to one-fourth of that–his fair-dollar share is therefore $135,000.

Example 3.9 Settling Grandma’s Estate

Page 135: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 135Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-135

Step 3 (First Settlement)

The fair-dollar shares are the baseline for the settlements–if the total value of the items that the player gets in Step 2 is more than his or her fair-dollar share, then the player pays the estate the difference. If the total value of the items that the player gets is less than his or her fair-dollar share, then the player gets the difference in cash.

Here are the details of how the settlement works out for eachof our four players.

Example 3.9 Settling Grandma’s Estate

Page 136: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 136Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-136

Art

As we have seen, Art’s fair dollar share is $135,000. At the same time, Art is getting a Picasso painting worth (to him) $280,000, so Art must pay the estate the difference of $145,000 ($280,000 – $135,000). The combination of getting the $280,000 Picasso painting but paying $145,000 for it in cash results in Art getting his fair share of the estate.

Example 3.9 Settling Grandma’s Estate

Page 137: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 137Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-137

Betty

Betty’s fair-dollar share is $130,000. Since she is getting thecabin, which she values at $250,000, she must pay the estate the difference of $120,000. By virtue of getting the $250,000 house for $120,000, Betty ends up with her fair share of the estate.

Example 3.9 Settling Grandma’s Estate

Page 138: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 138Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-138

Carla

Carla’s fair-dollar share is $123,000. Since she is getting no items from the estate, she receives her full $123,000 incash. Clearly, she is getting her fair share of the estate.

Example 3.9 Settling Grandma’s Estate

Page 139: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 139Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-139

Dave

Dave’s fair-dollar share is $110,000. Dave is getting the vintage Rolls, which he values at $52,000, so he has anadditional $58,000 coming to him in cash. The Rolls plusthe cash constitute Dave’s fair share of the estate.

Example 3.9 Settling Grandma’s Estate

Page 140: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 140Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-140

At this point each of the four heirs has received a fairshare, and we might consider our job done, but this is not the end of the story–there is more to come (good news mostly!). If we add Art and Betty’s payments to the estate and subtract the payments made by the estate to Carla and Dave, we discover that there is a surplus of $84,000! ($145,000 and $120,000 came in from Art and Betty; $123,000 and $58,000 went out toCarla and Dave.)

Example 3.9 Settling Grandma’s Estate

Page 141: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 141Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-141

Step 4 (Division of the Surplus)

The surplus is common money that belongs to the estate, and thus to be divided equally among the players. In our example each player’s share of the $84,000 surplus is $21,000.

Example 3.9 Settling Grandma’s Estate

Page 142: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 142Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-142

Step 4 (Division of the Surplus)

The surplus is common money that belongs to the estate, and thus to be divided equally among the players. In our example each player’s share of the $84,000 surplus is $21,000.

Step 5 (Final Settlement)

The final settlement is obtained by adding the surplus money to the first settlement obtained in Step 3.

Example 3.9 Settling Grandma’s Estate

Page 143: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 143Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-143

Step 5 (Final Settlement)

Art:Gets the Picasso painting and pays the estate $124,000–the original $135,000 he had to pay in Step 3 minus the $21,000 he gets from his share of the surplus.

(Everything done up to this point could be done on paper, but now, finally, real money needs to change hands!)

Example 3.9 Settling Grandma’s Estate

Page 144: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 144Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-144

Step 5 (Final Settlement)Betty:Gets the cabin and has to pay the estate only $99,000 ($120,000 – $21,000).

Carla:Gets $144,000 in cash ($123,000 + $21,000).

Dave:Gets the vintage Rolls Royce plus $79,000 ($58,000 + $21,000).

Example 3.9 Settling Grandma’s Estate

Page 145: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 145Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-145

The method of sealed bids works so well because it tweaks a basic idea in economics. In most ordinary transactions there is a buyer and a seller, and the buyerknows the other party is the seller and vice versa. In themethod of sealed bids, each player is simultaneously abuyer and a seller, without actually knowing which one until all the bids are opened. This keeps the playershonest and, in the long run, works out to everyone’s advantage.

The Method of Sealed Bids

Page 146: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 146Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-146

At the same time, the method of sealed bids will not work unless the following two important conditions are satisfied.

The Method of Sealed Bids

• Each player must have enough money to play the game.

If a player is going to make honest bids on the items, he or

she must be prepared to buy some or all of them, which means that he or she may have to pay the estate certain sums of money. If the player does not have this money available, he or she is at a definite disadvantage in

playing the game.

Page 147: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 147Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-147

• Each player must accept money (if it is a sufficiently

large amount) as a substitute for any item. This means that no player can consider any of the items priceless.

The Method of Sealed Bids

The method of sealed bids takes a particularly simple form in the case of two players and one item.

Consider the following example.

Page 148: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 148Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-148

Al and Betty are getting a divorce. The only joint property of any value is their house. Rather than hiring attorneys and going to court to figure out how to split up the house, they agree to give the method of sealed bids a try. Al’s bid on the house is $340,000; Betty’s bid is $364,000. Their fair-dollar shares of the “estate” are $170,000 and $182,000, respectively. Since Betty is the higher bidder, she gets to keep the house and must pay Al cash for his share.

Example 3.10Splitting Up the House

Page 149: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 149Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-149

The computation of how much cash Betty pays Al can be done in two steps. In the first settlement, Bettyowes the estate $182,000. Of this money, $170,000 pays for Al’s fair share, leaving a surplus of $12,000 to be split equally between them.

The bottom line is that Betty ends up paying $176,000 to Al for his share of the house, and both come out $6000 ahead.

Example 3.10Splitting Up the House

Page 150: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 150Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-150

The method of sealed bids can provide an excellent solution not only to settlements of property in a divorce but also to the equally difficultand often contentious issue of splitting up a partnership. The catch is that in these kinds of splits we can rarely count on the rationality assumption to hold. A divorce or partnership split devoid of emotion, spite, and hard feelings is a rare thing indeed!

The Method of Sealed Bids

Page 151: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 151Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-151

Chapter 3:The Mathematics of Sharing3.6 The Method of Markers

Page 152: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 152Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-152

The method of markers is a discrete fair-division method proposed in 1975 by William F. Lucas, a mathematician at the Claremont Graduate School.The method has the great virtue that it does not require the players to put up any of their own money. On the other hand, unlike the method of sealed bids, this method cannot be used effectively unless (1) there are many more items to be divided than there are players in the game and (2) the items are reasonably close in value.

The Method of Markers

Page 153: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 153Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-153

In this method we start with the items lined up in a random but fixed sequence called an array. Each ofthe players then gets to make an independent bid on the items in the array. A player’s bid consists of dividing the array into segments of consecutive items (as many segments as there are players) so that each of the segments represents a fair share of the entire set of items.

The Method of Markers

Page 154: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 154Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-154

For convenience, we might think of the array as a string. Each player then cuts” the string into N segments, each of which he or she considers an acceptable share. (Notice that to cut a string into N sections, we need N – 1 cuts.) In practice, one way to make the “cuts” is to lay markers in the places where the cuts are made. Thus, each player can make his or her bids by placing markers so that they divide the array into N segments.

The Method of Markers

Page 155: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 155Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-155

To ensure privacy, no player should see the markers of another player before laying down his or her own.

The final step is to give to each player one of the segments in his or her bid.

The easiest way to explain how this can be done is with an example.

The Method of Markers

Page 156: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 156Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-156

Alice, Bianca, Carla, and Dana want to divide the Halloween leftovers shown in Fig. 3-16 among themselves. There are 20 pieces, but having each randomly choose 5 pieces is not likely

Example 3.11Dividing the Halloween Leftovers

to work well–the pieces are too varied for that. Their teacher, Mrs. Jones, offers to divide the candy for them, but the children reply that they just learned about a cool fair-division game they want to try, and they can do it themselves, thank you.

Page 157: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 157Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-157

Arrange the 20 pieces randomly in an array.

Example 3.11Dividing the Halloween Leftovers

Page 158: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 158Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-158

Step 1 (Bidding)

Each child writes down independently on a piece of paper exactly where she wants to place her three markers. (Three markers divide the array into four sections.) The bids are opened, and the results are shown on the next slide.

The A-labels indicate the position of Alice’s markers (A1

denotes her first marker, A2 her second marker, and A3 her third and last marker).

Example 3.11Dividing the Halloween Leftovers

Page 159: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 159Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-159

Step 1 (Bidding)

Example 3.11Dividing the Halloween Leftovers

Page 160: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 160Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-160

Step 1 (Bidding)

Alice’s bid means that she is willing to accept one of the following as a fair share of the candy: (1) pieces 1 through 5 (first segment), (2) pieces 6 through 11 (second segment), (3) pieces 12 through 16 (third segment), or (4) pieces 17 through 20 (last segment). Bianca’s bid is shown by the B-markers and indicates how she would break up the array into four segments that are fair shares; Carla’s bid (C-markers) and Dana’s bid (D-markers).

Example 3.11Dividing the Halloween Leftovers

Page 161: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 161Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-161

Step 2 (Allocations)This is the tricky part, where we are going to give to each child one of the segments in her bid. Scan the array from left to right until the first first marker comes up. Here the first first marker is Bianca’s B1.

Example 3.11Dividing the Halloween Leftovers

Page 162: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 162Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-162

Step 2 (Allocations)This means that Bianca will be the first player to get her fair share consisting of the first segment in her bid (pieces 1 through 4).

Example 3.11Dividing the Halloween Leftovers

Page 163: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 163Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-163

Step 2 (Allocations)Bianca is done now, and her markers can be removed since they are no longer needed. Continue scanning from left to right looking for the first second marker. Here the first secondmarker is Carla’s C2, so Carla will be the second player

taken care of.

Example 3.11Dividing the Halloween Leftovers

Page 164: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 164Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-164

Step 2 (Allocations)Carla gets the second segment in her bid (pieces 7 through 9). Carla’s remaining markers can now be removed.

Example 3.11Dividing the Halloween Leftovers

Page 165: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 165Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-165

Step 2 (Allocations)Continue scanning from left to right looking for the first third marker. Here there is a tie between Alice’s A3 and Dana’s D3.

Example 3.11Dividing the Halloween Leftovers

Page 166: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 166Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-166

Step 2 (Allocations)As usual, a coin toss is used to break the tie and Alice will bethe third player to go–she will get the third segment in her bid (pieces 12 through 16).

Example 3.11Dividing the Halloween Leftovers

Page 167: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 167Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-167

Step 2 (Allocations)

Dana is the last player and gets the last segment in her bid (pieces 17 through 20,).

Example 3.11Dividing the Halloween Leftovers

Page 168: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 168Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-168

Step 2 (Allocations)At this point each player has gotten a fair share of the 20 pieces of candy. The amazing part is that there is leftover candy!

Example 3.11Dividing the Halloween Leftovers

Page 169: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 169Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-169

Step 3 (Dividing the Surplus)The easiest way to divide the surplus is to randomly draw lots and let the players take turns choosing one piece at a time until there are no more pieces left. Here the leftover pieces are 5, 6, 10, and 11 The players now draw lots; Carla gets to choose first and takes piece 11. Dana chooses next and takes piece 5. Bianca and Alice receive pieces 6 and 10, respectively.

Example 3.11Dividing the Halloween Leftovers

Page 170: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 170Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-170

The ideas behind Example 3.11 can be easily generalized to any number of players. We now give the general description of the method of markers with N players and M discrete items.

The Method of Markers Generalized

PreliminariesThe items are arranged randomly into an array. For convenience, label the items 1 through M, going from left to right.

Page 171: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 171Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-171

Step 1 (Bidding)

Each player independently divides the array into N segments (segments 1, 2, . . . , N) by placing N – 1 markers along the array. These segments are assumed to represent the fair shares of the array in the opinion of that player.

The Method of Markers Generalized

Page 172: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 172Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-172

Step 2 (Allocations)

Scan the array from left to right until the first first marker is located. The player owning that marker (let’s call him P1) goes first and gets the first

segment in his bid. (In case of a tie, break the tie randomly.) P1’s markers are removed, and we

continue scanning from left to right, looking for the first second marker.

The Method of Markers Generalized

Page 173: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 173Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-173

Step 2 (Allocations)

The player owning that marker (let’s call her P2) goes second and gets the second segment in her bid. Continue this process, assigning to each player in turn one of the segments in her bid. The last player gets the last segment in her bid.

Step 3 (Dividing the Surplus)

The players get to go in some random order and pick one item at a time until all the surplus items are given out.

The Method of Markers Generalized

Page 174: Chapter 3: The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1 Fair to Division Games.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 1.1 - 174Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. 3.1-174

Despite its simple elegance, the method of markers can be used only under some fairly restrictive conditions: it assumes that every player is able to divide the array of items into segments in such a way that each of the segments has approximately equal value. This is usually possible when the items are of small and homogeneous value, but almost impossible to accomplish when there is a combination of expensive and inexpensive items (good luck trying to divide fairly 19 candy bars plus an iPod using the method of markers!).

The Method of Markers: Limitation