Cepr Governance

download Cepr Governance

of 34

Transcript of Cepr Governance

  • 8/6/2019 Cepr Governance

    1/34

    Global Economic Governance:

    Systemic Challenges, Institutional Responses, and the Role of the New Actors

    Brussels (European Commission, Berlaymont Building, Hallstein Room)

    17 February 2009

    CEPR wishes to thank the European Commission for its financial and organizational support for this meeting.This document was prepared as part of Politics, Economics and Global Governance: The European

    Dimensions (PEGGED), a Collaborative Project funded by the European Commission's Seventh Research

    Framework Programme

    The views expressed in this document are those of the author(s) and not those of the above-mentionedinstitutions or of CEPR which takes no institutional policy positions

    Global Imbalances and Global Governance

    Philip R. Lane

  • 8/6/2019 Cepr Governance

    2/34

    Global Imbalances and Global Governance

    Philip R. Lane

    IIIS, Trinity College Dublin and CEPR

    February 2009

    Prepared for the Global Economic Governance: Systemic Challenges, Institutional Responses, and

    the Role of the New Actors workshop in Brussels on February 17th 2009. Agustin Benetrix, Christiane

    Hellmanzeik and Peter McQuade provided helpful research assistance. Email: [email protected]. Tel: +353 1

    896 2259. Fax: +353 1 896 3939. Postal Address: The Sutherland Centre, Arts Block, Trinity College

    Dublin, Dublin 2, Ireland.

    1

  • 8/6/2019 Cepr Governance

    3/34

    1 Introduction

    Figure 1 shows the evolution of global imbalances in recent years, plus the projections

    for the 2009-2013 period. The general dynamics are well known: the United States has

    been running the worlds largest current account decit, while current account surpluses

    have been generated by Japan, emerging Asia and the oil exporters (with the relative

    contributions of these groups varying over time). Although the aggregate current account

    balance of the euro area has been small, this obscures a wide dispersion of current account

    positions across the member countries, with the large German surplus oset by decits in

    countries such as Spain, Portugal, Greece and Ireland. The IMFs projections for 2009-2013

    indicate a general contraction in current account imbalances, with the important exception

    of emerging Asia.

    Turning to net foreign asset positions, Figure 2 looks broadly similar to Figure 1, al-

    though with some important modications. First, the pattern of net valuation gains and

    losses until 2007 has been stabilising for countries such as the United States, such that

    the deterioration in its net foreign asset position has been less than the size of current

    account decits. Second, Figure 2 shows that the dispersion of net foreign asset positions

    is projected to widen over 2009-2013, despite the expected contraction in current account

    balances. This reects the reality that the projection for current account balances does not

    anticipate widespread sign reversals in positions but just a dimunition of existing trends.

    Moreover, it is not clear that the pattern for valuation eects over 2009-2013 will neces-

    sarily be stabilising. Indeed, Milesi-Ferretti (2009) estimates that the pattern of valuation

    eects during 2008 was destabilising, with the United States experiencing a major valu-

    ation loss and some of the major surplus countries enjoying signicant valuation gains.

    (The 2008 distribution of valuation gains reects the skewed composition of international

    balance sheets, with the long equity, short debt prole of the United States leaving it very

    exposed to the global equity price declines during 2008.)

    2

  • 8/6/2019 Cepr Governance

    4/34

    Accordingly, there are several reasons to remain concerned about the scale of global

    imbalances. First, global imbalances were surely a contributory factor to the origin of the

    current global nancial crisis (Portes 2009). While there remains considerable disagree-

    ment about the appropriate weighting that should be attached to global imbalances in

    developing a comprehensive explanation for the current crisis, it is important to further

    improve our analytical understanding of the sources of global imbalances. Second, the on-

    going persistence of global imbalances (in the current account and in the net foreign asset

    position) continues to be a major risk factor for the world economy. Most obviously, the

    risk of a disruptive dollar depreciation remains current, such that there is a clear policy

    interest in continuing to focus on global imbalances.

    Third, it important to consider new institutional arrangements that might help to avoid

    the emergence of non-sustainable patterns in global imbalances in the future. Along one

    dimension, it is plausible that the global tightening of regulations concerning the behaviour

    of the nancial sector may help to avoid the amplication problem, by which capital inows

    into the United States contributed to increases in leverage and the explosion in securiti-

    sations. Accordingly, there is some level of coherence between the global moves to reform

    the nancial sector and the debate concerning the role of governance reforms in redressing

    global imbalances.

    A second dimension concerns the impact of the monetary policies of the worlds leading

    nancial economies on the distribution of global imbalances. While the current account

    is clearly not a policy target for central banks, the relevant issue is whether the major

    central banks responded appropriately to shifts in asset prices that may be traced back to

    global imbalances. Again, it is possible that the current crisis may prompt a recasting ofthe intellectual framework that guides monetary policy decisions, extending to include a

    greater appreciation of the role of international factors in driving domestic asset prices.

    While these elements of global governance are important, I focus in this paper on how

    reforms in the governance of the global nancial system may alter the incentives facing

    3

  • 8/6/2019 Cepr Governance

    5/34

    those emerging market economies that have opted to run large current account surpluses

    over the last decade. These surpluses haven been accumulated in order to self insure

    against the risks of disruptions in capital ows to these economies. Although the emerging

    markets have not been the only source of current account surpluses, we focus on this group

    of countries since these surpluses may be intepreted as globally inecient. In contrast,

    the large surpluses run by oil exporters in recent years conform to neoclassical predictions of

    optimising behaviour in response to a terms of trade windfall. Similarly, the chronic current

    account surpluses of Japan and Germany can be largely attributed to demographic patterns

    and the declining share of these economies in global GDP.1 While ecient current account

    surpluses may still pose problems for the global system, the inecient surpluses run by

    emerging market economies are arguably a more natural target for institutional reform.2

    Although the epicenter of the global nancial crisis has clearly been in the nancial

    systems of the advanced economies, the emerging markets have been substantially aected

    by the crisis. The latest indicators suggest a major slowdown in output and trade volumes

    and a reversal in capital inows to these economies. The decline in fundamentals is also

    reected in major shifts in asset prices, with a substantial depreciation of the currencies of

    most emerging market economies (China excepted), a decline in stock market values and an

    increase in foreign-currency bond spreads. These negative developments illustrate that the

    self insurance model has not enabled emerging market economies to remain immune from

    negative global developments and reinforce the urgency of developing a new institutional

    framework to support a more stable pattern of capital ows to emerging market economies.

    1 See Lane (2008x) on the Japanese external position.2 Here, I use inecient in the sense of departing from the current account balance that would be run

    under an international nancial system that has a superior institutional architecture.

    4

  • 8/6/2019 Cepr Governance

    6/34

    2 Shifts in the External Balance Sheets of Emerging

    Market Economies

    The external risk prole of emerging market economies has undergone a radical shift since

    the mid 1990s.3 Figure 3 shows the degree of international nancial integration of the

    major emerging market economies has trended upwards over time, where the IFI index is

    the sum of foreign assets and foreign liabilities expressed as a ratio to GDP.4 As is analysed

    by Lane and Milesi-Ferretti (2008a), the level of international nancial integration remains

    far below that exhibited by the major advanced economies. However, it is much higher

    in terms of gross positions than was the case during previous crisis episodes in the 1980s

    and 1990s. The scale of gross positions grew rapidly over the last ve years, which was

    mainly generated by an acceleration in gross capital ows. In addition, rising global asset

    values increased the scale of balance sheets relative to GDP. Accordingly, in terms of gross

    cross-border positions, the emerging market economies were much more integrated into the

    global nancial system at the onset of the current global crisis.

    As was noted in the previous section, the composition of the international investment

    position of emerging market economies underwent a major shift. A major trend has been

    the growing importance of FDI and portfolio equity as a source of nance (Figure 4).

    This has been a positive development in terms of risk prole, since the foreign investor

    absorbs the risk of state-contingent returns on these positions. We can gain further insight

    by inspecting the scale of the portfolio holdings by advanced-economy investors that are

    located in the major emerging market economies. Figure 5 expresses these holdings in terms

    of their weight in the total international portfolios of the major investor nations. We observe3 The following material draws on Lane (2009).4 In what follows, the group of major emerging market economies typically comprises the following

    members of the G20: Argentina, Brazil, Mexico, India, Indonesia, China, Korea, South Africa, Saudi

    Arabia and Turkey.

    5

  • 8/6/2019 Cepr Governance

    7/34

    the increasing importance of emerging market destinations in portfolio equity assets, while

    these countries are much less important in international portfolio debt holdings.

    Figure 6 shows that the risk prole has been further improved by the rapid growth in

    foreign-exchange reserves, which have increased from 5 percent of aggregate GDP in the

    1980s to over 25 percent by 2007.5

    Taken together, these trends have led to a striking shift in the international conguration

    of portfolios.6 Figure 7 shows that the major emerging market economies have shifted from

    a position in 1995 in which these countries were both net debtors and net recipients of

    equity investments to a prole in which a much larger negative net equity position is nearly

    matched by a very large long position in foreign debt holdings. The mirror-image trend is

    evident for the major advanced economies, which increased their long position in foreign

    equity while also taking on a larger short position in foreign debt.

    The transformation of the external nancial prole of emerging market economies also

    included a major reduction in net foreign liabilities (Figure 8). This was achieved by a

    sustained period of running current account surpluses (Figure 9). While the long-term

    allocative eciency of capital running uphill may be open to question, it should have

    reduced the vulnerability of emerging market economies to capital ow reversals, since the

    net external position has been a historical predictor of the incidence of crises.

    The impact of these shifts in external capital structure has been to transform the ag-

    gregate foreign-currency position of emerging market economies. Lane and Shambaugh

    (2008) have developed an index of the foreign-currency exposure that is embedded in a

    given level of foreign assets and foreign liabilities. This FXAGG index has the range

    (

    1; 1) where a country that has only foreign-currency liabilities and zero foreign-currency5 There is a rapidly-growing literature that seeks to explain the determinants of reserve accumulation.

    The recent study by Obstfeld et al (2008) highlights nancial development as a driver of external reserves,

    in order to oer investors protection against the risk of a double drain. See also the recent analysis in

    ECB (2009).6 See also the analysis in Lane and Milesi-Ferretti (2007a).

    6

  • 8/6/2019 Cepr Governance

    8/34

    assets would score the value 1, while a country with zero foreign-currency foreign liabili-

    ties and all of its foreign assets denominated in foreign currencies would score the value 1.

    Table 1 shows the FXAGG index has become much less negative for most major emerging

    market economies and indeed is substantially positive for a number of countries. For this

    latter group, the depreciation of the domestic currency would actually generate a positive

    balance-sheet eect, since the capital gain on its foreign-currency assets would exceed the

    capital loss on its foreign-currency liabilities.

    At one level, this general reconguration may be viewed as involving a major risk trans-

    fer from the emerging markets to investors in the advanced economies. In turn, this should

    be welfare improving to the extent that investors in the higher-income economies with

    more developed nancial systems should be better equipped to manage risk. However, the

    build up in large two-way gross positions also meant that failures in risk management and

    illquidity problems in the advanced economies may be transmitted quickly to counterparts

    in the emerging market economies.

    However, while these steps have reduced the vulnerability to nancial crises, each in-

    volves signicant ineciencies. In particular, this strategy has been costly in terms of

    foregone domestic absorption opportunities and in the potential for superior international

    risk sharing arrangements. Moreover, it exerts substantial spillover eects on the reserve-

    issuing countries, through the impact of persistent trade surpluses and the ocial-sector

    demand for liquid securities. Finally, the adverse impact of the current crisis on emerging

    market economies demonstrates that vulnerabilities remain, such that the self-insurance

    approach has not provided complete insulation.

    7

  • 8/6/2019 Cepr Governance

    9/34

    3 The Institutional Framework for Capital Flows be-

    tween Advanced and Developing Economies

    In relation to the medium-term goal of improving the structural foundations of the inter-

    national nancial system, the over-riding principle is to reduce the risks faced by emerging

    market economies in engaging with the international nancial system (Wolf 2009). In ad-

    dition, in managing the residual risk, the goal is to develop mechanisms that reduce the

    cost of insuring against such risks.

    In general, the appropriate framework for thinking about medium-term reform is to

    recognise that the emerging market economies suer from an incomplete level of interna-

    tional nancial integration. Unlike very low income countries, these economies are su-

    ciently integrated into the global nancial system to be exposed to severe nancial shocks.

    However, at the same time, these countries are treated dierently by the global system in

    comparison to the nancial environment that faces the most advanced economies. Empiri-

    cally, Calvo et al (2008) and Kose et al (2008) nd that there is a threshold eect in terms

    of the relation between international nancial integration and nancial stability. The goal

    for the emerging market economies is to pass this threshold and thereby attain a more ro-

    bust form of nancial integration. Importantly, as is emphasised by Kose et al (2008), the

    nancial integration threshold is aected by key features of the domestic economy, includ-

    ing the level of domestic nancial development, the quality of institutions and governance,

    macroeconomic policy discipline and trade integration. Accordingly, reaping the gains from

    nancial globalisation involves the same types of reforms that are also generally benecial

    for domestic economic performance.In relation to the domestic reform eorts of the emerging market economies, the recent

    increase in the cost of external capital should induce an intensication of eorts to develop

    the domestic nancial system. Domestic nancial development is important for two rea-

    sons. First, the improved domestic mobilisation of domestic savings reduces the importance

    8

  • 8/6/2019 Cepr Governance

    10/34

    of external capital as a funding source. Second, a deeper nancial system increases the span

    of investable opportunities that are available to foreign investors. Financial development

    should be broadly interpreted to encompass improvements in corporate governance and

    the quality of the regulatory system. In particular, the current crisis has highlighted that

    volume-based indices of nancial development (such as the stock of outstanding securities)

    are not good measures if the nancial system is distorted by a poor regulatory environment.

    It is also important to take into account that the empirical evidence indicates that

    nancial reform policies only promote nancial development in environments in which pri-

    vate property rights are secure from arbitrary political interference (Tressel and Detragiache

    2008). Moreover, while the full impact of domestic nancial reform only unfolds over the

    medium term, the credible announcement of a programme of nancial reforms should be

    helpful even in the short term. While Figure ?? shows that the major emerging market

    economies have made major progress in nancial reform, a considerable gap remains for

    several countries relative to a fully-liberalised domestic nancial system (the maximum

    score is 21 in the IMF index).

    It should also be understood that domestic risk management extends beyond the nan-

    cial system to include social insurance programmes. In advanced economies, risk manage-

    ment is provided by a combination of public and private systems. However, the degree of

    social insurance for major personal risks (illness, unemployment) is much less adequate in

    a number of emerging market economies, leading to a high degree of precautionary saving

    by households. Accordingly, part of the reform agenda is to improve the adequacy of social

    insurance, via welfare systems and the public funding of relevant goods and services. In

    similar fashion, institutional reform extends beyond the regulation of the nancial system.A striking illustration is provided by Naughton (2006), who shows how the ambiguous

    ownership status of many enterprises in China generates an extraordinarily high level of

    corporate savings, due to lack of clarity over the appropriate distribution of dividend pay-

    ments.

    9

  • 8/6/2019 Cepr Governance

    11/34

    In relation to domestic reforms that directly aect the nature of international capital

    ows, one key element is the development of local-currency debt markets. Burger and

    Warnock (2006) investigate the determinants of success in promoting local-currency debt

    markets and nd that key drivers include the attainment of macroeconomic stability (low

    ination) and strong creditor protection. Indeed, these authors note that the requirements

    for a thriving local-currency bond market are very similar to those for the development

    of the domestic-currency banking system. Accordingly, reform eorts that are targeted

    at improving the operation of debt nancing in general can serve the dual purpose of

    promoting both the bond market and the banking system.7

    So far, local-currency debt markets have been dominated by locally-resident investors,

    with relatively little participation by foreign investors. While participation by domestic

    residents is a major achievement in itself, it is also desirable to enable eective cross-border

    capital ows in local currency. To this end, it is important that the development of local-

    currency debt markets is complemented by the development of the currency derivatives

    market, in order to allow investors to separately trade currency risk and credit risk.

    The role of derivatives markets in cross-border risk transfer is not well understood at

    the empirical level, with many derivative trades simply redistributing risk across domes-

    tic residents. However, the evidence from a recent national survey in Australia is quite

    striking. The analysis of this survey by Becker and Fabbro (2006) shows that currency

    hedging allowed Australian residents to transform the risk prole of the external balance

    sheet. In particular, foreign-currency debt of AUS$428 billion at the end of March 2005

    was greatly reduced to AUS$90 billion through derivatives contracts with overseas coun-

    terparties. These international hedges meant that the aggregate foreign-currency exposureof Australia turned from negative to positive. Accordingly, the Australian example illus-

    7 Schmitz (2009) nds that domestic nancial reforms stimulates capital inows for a sample of emerging

    European economies. A striking feature of his work is that it is banking-sector reform that is especially

    important in attracting inows.

    10

  • 8/6/2019 Cepr Governance

    12/34

    trates how foreign-currency debt can be transformed via currency derivatives into domestic-

    currency debt from the perspective of domestic residents.8

    In addition to the promotion of local-currency debt markets, there is also considerable

    scope to improve risk sharing via other types of state-contingent instruments. For instance,

    the idea of GDP-indexed bonds has received considerable attention (see Borensztein and

    Mauro 2004 for a recent and comprehensive review). In a series of contributions, Caballero

    and a set of collaborators have advocated other types of state-contingent instruments (see

    Caballero and Cowan 2007 for an overview of this line of work). On the liabilities side, a

    commodities exporter might issue debt with a coupon that is indexed to global commodity

    prices. More broadly, emerging markets might tie yields to the high-risk spread in the US

    corporate debt market. The virtue of these types of instruments is that the contingent

    element in the return is a function of external conditions, such that it cannot be manip-

    ulated by the issuer. This feature eliminates the moral hazard problem that generically

    aects state-contingent contracts. There is also scope for greater use of state-contingent

    instruments on the asset side of the international balance sheet, since many of the risk

    sharing benets of state-contingent liabilities can be replicated by an appropriate portfolio

    of assets. However, the limitation of an asset-based approach is that, all else equal, it

    involves the leveraging of the international balance sheet.

    A second key element is to further promote international equity nancing. As indicated

    earlier, the share of equity in the foreign liabilities of emerging markets has grown strongly

    over the last decade. However, corporate governance and regulatory problems limit the

    attractiveness of emerging-market stockmarkets for many investors (see, for example, the

    evidence provided by Kho et al 2008). However, the evidence is that nancial reformis associated with an increase in the equity share in liabilities, such that investors do

    8 This is not to under-estimate the regulatory and market design challenges in establishing a well-

    functioning derivatives market. Again, the current crisis teaches us that poorly-functioning derivatives

    markets can lead to non-fundamental volatility in the prices of the underlying assets.

    11

  • 8/6/2019 Cepr Governance

    13/34

    respond to shifts in the institutional environment (Faria et al 2007). Similar factors also

    apply in relation to foreign direct investment. In addition, there are restrictions in some

    countries that limit the capacity of foreign investors to acquire controlling stakes in certain

    sectors that are deemed to be strategically important. However, in the other direction, it

    is possible that the level of subsidies and tax breaks oered to foreign direct investors is

    arguably excessive in a number of host countries, such that some shift away from foreign

    direct investment could be desirable in some cases.

    The importance of domestic institutional development extends beyond the nancial

    sector. In particular, a fundamental goal for emerging market economies is to copperfasten

    stability in macroeconomic policies. In relation to scal procyclicality, institutional reforms

    can do much to improve the cyclical behaviour of scal policy (Lane 2003). While there

    remains considerable variation across countries, the capacity of countries such as Chile to

    develop scal processes that help to insulate the budget from the curse of procyclicality

    has been impressive.

    So far, we have discussed domestic reforms. An extension of this is to further pro-

    mote regional nancial integration. The empirical evidence is that gravity factors such as

    distance and cultural linkages are inuential in international asset trade (Portes and Rey

    2005, Lane and Milesi-Ferretti 2008b). In addition, there is a strongly positive correlation

    between trade in goods and services and trade in assets. Accordingly, there is much scope

    for regional levels of nancial integration. In particular, regional capital ows may be more

    stable in character, in view of the underlying linkages between neighbouring economies and

    the lower level of bilateral exchange rate volatility. Accordingly, it is desirable that regional

    groups intensify eorts to cooperate in the design of common institutional standards fornancial market development and work to lift barriers to cross-border asset trade.

    Turning to the international dimension of reform, there is considerable scope for the

    international community to support a more stable system of international nance for emerg-

    ing market economies. The international nancial institutions have a clear role to play in

    12

  • 8/6/2019 Cepr Governance

    14/34

    terms of the provision of technical advice in the development of domestic nancial systems.

    For instance, in relation to local-currency debt markets, the World Banks GEMLOC pro-

    gram seeks to build a common knowledge base concerning the operation of these markets. 9

    The IFIs could possibly do more in terms of issuing securities in the currencies of the

    emerging market economies. Such issues have the potential to help to expand the depth

    and liquidity of the domestic-currency bond markets, as well as allowing the international

    nancial institutions to make local-currency loans to clients in those markets. Such issuance

    could be in specic currencies, such as the RMB-denominated bond issues by the Asian

    Development Bank and the International Finance Corporation (the so-called Panda Bonds).

    In addition, securities could be issued that are indexed to a basket of emerging market

    currencies (see also the discussion in Wolf 2009). More generally, in view of the free riding

    problem and other externalities that inhibit the creation of new securities markets, the IFIs

    potentially have a central role in helping to develop the types of state-contingent securities

    that may improve the risk prole of the external liabilities of emerging markets.

    The current crisis has vividly illustrated how public sources of funding must be available

    in the event of the breakdown of nancial trade among private-sector counterparties. In

    this respect, two major innovations stand out in terms of the expansion of public funding

    for cross-border transactions. First, there has been the establishment of currency swap

    arrangements among the worlds major central banks and also vis-a-vis selected emerging

    market economies.10 As is discussed by Obstfeld et al (2009), the currency swaps with

    emerging market economies have typically been with countries that have already very

    high levels of reserves. Accordingly, the main function of the swaps has been to signal

    the commitment of the participating central banks to ensure adequate foreign-currency9 GEMLOC stands for Global Emerging Market Local Currency Bond Fund Program.

    10 See McGuire (2009) for an illuminating analysis of the global dollar shortage that was created by

    international banks seeking to obtain dollar funding for the very large dollar asset positions that expanded

    rapidly in recent years.

    13

  • 8/6/2019 Cepr Governance

    15/34

    liquidity for the countries in question.

    Second, the IMF created the new Short-Term Liquidity Facility (SLF) that is available

    to those member countries that have previously demonstrated strong fundamentals in terms

    of sound policies, access to capital markets and sustainable debt burdens. Since it relies

    on the track record of the applicant, the funds can be disbursed quickly and without

    conditionality, such that the SLF has the potential to be helpful in tackling short-term

    liquidity diculties. Accordingly, the SLF represents a potentially useful expansion in the

    range of instruments available to the IMF in dealing with liquidity problems. However, as

    with any public liquidity facility, the SLF faces the stigma problem, by which a country

    may be reluctant to tap these funds in fear of the negative signal that such a move would

    send to the markets.

    More generally, the disruption in private capital ows reinforces the need for an ex-

    pansion of the funding base for the IMF. In tandem with a redistribution of quotas, it is

    appropriate that the largest emerging market economies join the advanced economies in

    becoming substantial underwriters of the IMFs balance sheet. A better-nanced IMF that

    stood ready to provide liquidity support would enable these economies to shed some of

    their excess foreign-currency reserves and would be collectively more ecient. Accordingly,

    the principle of major IMF renewal should be a key governance target.

    That said, it is unlikely that major IMF reform can be achieved in the short term. The

    recent agreement to reallocate quotas in a limited fashion took a considerable period to

    be negotiated and has not yet been ratied by all member countries. A major shift in the

    distribution of voting power at the IMF requires leadership by those regions that are cur-

    rently over-represented, with the obvious potential for the consolidation of representationby member countries of the European Union.

    The expansion of IMF resources need not wait for the completion of governance reform.

    Already, Japan has oered $100 billion in nancing for the IMF, while other major surplus

    economies may also be prepared to oer extra funding. Such funding sources should

    14

  • 8/6/2019 Cepr Governance

    16/34

    be explored in tandem with accelerated eorts to engineer a more radical shift in quota

    allocations.

    The current crisis has also revealed a major analytical failure in under-estimating the

    risks embedded in the rapid increase in nancial balance sheets over 2002-2007. It is

    important that the appropriate lessons from this episode be drawn and the IMF is best

    positioned to conduct the research that analyses the sources of the crisis from a global

    perspective. In turn, the IMF has a role to play in developing new analytical frameworks

    to better understand international nancial linkages and in establishing a common level

    of understanding across the member countries. As is emphasised by Eichengreen (2008),

    this is a prerequisite for enabling any substantive level of policy coordination. Indeed, the

    2006-2007 multilateral consultation process on global imbalances can be understood in this

    way, as a mechanism to improve mutual understanding of the policy goals of the dierent

    participants and identify areas of potential analytical disagreement. While such initiatives

    do not immediately translate into coordinated policy decisions, the central role of national

    governments in policy delivery means that a new framework for global nancial governance

    must build linkages between national governments and the IMF, in addition to the functions

    that can be addressed through supra-national institutions and purely inter-governmental

    cooperative initiatives.

    Improved analysis of global imbalances would be greatly facilitated by renewed eorts

    to improve the collection of publicly-available high-quality data on international capital

    ows and international investment positions. While data availability has improved with

    initiatives such as the Coordinated Portfolio Investment Survey (CPIS), major data holes

    remain. Indeed, measurement problems are growing in absolute scale, due to the rapidgrowth in the volume of cross-border transactions and the pace of nancial innovation. Lane

    and Milesi-Ferretti (2009) have shown the extent of measurement problems in analysing

    the US external position, while it is evident that there are substantial data problems in

    understanding the international balance sheets of major emerging market economies. A

    15

  • 8/6/2019 Cepr Governance

    17/34

    major target must be to improve the quality of data concerning capital ows that are

    intermediated through oshore nancial centres, in view of the very limited data availability

    for these entitites.

    In addition to the roles played by the international nancial institutions, there is also

    room for a greater level of inter-governmental cooperation in regulating the global nancial

    system. Angeloni (2008) provides an interesting study of the relative merits of dierent

    vehicles for international policy coordination. To a degree, the global debate mirrors the

    shifting preferences within the European Union concerning the conditions under which it

    is appropriate to delegate powers to a supranational organisation such as the European

    Commission or the European Central Bank versus decisions that are better reserved for

    inter-governmental negotiation.Most recently, the focus has been on coordinating reforms

    of national regulatory systems through the activities of the Financial Stability Forum. In

    relation to international capital ows, one element in these reforms could be to achieve

    a coordinated response to the treatment of foreign-currency claims by domestic nancial

    institutions. In particular, it is worth investigating whether there are regulatory barriers

    that unncessarily deter nancial institutions in the advanced economies from holding claims

    that are denominated in the currencies of the emerging market economies (see also Portes

    2009).

    In addition to reform of the global nancial institutions, there is also room for a greater

    level of regional initiatives. The limits to the potential resources of the IMF and the

    heterogeneity of IMF membership means that there is scope for additional resource pooling

    at the regional level.11 Most obviously, the bilateral swap arrangements among ASEAN+3

    countries under the Chiang Mai Initiative demonstrate the viability of securing liquidityinsurance that is additional to IMF resources.12 Moreover, the current crisis has also shown

    11 See Irwin et al (2008) for a model of how diversity across countries limits the capacity of the IMF to

    function as a credit union.12 See Kohlscheen and Taylor (2008) for an analysis of the Chiang Mai bilateral swap arrangements. In

    line with a risk pooling model, these authors nd that bilateral swaps among participants are larger, the

    16

  • 8/6/2019 Cepr Governance

    18/34

    a regional capability to quickly respond to the shift in international nancial conditions.

    For example, major increases in the scale of the agreed bilateral swaps between China

    and Korea and between Japan and Korea were announced in December 2008. There is

    also room for the regional development banks to provide additional nancing in those cases

    where private-sector credit markets have broken down.

    Regional groupings may also be better placed in terms of continuous surveillance of

    member country policies and in designing multi-dimensional forms of policy coordination,

    by which regional integration in trade and factor mobility reinforces the incentives to co-

    operate in terms of nancial support.13 The European experience also suggests that there

    may be scope for regional cooperation in the development of processes that help in ensuring

    the sustainability of the public nances (Lane 2008). While the scope for political inte-

    gration clearly varies across regions and limits the transferability of institutional models

    across regions, the general principle is to obtain those benets from regional integration

    that are feasible in each particular setting.

    Finally, it is important to appreciate that a broad reform programme at the domestic

    and international levels could lead to a major re-conguration of the distribution of global

    imbalances. In particular, the growing share of global GDP that is generated by emerging

    market economies in combination with successful domestic nancial development and ap-

    propriate international nancial reforms may lead to this group of countries seeking to be

    a major net absorber of global capital ows.14 If this scenario plays out, other potential

    weaker the correlation in reserves between the pair of countries. However, these authors also highlight the

    limitations of a regional approach to risk pooling: the correlation in reserves growth is much higher within

    regions than across regions.

    13 The Chiang Mai agreement among the ASEAN+3 (China, Japan, Korea) provides for short-term

    currency swap facilities. This agreement demonstrates the ability of governments to agree on forms of

    policy coordination even when the level of political integration is quite low. See Lane (2008) on the lessons

    to be drawn from the European approach to economic integration.14 Dollar and Kraay (2006) calibrate a model that projects current account decits for China on the order

    of 5 percent of its GDP for a sustained 10-15 year period. While not approaching the size of the current US

    17

  • 8/6/2019 Cepr Governance

    19/34

    borrowers will receive smaller net capital inows and/or the level of global interest rates

    will climb. For advanced economies seeking to save due to population ageing, this should

    be a welcome development.

    4 Conclusions

    The self-insurance strategy adopted by many emerging market economies over the last

    decade have been only partially successful in reducing exposure to international nancial

    shocks. However, the limited role of domestic-currency debt in the funding of external liabil-

    ities means that the nature of international nancial integration for the emerging marketeconomies remains quite dierent relative to the experience of the advanced economies.

    Moreover, the self-insurance approach is collectively inecient in terms of the allocation

    of resources within the emerging market economies and between the emerging markets

    and the advanced economies. Moreover, the expansion in the gross scale of international

    balance sheets means that the linkages between the emerging market economies and the

    advanced economies have grown tighter, in terms of the exposure to breakdowns in the

    normal operation of nancial markets.

    Accordingly, there is a busy reform agenda at the domestic, regional and global levels

    in order to develop a nancial system that improves the stability of external nancing

    for emerging market economies. The reforms that will benet the emerging markets are

    also the reforms that should improve global economic performance and global nancial

    stability. Accordingly, improving the institutional framework that underpins international

    capital ows should be a priority for global reform eorts.

    decit relative to world GDP, it would still be a substantial call on global savings. See also the discussion

    in Lane and Schmukler (2007).

    18

  • 8/6/2019 Cepr Governance

    20/34

    References

    [1] Angeloni, Ignazio (2008), Testing Times for Global Financial Governance, Bruegel

    Essay and Lecture Series.

    [2] Borensztein, Eduardo and Paolo Mauro (2004), The Case for GDP-Indexed Bonds,

    Economic Policy, 38, 165216.

    [3] Burger, John and Frank Warnock (2006), Local Currency Bond Markets, IMF Sta

    Papers 53, 115-132.

    [4] Caballero, Ricardo and Arvind Krishnamurthy (2009), Global Imbalances and Fi-nancial Fragility, mimeo, MIT and Northwestern University.

    [5] Caballero, Ricardo and Kevin Cowan (2007), Financial Integration Without the

    Volatility, mimeo, MIT and Inter-American Development Bank.

    [6] Caballero, Ricardo, Emmanuel Farhi and Pierre-Olivier Gourinchas (2008), An Equi-

    librium Model of Global Imbalances and Low Interest Rates, American Economic

    Review 98(1), 358-393.

    [7] Calvo, Guillermo A., Leonardo Leiderman and Carmen Reinhart (1996), Capital

    Flows to Developing Countries in the 1990s: Causes and Eects, Journal of Economic

    Perspectives 10, 123-139.

    [8] Calvo, Guillermo A., Alejandro Izquierdo and Luis-Fernando Meja (2008), Systemic

    Sudden Stops: The Relevance Of Balance-Sheet Eects And Financial Integration,

    NBER Working Paper No. 14026.

    [9] Dollar, David and Aart Kraay (2006), Neither a Borrower Nor a Lender: Does Chinas

    Zero Net Foreign Asset Position Make Economic Sense?, Journal of Monetary Eco-

    nomics 53(5), 943-971.

    19

  • 8/6/2019 Cepr Governance

    21/34

    [10] Eichengreen, Barry (2008), Should There Be a Coordinated Response to the Problem

    of Global Imbalances? Can There Be One?, United Nations DESA Working Paper

    No. 69.

    [11] Eichengreen, Barry and Ricardo Hausmann (2005), Other Peoples Money: Debt De-

    nomination and Financial Instability in Emerging Market Economies, University of

    Chicago Press.

    [12] European Central Bank (2009), Foreign Asset Accumulation by Authorities in Emerg-

    ing Markets, Monthly Bulletin (January), 73-85.

    [13] Faria, Andre, Philip R. Lane, Paulo Mauro and Gian Maria Milesi-Ferretti (2007),

    The Shifting Composition of External Liabilities, Journal of European Economic

    Association 5 (2-3), 480-490.

    [14] Felices, Guillermo and Bjorn-Erik Orskaug (2008), Estimating the Determinants of

    Capital Flows to Emerging Market Economies: A Maximum Likelihood Disequilibrium

    Approach, Bank of England Working Paper No. 354.

    [15] Irwin, Gregor, Adrian Penalver, Chris Salmon and Ashley Taylor (2008), Dealing with

    Country Diversity: Challenges for the IMF Credit Union Model, Bank of England

    Working Paper No. 349.

    [16] Kaminsky, Graciela, Carmen Reinhart and Carlos Vgh (2003), The Unholy Trinity

    of Financial Contagion, Journal of Economic Perspectives 17(4), 51-74.

    [17] Kho, Bong-Chan, Rene Stulz and Frank Warnock (2008), Financial Globalization,Governance, and the Evolution of the Home Bias, Journal of Accounting Research,

    forthcoming.

    20

  • 8/6/2019 Cepr Governance

    22/34

    [18] Kohlscheen, Emanuel and Mark P. Taylor (2008), International Liquidity Swaps:

    Is the Chiang Mai Initiative Pooling Reserves Eciently? International Journal of

    Finance & Economics 13(4), 323 - 332.

    [19] Kose, M. Ayhan, Eswar Prasad, Kenneth Rogo and Shang-Jin Wei (2008), Financial

    Globalization: A Reappraisal, IMF Sta Papers, forthcoming.

    [20] Krugman, Paul (2008), The International Finance Multiplier, mimeo, Princeton

    University.

    [21] Lane, Philip R. (2008), The Macroeconomics of Financial Integration: A European

    Perspective, IIIS Discussion Paper No. 265.

    [22] Lane, Philip R. (2009), The Global Crisis and Capital Flows to Emerging Market

    Economies, mimeo, Trinity College Dublin.

    [23] Lane, Philip R. and Gian Maria Milesi-Ferretti (2007a), The External Wealth of

    Nations Mark II, Journal of International Economics 73, 223-250

    [24] Lane, Philip R. and Gian Maria Milesi-Ferretti (2007b), Europe and Global Imbal-

    ances, Economic Policy 22(51), 519-573.

    [25] Lane, Philip R. and Gian Maria Milesi-Ferretti (2008a), The Drivers of Financial

    Globalization, American Economic Review (Papers and Proceedings) 98(2), 327-332.

    [26] Lane, Philip R. and Gian Maria Milesi-Ferretti (2008b), International Investment

    Patterns, Review of Economics and Statistics 90(3), 538-549.

    [27] Lane, Philip R. and Gian Maria Milesi-Ferretti (2009), Where Did All the Borrowing

    Go? A Forensic Analysis of the U.S. External Position, Journal of Japanese and

    International Economies, forthcoming.

    21

  • 8/6/2019 Cepr Governance

    23/34

    [28] Lane, Philip R. and Sergio Schmukler (2007), The Evolving Role of China and India

    in the International Financial System, Open Economies Review 18(4), 499-520.

    [29] Lane, Philip R. and Jay Shambaugh (2008), Financial Exchange Rates and Interna-

    tional Currency Exposures, American Economic Review, forthcoming.

    [30] McGuire, Patrick and Nikola Tarashev (2008), Bank Health and Lending to Emerging

    Markets, BIS Quarterly Review (December), 67-80.

    [31] McGuire, Patrick (2009), The US Dollar Shortage in International Banking, BIS

    Quarterly Review, forthcoming.

    [32] Milesi-Ferretti, Gian Maria (2008), Fundamentals at Odds? The US Current Account

    Decit and the Dollar, Economic Notes 37(3), 259-281.

    [33] Milesi-Ferretti, Gian Maria (2009), A $2 Trillion Dollars Question, VoxEU.

    [34] Naughton, Barry (2006), Top-Down Control: SASAC and the Persistence of State

    Ownership in China, mimeo, University of California at San Diego.

    [35] Obstfeld, Maurice, Jay Shambaugh and Alan Taylor (2008), Financial Stability, the

    Trilemma, and International Reserves, NBER Working Paper No. 14217.

    [36] Obstfeld, Maurice, Jay Shambaugh and Alan Taylor (2009), Financial Instability,

    Reserves, and Central Bank Swap Lines in the Panic of 2008, American Economic

    Review (Papers and Proceedings), forthcoming.

    [37] Portes, Richard (2009), Global Imbalances, mimeo, London Business School.

    [38] Portes, Richard and Helene Rey (2005), The Determinants of Cross-Border Equity

    Flows, Journal of International Economics 65, 269-296.

    [39] Prasad, Eswar (2009), Indias Approach to Capital Account Liberalizaton, IZA Dis-

    cussion Paper No. 3927.

    22

  • 8/6/2019 Cepr Governance

    24/34

    [40] Reinhart, Carmen and Kenneth Rogo (2004), Serial Default And The Paradox Of

    Rich To Poor Capital Flows, American Economic Review (Papers and Proceedings)

    94(2), 52-58.

    [41] Reinhart, Carmen and Vincent Reinhart (2008), Capital Flow Bonanzas: An Encom-

    passing View of the Past and Present, NBER Working Paper No. 14321.

    [42] Schmitz, Martin (2009), Financial Reforms and Capital Flows to Emerging Europe,

    IIIS Discussion Paper No. 278.

    [43] Spilimbergo, Antonio, Steven Symansky, Olivier Blanchard and Carlo Cottarelli

    (2008), Fiscal Policy for the Crisis, IMF Sta Position Note No. 08/01.

    [44] Tressel, Thierry and Enrica Detragiache (2008), Do Financial Sector Reforms Lead

    to Financial Development? Evidence from a New Dataset, IMF Working Paper No

    08/265.

    [45] Wolf, Martin (2009), Fixing Global Finance, Yale University Press.

    23

  • 8/6/2019 Cepr Governance

    25/34

  • 8/6/2019 Cepr Governance

    26/34

    Net Foreign Asset PositionsWEO October 2008

    1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013

    -9

    -7

    -5

    -3

    -1

    1

    3

    5

    7

    9

    1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013

    -9

    -7

    -5

    -3

    -1

    1

    3

    5

    7

    9

    United StatesEuro AreaJapanEmerging AsiaOil Exporters

    Figure 2: Net Foreign Asset Positions. Source: World Economic Outlook (October 2008).

    25

  • 8/6/2019 Cepr Governance

    27/34

    International Financial Integration (% of GDP)

    0

    20

    40

    60

    80

    100

    120

    140

    1970

    1971

    1972

    1973

    1974

    1975

    1976

    1977

    1978

    1979

    1980

    1981

    1982

    1983

    1984

    1985

    1986

    1987

    1988

    1989

    1990

    1991

    1992

    1993

    1994

    1995

    1996

    1997

    1998

    1999

    2000

    2001

    2002

    2003

    2004

    2005

    2006

    2007

    Figure 3: International Financial Integration Ratio. Note: Sum of foreign assets and

    liabilities, expressed as a ratio to GDP. Group of major emerging market economies. Source:

    Authors calculations based on updated version of dataset compiled by Lane and Milesi-

    Ferretti (2007a).

    26

  • 8/6/2019 Cepr Governance

    28/34

    Share of Equity Liabilities (% of total liabilities)

    0

    10

    20

    30

    40

    50

    60

    70

    1970

    1971

    1972

    1973

    1974

    1975

    1976

    1977

    1978

    1979

    1980

    1981

    1982

    1983

    1984

    1985

    1986

    1987

    1988

    1989

    1990

    1991

    1992

    1993

    1994

    1995

    1996

    1997

    1998

    1999

    2000

    2001

    2002

    2003

    2004

    2005

    2006

    2007

    Figure 4: Equity Share in Foreign Liabilities. Note: Group of major emerging market

    economies. Source: Authors calculations based on updated version of dataset compiled by

    Lane and Milesi-Ferretti (2007a).

    27

  • 8/6/2019 Cepr Governance

    29/34

    year

    EMs: Portfolio SharesCPIS

    2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 20071

    2

    3

    4

    5

    6

    7

    8

    9

    10

    EquityDebt

    Figure 5: Portfolio Allocations to Major Emerging Markets. Note: Portfolio holdings of

    major investor nations (US, UK, Euro Area, Japan) in major emerging markets (Argentina,

    Brazil, Mexico, Turkey, South Africa, Russia, Saudi Arabia, India, Indonesia, China, Ko-

    rea). Source: Authors calculations based on IMFs Coordinated Portfolio Investment

    Survey.

    28

  • 8/6/2019 Cepr Governance

    30/34

    Foreign Exchange Reserves (% of GDP)

    0

    5

    10

    15

    20

    25

    30

    1970

    1971

    1972

    1973

    1974

    1975

    1976

    1977

    1978

    1979

    1980

    1981

    1982

    1983

    1984

    1985

    1986

    1987

    1988

    1989

    1990

    1991

    1992

    1993

    1994

    1995

    1996

    1997

    1998

    1999

    2000

    2001

    2002

    2003

    2004

    2005

    2006

    2007

    Figure 6: Foreign Exchange Reserves. Note: Group of major emerging market economies.

    Source: Authors calculations based on updated version of dataset compiled by Lane and

    Milesi-Ferretti (2007a).

    29

  • 8/6/2019 Cepr Governance

    31/34

    Advanced G17

    (1995)

    Advanced G17

    (2007)

    Emerging G17

    (1995)

    Emerging G17

    (2007)

    -35

    -30

    -25

    -20

    -15

    -10

    -5

    0

    5

    10

    15

    20

    -20 -15 -10 -5 0 5 10 15 20 25

    Net Debt

    Net Equity

    Figure 7: Composition of External Balance Sheets. Note: Advanced G17 comprises US,

    UK, Euro Area, Japan and Canada. Emerging G17 is group of major emerging market

    economies. Source: Authors calculations based on updated version of dataset compiled by

    Lane and Milesi-Ferretti (2007a).

    30

  • 8/6/2019 Cepr Governance

    32/34

    Net Foreign Assets (% of GDP)

    -25

    -20

    -15

    -10

    -5

    0

    1970

    1971

    1972

    1973

    1974

    1975

    1976

    1977

    1978

    1979

    1980

    1981

    1982

    1983

    1984

    1985

    1986

    1987

    1988

    1989

    1990

    1991

    1992

    1993

    1994

    1995

    1996

    1997

    1998

    1999

    2000

    2001

    2002

    2003

    2004

    2005

    2006

    2007

    Figure 8: Net Foreign Asset Position. Note: Group of major emerging market economies.

    Source: Authors calculations based on updated version of dataset compiled by Lane and

    Milesi-Ferretti (2007a).

    31

  • 8/6/2019 Cepr Governance

    33/34

    Current Account (% of GDP)

    -3

    -2

    -1

    0

    1

    2

    3

    4

    5

    1970

    1971

    1972

    1973

    1974

    1975

    1976

    1977

    1978

    1979

    1980

    1981

    1982

    1983

    1984

    1985

    1986

    1987

    1988

    1989

    1990

    1991

    1992

    1993

    1994

    1995

    1996

    1997

    1998

    1999

    2000

    2001

    2002

    2003

    2004

    2005

    2006

    2007

    Figure 9: Current Account Balances. Note: Group of major emerging market economies.

    Source: Authors calculations based on data from International Monetary Fund.

    32

  • 8/6/2019 Cepr Governance

    34/34

    Table 1: International Currency Exposures

    FXAGG

    Arg. Brazil China India Indo. Korea M exico Russia S.A rabia S.Africa Tur.

    1995 -0.01 -0.13 0.15 -0.48 -0.56 0.00 -0.32 -0.02 0.59 0.02 -0.42

    1996 0.01 -0.13 0.19 -0.42 -0.48 -0.05 -0.25 0.06 0.64 0.05 -0.38

    1997 0.02 -0.17 0.26 -0.36 -0.55 -0.11 -0.20 0.13 0.58 0.10 -0.341998 -0.01 -0.24 0.31 -0.33 -0.52 -0.01 -0.22 0.01 0.48 0.20 -0.36

    1999 0.02 -0.21 0.33 -0.27 -0.46 0.04 -0.20 0.06 0.48 0.27 -0.32

    2000 0.02 -0.19 0.38 -0.21 -0.47 0.15 -0.15 0.17 0.54 0.31 -0.38

    2001 -0.06 -0.17 0.37 -0.16 -0.46 0.15 -0.08 0.19 0.58 0.31 -0.34

    2002 -0.08 -0.18 0.41 -0.07 -0.40 0.16 -0.09 0.24 0.63 0.29 -0.32

    2003 -0.05 -0.12 0.43 0.03 -0.35 0.19 -0.09 0.22 0.66 0.33 -0.30

    2004 -0.03 -0.05 0.43 0.07 -0.33 0.24 -0.06 0.23 0.72 0.34 -0.24

    NETFX

    Arg. Brazil China India Indo. Korea M exico Russia S.A rabia S.Africa Tur.

    1995 -0.01 -0.07 0.08 -0.22 -0.42 0.00 -0.19 -0.01 0.68 0.01 -0.32

    1996 0.01 -0.06 0.10 -0.16 -0.38 -0.02 -0.27 0.05 0.66 0.03 -0.27

    1997 0.02 -0.08 0.14 -0.15 -0.43 -0.06 -0.19 0.10 0.58 0.07 -0.25

    1998 -0.01 -0.13 0.19 -0.13 -0.42 0.00 -0.19 0.01 0.50 0.16 -0.27

    1999 0.02 -0.13 0.22 -0.11 -0.94 0.04 -0.17 0.08 0.58 0.26 -0.26

    2000 0.02 -0.17 0.27 -0.09 -0.71 0.15 -0.14 0.36 0.59 0.48 -0.40

    2001 -0.07 -0.14 0.26 -0.07 -0.57 0.13 -0.06 0.32 0.58 0.45 -0.36

    2002 -0.10 -0.16 0.30 -0.03 -0.48 0.15 -0.07 0.37 0.67 0.37 -0.43

    2003 -0.16 -0.11 0.32 0.01 -0.36 0.18 -0.06 0.34 0.69 0.47 -0.34

    2004 -0.07 -0.06 0.34 0.04 -0.31 0.25 -0.05 0.35 0.76 0.43 -0.26

    Note: FXAGG is scaled between (-1,1) and denotes the aggregate foreign currency exposure for

    a given level of foreign assets and liabilities; NETFX(= FXAGG IFI) is ratio of net foreign-

    currency assets to GDP. Source: Authors calculations based on dataset compiled by Lane and

    Shambaugh (2008).