Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: The Example … · 2017-07-28 · Causes...

26
1 © Professor Rowley Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: The Example of South Korea © Professor Chris Rowley* & Dr Kiu Sik Bae** *Director, Centre for Research on Asian Management, City University, London, UK; Director of Research and Publications, HEAD Foundation, Singapore ** Research Fellow, Korea Labour Institute, Seoul, Korea Here we follow on from our earlier preliminary piece (Waxing and waning of waves of anti- unionism in South Korea’) on Cass Knowledge (https://www.cassknowledge.com/research/article/waxing-and-waning-waves-anti- unionism-south-korea ). We report on the next phase of our work and research. 1. Background The history of trade unions, membership, structure and types in South Korea (‘Korea’ for shorthand from now on) indicates a rocky path. In the 19 th century wage earners began to appear and the early labour movement was led mainly by miners and dockers with the Sungjin Dock Workers Union in 1898 the first union. The factory system started and Japanese colonisation (1910-45) propelled modern production systems and an increase in factory workers and labour organisations. Employers exploited and discriminated against Korean workers. Labour leaders and activities were strongly oppressed under Japanese rule. Thus, labour leaders undertook underground activities and most of the labour movement cooperated with the socialists. Therefore, the labour movement was anti-foreign capital and defiant toward employers and government and was connected with the independence movement. Following independence in 1945 the trade unions were divided by ideology into two national centres: the rightist Korea Federation of Trade Unions (KFTU) and the leftist National Councils of Korea Trade Unions (NCKTU, the ‘Junpyung’). The NCKTU had been originally much stronger, but was weakened by both its own militant strategies and also the ‘red purge’ of the newly formed government and rightwing forces. The NCKTU was finally outlawed and destroyed just before, and during, the Korean War of 1950-53(Kim 1993). The Korean War and the division of the Korean peninsula were crucial factors contributing to the evolution of an authoritarian industrial relations environment. Many trade union leaders had connections with the communists and there was a strong ideological legacy of anti-

Transcript of Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: The Example … · 2017-07-28 · Causes...

Page 1: Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: The Example … · 2017-07-28 · Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: ... (1910-45) propelled modern production

1

© Professor Rowley

Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: The Example of South Korea ©

Professor Chris Rowley* & Dr Kiu Sik Bae**

*Director, Centre for Research on Asian Management, City University, London, UK; Director of Research and Publications, HEAD Foundation, Singapore ** Research Fellow, Korea Labour Institute, Seoul, Korea

Here we follow on from our earlier preliminary piece (‘Waxing and waning of waves of anti-

unionism in South Korea’) on Cass Knowledge

(https://www.cassknowledge.com/research/article/waxing-and-waning-waves-anti-

unionism-south-korea). We report on the next phase of our work and research.

1. Background

The history of trade unions, membership, structure and types in South Korea (‘Korea’ for

shorthand from now on) indicates a rocky path. In the 19th century wage earners began to

appear and the early labour movement was led mainly by miners and dockers with the

Sungjin Dock Workers Union in 1898 the first union. The factory system started and Japanese

colonisation (1910-45) propelled modern production systems and an increase in factory

workers and labour organisations. Employers exploited and discriminated against Korean

workers. Labour leaders and activities were strongly oppressed under Japanese rule. Thus,

labour leaders undertook underground activities and most of the labour movement cooperated

with the socialists. Therefore, the labour movement was anti-foreign capital and defiant

toward employers and government and was connected with the independence movement.

Following independence in 1945 the trade unions were divided by ideology into two national

centres: the rightist Korea Federation of Trade Unions (KFTU) and the leftist National

Councils of Korea Trade Unions (NCKTU, the ‘Junpyung’). The NCKTU had been originally

much stronger, but was weakened by both its own militant strategies and also the ‘red purge’

of the newly formed government and rightwing forces. The NCKTU was finally outlawed

and destroyed just before, and during, the Korean War of 1950-53(Kim 1993).

The Korean War and the division of the Korean peninsula were crucial factors contributing to

the evolution of an authoritarian industrial relations environment. Many trade union leaders

had connections with the communists and there was a strong ideological legacy of anti-

Page 2: Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: The Example … · 2017-07-28 · Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: ... (1910-45) propelled modern production

2

© Professor Rowley

communism. However, only the anti-communist labour movement was granted legal

approval. So-called ‘yellow’ or docile unions (with leaders controlled by management and the

authorities) developed. Immediately after the Korean War the government enacted the Trade

Union Act (TUA) 1953. There was US involvement and supported a business unionism

model.

With this as the legal basis of activities, unions were not able to escape political restrictions

under the oppressive political regime. Collective bargaining and union activities were strictly

restricted by laws (Kim 1993). Even researching and teaching about labour issues at colleges

and universities were restricted. With the destruction of the strong leftist labour movement

and a politically controlled labour regime in place, the authoritarian developmental state was

able to manoeuvre the labour-exclusive industrialisation strategy in the early 1960s to the

mid-1980s (Koo 2001).

Korea underwent ‘compressed’ industrialisation via export between the early 1960s and mid-

1980s. Industrial cities such as Gumi, Ulsan, Changwon, and Busan as well as big industrial

zones in Seoul, Inchon, Masan, were successively established during the period of industrial

transformation. Light, labour-intensive industries such as textiles and electronic assembly

industries which had developed in the early phase of industrialisation, were slowly replaced

by ship-building, steel, auto and petrochemical industries in its later phase. Industrialisation

gave rise to large numbers of workers concentrated in cities or industrial zones who may

sometimes have had collective complaints or demands on wages, inhumane treatment or

working conditions. Spatial concentration of industrial workers made those cities or zone a

futile potential ground for labour movement (Koo 2001).

In the face of this potential labour movement threat, the policy direction of the government

was to ensure industrial peace and minimize union influence. A key measure taken was to

force trade unions to affiliate to an industrial federation under a single, government-

sponsored, national centre. Thus, the KFTU was reorganized as the Federation of Korea

Trade Unions (FKTU) in the early 1960s. It played the role of a junior partner of the state and

management under the ‘growth first, distribution later’ and anti-communism stance and was

pro-government and management. A succession of legal revisions followed, mainly to

weaken union activities by tight control based on hierarchical labour-management

Page 3: Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: The Example … · 2017-07-28 · Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: ... (1910-45) propelled modern production

3

© Professor Rowley

relationships at the enterprise level.

Democracy in 1987 changed the political landscape with the ending of the military

government and marked a turning point for the trade union movement. A boom in

unionization (and strikes) followed. Such a growth of union organisation meant the former

employer-dominated industrial relations could not be sustained and trade unions became a

major player in national politics and the economy. The next major watershed was the 1997

Asian financial crisis and then the post-2008 global financial crisis.

The ebbs and flows of union numbers, membership and density over these critical events can

be seen in the table. In short, it shows the number of unions at a zenith in 1989 with nearly

8,000, nearly 2 million members and nearly 19% density. The trends in each of the three

aspects have fluctuated slightly since then but overall have fallen on each dimension, with

union numbers below 4,500, membership less 1.65 million than and density below 10% by

2010.

Table 1

Enterprise unionism is an essential part of the enterprise-based industrial relations system.

Enterprise unionism limits union membership only to employees belonging to particular

firms, in other words employee unionism (Kawanishi, 1989). Many aspects of anti-unionism

in Korea are closely associated with enterprise unionism. It is much easier for employers to

block workers of their firms from organising new unions, while rank-and-file workers face

serious difficulties in organising new unions at their own firms. Enterprise unions are

separate entities with their own rules and governance mechanisms, making coordination

much more difficult. Moreover, it is very difficult for enterprise unions at small and medium-

sized enterprises (SMEs). Many enterprise unions organised at SMEs until 1989 could not

survive on their own and had to dissolve themselves. Therefore, enterprise unionism has been

very much unfavourable to organising workers at SMEs, as indicated in the table.

Table 2

Page 4: Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: The Example … · 2017-07-28 · Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: ... (1910-45) propelled modern production

4

© Professor Rowley

Enterprise unionism has encouraged employers to exercise much stronger power or influence

to block unionisation than industrial, general or occupational unionism. Enterprise unionism

has been a major institutional barrier to organisation of workers at SMEs.

2. Various Forms of Anti-unionism in Korea

Anti-unionism in Korea has taken various forms and characteristics since the 1960s,

depending on the political context. First, there has been an institutionalised form of anti-

unionism. Governments had legal power to directly intervene in union affairs, such as union

organisation, elections and collective bargaining and industrial action in the name of national

security or public order (Kim 2002). The authorities were able to exercise veto power on

whether unions would be allowed or not. Apart from these interventions, the authorities were

able to crack down on or limit an independent trade union movement by mobilising

intelligence police and administrative means. They sometimes decided to dissolve unions

seen as independent.

Furthermore, labour law allowed only enterprise unions to be organised.1 This policy made it

very hard for workers at the workplace to organise unions because the policy did not allow

workers to join unions outside their firms but only to organise their own enterprise unions or

join enterprise unions if one already existed. The developmental state was itself a major

bulwark of this kind of anti-unionism by restricting union organising, and monitoring and

controlling union activities and union leaders through legislation.

Another strand of anti-unionist institution was the indirect election of union officers through

union delegates at each level, despite membership wishes to elect leaders by direct election.

Government and management, together with union officials at the FKTU and industrial

federations of trade unions, made indirect elections of union leaders into ‘custom and

practice’. While management and the authorities were able to control trade unions through

already docile, long-serving union leaders, the existing union officials preferred indirect

elections to direct ones to help keep their positions for a long time. Management, the

authorities and union officials were able to manipulate or intervene in indirect elections of

1. Enterprise unions are not solely related to government policies, but had some connection with labour market developments. Korea had little tradition of craft skills and did not see any developments in occupational labour markets during or after the industrialisation period. There had been few moves to regulate wages or working conditions in the regional or sectoral level by trade unions (Park, 1992).

Page 5: Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: The Example … · 2017-07-28 · Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: ... (1910-45) propelled modern production

5

© Professor Rowley

union leaders by first electing union delegates close to management. However, rank-and-file

members wanted to change union leaders docile to management and the authorities through

direct elections. The wish for direct elections of leaders surfaced into demands for union

democracy and direct election of leaders from 1987 onwards. Almost all unions which were

newly established after 1987 decided to have elections of their leaders as direct, while many

existing enterprise unions gradually changed elections from indirect to direct amid the

resistance of long-serving union leaders.

There was an important institutional element which was not necessarily anti-unionist in

orientation, but which was consequently harmful to the union movement. That is the

compulsory 3 years military service required for all young men. The military governments

before 1987 domesticated some resistance of young men by indoctrinating strong anti-

communism mingled with submission to the authoritarianism. The strong military discipline,

often accompanied by physical beatings, forced young men in their early 20s to be

submissive to authorities and in turn obediently accept control by management and the

regime, whether the control was legitimate or not. Military culture, which permeated

throughout the whole society, emphasised hierarchical order of despotic command and

control from the top, and contributed to patriachism in the workplace (Koo, 2001). Under the

military regime there were few male union leaders in the independent trade union movement,

whereas there were a number of female union leaders in the same movement. It was not until

1987 that a new generation of young male union leaders appeared.

The second form of anti-unionism is attitudinal. This took the form of opposition by both the

government and management to any attempt at establishing new enterprise unions, or electing

union leadership independent of existing unions’ orientation. They denied any independent

attempt at union organisation from below at the workplace, which was not informally granted

by authorities. The independent union movement was deemed to threaten the industrialisation

drive led by the government. Therefore, the authorities were very concerned with any move

to support an independent union movement by progressive Christian labour missionaries or

Catholic labour missionaries in the 1970s and early 1980s. The authorities denounced the

missionaries as a ‘third party’ for intervening in the labour movement. The authorities not

only denied independent trade unions, but also limited freedom of association and collective

bargaining (Kim, 2002). The state’s anti-unionist attitude did not change until 1987.

Page 6: Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: The Example … · 2017-07-28 · Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: ... (1910-45) propelled modern production

6

© Professor Rowley

New unions could be organised at the time only under FKTU guidance and with the condition

of the authorities’ informal recognition. These unions were not independent and were

dominated by existing union leaders or docile enterprise union leaders. Even if the authorities

informally granted union organisation at a certain firm, the management at the firm may have

been strongly opposed. Management often lobbied the authorities to block any effort of

organising unions at their own firms. Management efforts to keep firms from unionisation

was effective. Management’s anti-union attitudes remained strong, even after 1987.

Management’s anti-unionism became even stronger when they saw firms in the region or the

same sector coming under the pressure of strong enterprise unions to negotiate wage

agreements.

Since 2000 management’s strong opposition to industrial unions, especially to industrial

bargaining, was conspicuous. A significant number of enterprise unions in the metal industry,

hospitals and some of the public sector under the KCTU, reorganised themselves into

industrial unions. Management represented by the Korean Employers Federation or the

Federation of Korean Industries has worried about the rise of industrial unions and especially

attempts at industrial bargaining.

The third form of anti-unionism is ideology. With experience of the Korean War, anti-

communism ideology still remained very strong in society as a whole. The authorities and

management often used such ideology to prevent independent unions from being organised

by calling workers or their supporters socialists. The ideology of ‘economic growth first’ or

‘national revival through industrialisation’ was given the overwhelming priority to anything

from the 1960s onwards. An independent trade union movement would have hindered

economic growth or industrialisation altogether, according to the logic of the official

propaganda at the time. This kind of stance often discouraged workers from organising their

own independent unions. It was not until 1987 that workers really got over the fear of being

regarded as socialists or threatening social order or national security. However, there has

always been strong anti-unionism sentiments among management, which denies industrial

pluralism at the workplace or which regards unions as an obstacle to free markets, partly

because political and academic elites were educated and trained in the neo-liberal US,

especially from the 1980s onwards. Another prong of anti-unionist ideology has been

Page 7: Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: The Example … · 2017-07-28 · Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: ... (1910-45) propelled modern production

7

© Professor Rowley

continuous emphasis of management prerogatives on the part of employers, often supported

with legislation and administrative interpretations2 by the government.

The fourth form of anti-unionism has been management’s drive and often government

strategies to separate enterprise unions from the independent and often militant Korean

Confederation of Trade Unions (KCTU) from the late 1980s. Once management and the

government recognised enterprise unions, they wanted unions already affiliated to KCTU to

distance themselves and finally to withdraw from the KCTU. This anti-unionism among

management and government was fuelled through militant industrial action and frequent

attempts at general strikes by the KCTU and its member unions. Management often took

advantage of unsuccessful, often protracted, illegal strikes by their own enterprise unions

affiliated to the KCTU in order for the unions to withdraw from the KCTU in return for

ending strikes without many dismissals or discipline of union leaders.

The fifth form of anti-unionism involves alternatives to trade unions taken by management.

Management with strong anti-union attitudes have taken pre-emptive measures, such as

setting up labour-management councils (LMC) or staff councils instead of trade unions

(Rowley and Yoo, 2008). Management allowed LMCs to play a significant role, such as

collective bargaining, consultation, information sharing and direct election of labour

representatives on the councils, as long as they remained as LMCs. In contrast, the organising

of a union was been blocked by management with all means and costs. These LMCs at non-

union firms are supposed to be alternatives to trade unions. This kind of anti-unionism has

been favoured at the prominent Samsung Group, its sister group CJ, Posco and other business

groups over the years.

3. Anti-Unionism to the mid-1980s

There had been authoritarian rule under the military governments from the 1960s. Although

regular elections for the president and politicians took place and were rare windows of

2. Laws in Korea have the basic clauses and provisions. For their implementation they need subordinate statutes (Presidential Decree,  Ordinance of Prime Minister and Ordinance of Ministry). When it is still unclear how to implement laws after going through laws and their subordinate statutes and there are not any relevant legal cases by the court, it is mostly often the case that the course of action relies on administrative interpretations by the relevant department of the government. Administrative interpretations by the government sometimes have exercised strong power. The government had arbitrarily exercised these administrative interpretations to control unions and limit union activities until 1987.

Page 8: Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: The Example … · 2017-07-28 · Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: ... (1910-45) propelled modern production

8

© Professor Rowley

opportunities for democracy, civil rights were not guaranteed and political democracy was

crippled. The ‘economic growth first’ ideology meant trade unions were more likely to be

regarded as obstacles to the economic growth in the rapid industrialisation process by not

only employers but also the government and public media. Independent union leaders were

unilaterally excluded and expelled from trade unions by the government. Docile trade unions

which were cooperative with employers rather than representing workers' interests were

recognised by employers and government.

The government's authoritarianism involved selective policies towards labour. Individual

labour disputes were permitted to be raised and dealt with, but collective labour disputes were

oppressed or brokered by the authorities. Union organising activities had been active in the

late 1960s and 1970s among workers. While most unions organised under the guidance of the

officially recognised FKTU were given certificates and then often recognised from the 1960s,

other unions organised by workers below or with the support of outside organisations, such as

missionaries of churches and labour activists, were not given certificates and often crushed by

the authorities or management. The government allowed docile enterprise unions linked to

the FKTU, but cracked down on independent trade unions.

Even organising unions by the FKTU was often met by employers' strong opposition. There

was very little breathing room for an independent trade union movement to survive. Labour

missionaries of Protestant Churches and Catholic Churches, together with some progressive

intellectuals and student activists, helped independent unions survive amid the severe

oppression of the authorities and management in the 1970s and 1980s. A very small number

of trade unions remained independent of employers and the state despite tough political and

industrial conditions. Most leaders of those remaining independent unions interestingly were

female, whose leadership was based on internal union democracy and strong support from

their members. Those independent unions began to be called ‘Democratic Unions’ opposed to

the existing unions subservient to management and the authorities. There were many attempts

by the rank-and-file at democratising enterprise unions dominated by management in the

Page 9: Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: The Example … · 2017-07-28 · Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: ... (1910-45) propelled modern production

9

© Professor Rowley

1970s.3 However, most enterprise unions and their industrial federations of trade unions were

made docile by dominant employers and the oppressive state.

There was some potential strength built-up from the growing number of workers during the

rapid and compressed industrialization period. Indeed, even with the strong opposition of

employers and oppression by the state, more trade unions were organised by the existing

officially recognized trade unions, reflecting hope and complaints among rank-and-file

workers. Though activities were limited to a narrow range, trade unions were the only legal

means workers could rely on in order to increase wages and improve working conditions.

Up until 1987 anti-union drives were mainly led by the authorities rather than management to

prevent an independent trade union movement. The authorities were able to effectively

control the trade union movement, including a few independent unions and made them serve

economic growth and subservient to the authoritarian regimes. Management had not

developed anti-union policies very well, but rather relied on the authorities. A small number

of independent trade unions (called ‘democratic unions’ at the time) succeeded in surviving

in tough political and industrial environments and would become important later on. They

mobilised and developed many different forms of industrial action short of strikes to enhance

their bargaining power or to keep their independent unions from management attack or the

threat of the authorities. Those actions included wearing ribbons, overtime bans and lunch

sits-in at company canteens. Despite the anti-unionism by the authorities and management, a

small number of independent unions were able to resist and keep going.

We provide an example next. The Union of YH Trade was an independent union which faced

factory closures and with the help of the opposition party fought against management and

authorities. The struggle escalated into a serious political issue and it became an impetus to

the ending of the military regime. The experience of those few independent unions provided a

groundwork for many strong independent unions from 1987.

4. Independent Unions Overcoming Anti-unionism and New Anti-unionism, 1987-1997

3 Most enterprise unions organised after 1987 wanted to become ‘Democratic Unions’ and to differentiate themselves from the past disgraced ‘yellow’ unions. That is why the KCYU and its affiliates call themselves ‘Democratic Unions’.

Page 10: Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: The Example … · 2017-07-28 · Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: ... (1910-45) propelled modern production

10

© Professor Rowley

Political democratization in 1987 led to the sudden rise of many new independent trade

unions which overcame the strong anti-unionism of employers and government. Workers

emboldened in the political democratisation processes no longer feared anti-union institutions

and policies of the authorities and management and staged practically general strikes on a

national scale. A national wave of strikes swept nearly all medium and large workplaces.

Workers went on strike first and then successfully negotiated union recognition and

improvements in wages, working conditions and treatment of manual workers.

Figure 1

The successes of the strike at Hyundai Engine and Hyundai Heavy Industry in 1987

emboldened workers nationwide. Newly established independent enterprise unions rooted

their strong organisational basis in enterprises. The stronger presence of enterprise unions in

their workplaces enhanced their bargaining power by controlling their workplace. On the

other hand, the leadership of the existing moderate, docile trade unions (the FKTU and its

affiliates) recognised under the military government, was put to non-confidence votes or to

transform themselves into trade unions more responsive to rank-and-file workers’ demands.

The indirect elections of union leaders as the major obstacle to internal union democracy and

elections were reformed under pressure from below and direct elections of union leaders

adopted. Although the reform process of union elections was slow because of resistance to

keep positions, direct union elections by members brought more democratic governance,

especially of enterprise unions. Thus, the FKTU and its affiliate unions were reinvigorated

and able to strengthen their bargaining power.

There were many confrontations and strikes within workplaces revolving around trade union

recogniton. New unions were able to double wages and improve working conditions. The

push by strong trade unions continued until the 1997 Asian financial crisis. The exercise of

power by strong trade unions had significantly restricted employers' autonomy or

prerogatives at large firms. Employers and some government officials developed a new anti-

unionism in the face of powerful unions at their workplaces.

However, even under these kinds of favourable conditions to workers, some big employers

such as Samsung and Posco, were able to keep trade unions out by mobilising resources and

Page 11: Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: The Example … · 2017-07-28 · Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: ... (1910-45) propelled modern production

11

© Professor Rowley

other means. Some firms adopted the physical anti-unionism of the ‘Gusadae’ (‘squad to save

companies from trade union destructive strikes and activities’, that is, strike breakers).

Management organised workers who were relatives of owners or managers or were subject to

management for one reason or another, in opposition to new unions or strikes. Gusadae had

often tried to drive striking workers from factories who mostly occupied factories. It was

common that workers who went on strike mostly occupied their factories because

government only allowed strikes within factory gates to prevent strikes from developing into

street demonstrations. This practice of strikes accompanied by factory occupations, together

with the enterprise union system, actually paradoxically reinforced union presence in the

workplace.

Big businesses (the chaebol) have been very reluctant in recognising trade unions (Kwon and

O’Donnell, 2001). Their chairmen have never met or talked with trade union leaders, except a

very few occasions, When they were forced to negotiate with trade unions, they sent their

agents (chief executives) for negotiations or collective bargaining even if the chairmen still

held decision-making power. Anti-unionism among owners remained strong, even in

unionised firms. Owners of big business have dealt with trade unions behind the scene, but

have not directly been involved in negotiations with trade unions. They have not talked with

trade union leaders frankly and have not attempted to reach compromises by persuading or

listening to, union leaders.

Another important anti-unionism strand developed, a non-union form of representation,

which has been pursued and used by employers as a union avoidance strategy. Management

at non-union firms were able to use the existing institution of LMCs as alternatives to union

representation. LMCs have to be set up at all establishments with at least 30 employees,

regardless of whether unionised or not. Whether LMCs at non-union firms are established or

not and how much room or rights are allowed for employee representatives on LMCs, were

up to management.

Less than half of non-union establishments had LMCs at the end of 2009 (see Table). Large,

public sector and manufacturing establishments are more likely than others to have LMCs.

These employers at non-union firms have given employee representative of LMCs more

Page 12: Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: The Example … · 2017-07-28 · Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: ... (1910-45) propelled modern production

12

© Professor Rowley

rights and room for representing employees’ interest. They have sometimes provided time-off

facilities for employee representatives of the LMCs and given them collective bargaining

rights. These were pre-emptive measures or policies by non-union management to avoid

unions.

Table 3

So, not all LMCs at non-union firms are union avoidance means. As is indicated in Figure 1,

there are some five different types of employee representation at non-union firms through

LMCs. Some LMCs at non-union firms have played a role of proper employee representation

and do not act as union-replacing organisations. Union replacing LMCs have played more

active roles in representing employees’ interests, not by employees themselves but by

management to avoid unions. There are some blurred boundaries where LMCs can play the

role of either employ representation or union avoidance or both roles.

Figure 2

The anti-unionism of the Gusadae was not very successful in driving away trade unions or

striking workers out of the workplace. Gusadae were suspected of violating labour law by

being involved in ‘unfair labour practices’, such as direct intervention in union internal affairs,

violence towards strikers and helping pro-employer’s worker organisations in opposition to

unions at the workplace. Using Gusadae as a physical force to counter union strength at the

workplace was not a largely successful tactic.

However, the newly born union movement, especially the KCTU and its affiliated enterprise

unions, did not succeed in concluding a stable institutionalised industrial order based on

compromise with employers by heavily relying on a militant stance towards wage bargaining

or other issues and pursuing workers’ maximum interests. The moderate FKTU and its

affiliate unions were willing to make compromises with management in dealing with various

employment issues. During the period, anti-union feelings against the KCTU and its affiliates

among employers accumulated.

5. Retreating in the Midst Another Rise of Anti-Unionism Post-1997?

Page 13: Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: The Example … · 2017-07-28 · Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: ... (1910-45) propelled modern production

13

© Professor Rowley

There was a period of power deadlock during 1998-2007 in the middle of an increasing anti-

union climate, especially against the KCTU. There were a number of cases where violent

strikes and factory occupations by workers led to interventions by riot police to arrest strikers

and their leaders. After violent confrontation with employers and finally with the government

by occupying and controlling factories, the militant trade unions were often crushed by the

police and union leadership changed into moderate ones. The KCTU and its affiliated unions

confronted the government on labour law or government policies or the government

intervened in so-called illegal major strikes by mobilising the police. The KCTU called

general strikes 4–8 times a year in the late 1990s to the mid-2000s. Despite the shrinking

number of union members participating in general strikes and public opinion unfavourable to

militant union actions, the KCTU and its affiliated unions too often tried to resort to general

strikes.

Trade union density has fallen since 1990, partly because of industrial restructuring,

manufacturing relocation abroad (to Malaysia, China, Vietnam, Indonesia, etc) and the

expansion of the service sector, where it is difficult to organise trade unions. Also, the

confrontational style of the KCTU and its affiliated enterprise unions gave people a strong

impression that they were radical and confrontational.

Most working days lost were due to strikes by a few large enterprise unions, as indicated in

the table. More people became critical towards large enterprise unions for exercising their

strong power via frequent strikes. Too many attempts at general strikes by the KCTU and

frequent strikes by large unions brought strong negative responses not just from employers,

but also from the general public.

Table 4

Trade union structure based on enterprises has unintentionally contributed to the polarization

of labour markets between large and small firms and permanent and temporary workers in

terms of wages, benefits and working conditions (Rowley et al, 2011). This made public

opinion even more hostile toward militant trade unions at large firms – increasingly such

unions were isolated from public opinion. Now the KCTU and its affiliated unions were

Page 14: Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: The Example … · 2017-07-28 · Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: ... (1910-45) propelled modern production

14

© Professor Rowley

surrounded and viewed by most employers in a hostile perspective. Anti-union feelings

against the KCTU and its affiliates became even stronger among employers.

These anti-union feelings developed into anti-union behaviour by large businesses when

KCTU-affiliated enterprise unions became weaker for one reason or another. When KCTU

affiliated enterprise unions lost a protracted strike, management took advantage of the

opportunity and dismissed or disciplined union key leaders for illegally occupying factories

or obstructing operations. Management exchanged dismissals or discipline for withdrawal of

the enterprise union from the KCTU and thereby got the upper hand over unions. Anti-

unionism in these occasions took the form of enterprise unions subject to management at the

firms. There are many examples of big unions which withdrew from the KCTU and were

weakened.

However, we cannot lay the blame of this anti-unionism only on employers at those firms.

The militancy of KCTU affiliated unions often provoked employers and triggered anti-

unionism among big employers. Big buisnesses sometimes encouraged militant enterprise

unions to go on strike, trapped unions in negotiation deadlock and intentionally protracted

strikes without compromise. Despite significant losses, employers prepared for long strikes

and the unions were entrapped and increasingly lost the strength of unity among their

membership. Divisions among their members emerged often revolving around what

compromise or concession to make. Once divisions emerged among the union membership,

strikers regrouped into different opinions. At the end of strikes the divisions among union

members became acute and the unions were significantly weakened. Employers, especially at

big firms, did not miss the opportunity and intervened in union internal affairs. They came up

with solutions which favoured moderate members to militant ones and punished the key

union leaders of KCTU affiliated unions who led long strikes.

Another form of anti-unionism has been the opposition of employers to industrial unions. As

mentioned earlier, the trade union movement started the industrial union movement to

overcome the shortcomings of enterprise unions, which was led by some industrial

federations of trade unions under the KCTU. The proportion of industrial unions in terms of

union membership accounted for nearly one-half (48.7%), as seen in the table.

Page 15: Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: The Example … · 2017-07-28 · Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: ... (1910-45) propelled modern production

15

© Professor Rowley

Table 5

Many employers regarded enterprise unions as part of their firms while seeing industrial

unions as outside organisations (or ‘third parties’). Moreover, the newly organised industrial

unions went on strike in the metal and hospital sector more frequently than before in order to

get employers to recognise industrial unions and force them to negotiate. The tactics of

industrial unions pressing employers exacerbated labour-management relations particularly at

large companies because employers had power to resist industrial union attempts at industrial

bargaining. Although employers at large companies recognised enterprise branches of

industrial unions and reluctantly recognised industrial unions themselves, they never sat at

industrial bargaining tables. Confrontation between industrial unions and employers at large

companies weakened enterprise branches of industrial unions at those firms. For example, in

the mid- and late 2000s a number of enterprise branches of the metal industrial union at large

companies went back to enterprise unions and withdrew from the metal industrial union and

the KCTU under the heavy influence of big employers.

As union influence and bargaining power declined, the role of LMCs as either employee

representation or union avoidance increasingly weakened. As seen in the table, the role of

LMCs in wage increases through negotiations, consultations or discussion significantly

reduced. Now management at large non-union firms are less likely to give LMCs rights or

room for representing employees’ interests because pressure or threat of union organisation

are felt to be much weaker than before.

Table 6

6. A Coming New Watershed for Trade Unions and Anti-Unionism

Another critical wave of anti-unionism in Korea has come with two fundamental changes in

labour law in 2010. First, the legal replacement of the union facilities of full-time union

officers paid by their employers by paid time-off facilities for union duties. Second, allowing

multiple unions at firms. These changes have significantly lessened and will further weaken,

trade unions at the firm level. Anti-unionism has taken the form of a more aggressive strategy

of employers towards trade unions than before in order to take advantage of the opportunities

of diminishing trade union power at the workplace.

Page 16: Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: The Example … · 2017-07-28 · Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: ... (1910-45) propelled modern production

16

© Professor Rowley

One of the most important pillars to support the strong presence of unions at firms has been

the arrangement of full-time union officers paid by employers which was secured by trade

union movement from the late 1980s.4 The arrangement has also been an institutional anchor

for union security at the workplace. The arrangement of full-time union officers paid by

employers was achieved by the trade union movement during and after the 1987 mass

struggle of workers. It was closely associated with enterprise unionism in Korea. Enterprise

unionism seemed to be strongly rooted at firms with the help of full-time union officers paid

by each employer at the firm level. The number of full-time union officers and their

prominent role at each enterprise unions and industrial federations based on enterprise unions

gave the trade union movement substantial influence and bargaining power.

There was a criticism that there were too many full-time union officers, particularly at large

firms who control work practices and tend to make them too rigid. After a long national

debate on industrial relations regulation and its reform in 1995–96, there was already an

incomplete political compromise to introduce a legal ban on full-time union officers and at

the same time to allow multiple unions at the workplace in 1997. However the political

compromise and the following legal changes could not be realised and implemented because

some unions and big businesses opposed to its implementation and its implementation were

delayed until the end of 2009. In the meantime, the political and industrial context of those

changes altered. The strength of enterprise unions have declined at almost all firms since the

mid-2000s. To allow multiple unions helps employers ‘whipsaw’ multiple unions to compete

each other for bargaining rights with employers.

Previously, the principle of one union at one firm which denied multiple unions at firm level,

gave the first organised (and often employer-dominated) unions exclusive rights to represent

workers rather than later organised unions representing real workers’ interests. If multiple

unions had been allowed in the late 1980s that would have helped independent unions at big

companies to replace prior established company unions. However allowing multiple unions at

the workplace may now prompt employers to increase their anti-union behaviour by

supporting more moderate unions at the workplace by isolating more independent and radical

4. Although union facilities of full-time union officers paid by employers, who are exempt from work at the workplace, had existed since the 1970s, the arrangement was often informally provided in return for enterprise unions’ cooperation with management.

Page 17: Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: The Example … · 2017-07-28 · Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: ... (1910-45) propelled modern production

17

© Professor Rowley

unions – we need to wait and see. Moreover, the legal ban on full-time union officers paid by

employers without giving enterprise unions any opportunity for reorganising themselves into

other types of unions such as industrial, regional, general or occupational unions have, to

large extent, curtailed trade union power in favour of employers.

In fact the number of full-time union officers in 2008 was as many as one officer per every

nearly 150 members, as seen in Table 7, but it significantly shrunk to the level just to

accommodate time-off provisions as seen in Table 8. The actual number of paid full-time

union officers has declined to less than half. The number has fallen more at large firms than

at small ones, as seen in Table9. The number of paid full-time union officers at large firms

fell more than at medium-sized firms, as seen in Table 10.

Tables 7, 8, 9, 10

The current conservative government is regarded as favouring employers and has thoroughly

monitored how employers and enterprise unions implemented the new arrangement of time-

off for trade union officers. The degree of implementation of time-off for union officers

instead of paid full-time union officers was nearly close to total.

The setting up of multiple unions competing for the exact same membership at one firm has

made matters worse. More new unions have been established at independent union firms

rather than at company-dominated union firms. Employers have been able to ‘whipsaw’ new

unions against independent unions. As a consequence of this new regulation on full-time

trade union officers and allowing multiple unions at firms, independent enterprise unions

have become much weaker and the decline in trade union power and influence was further

accelerated. Anti-unionism has appeared as some employers took on already weakened trade

unions, often together with the help of union-busting agencies and set-up new company-

friendly unions. Moreover, the government's anti-union stance has emboldened employers to

attack unions and to withdraw agreed collective contracts, which had not been seen before.

The government has asked employers in the public sector to take a firm stance on trade

unions by withdrawing collective contracts when they found the contracts included some

personnel matters which are regarded as infringing employers' prerogatives. The situation

Page 18: Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: The Example … · 2017-07-28 · Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: ... (1910-45) propelled modern production

18

© Professor Rowley

seems to be more complex than before. However we have to wait and see what will happen in

the coming years.

For example, some employers in the metal sector in the Kyungjoo region have attacked their

enterprise branches of the metal industrial union within the help of a union-busting agency

and under the auspice of some administration. Some enterprise branches of the metal union

gave in to employers, withdrew from the metal union and reorganised themselves into an

enterprise union dominated by employers. The employers adopted an offensive position in

the two major restructurings and compulsory redundancies at Ssangyong Motor and Hanjin

Shipbuilding. The aggressive redundancies even gave rise to tragic incidents, such as 22

redundant workers or their spouses who committed suicide, arising from psychological agony

and trauma at Ssangyong Motor. Another example is the 300 day sit-in by female activists at

a sky-high crane within HanJin Shipbuiding which attracted much attention from wide

audience and the National Assembly (equivalent to the House of Commons in Britain).

However, what the new wave of anti-unionism is likely to be is not yet fully apparent because

the full effects of multiple unions are yet to be realised. What has appeared so far as a result

of the institutional changes and their associated anti-unionism is so fundamental as to bring in

institutional change in the industrial relations system of Korea.

7. Summary and Conclusions

Anti-unionism in Korea has been shaped and reshaped during the changing context of history,

politics, industrialisation and society. Anti-unionism was, at large, led by the state during the

military dictatorship up the mid-1980s. The nature of anti-unionism was legally or

administratively institutionalised, attitudinal, ideological, divisive and pre-emptive in Korea.

Anti-unionism has remained strong under enterprise unionism because trade union resided

within firms and are often likely to collude with employers in controlling working practices.

The authoritarian anti-unionism led by the military government was designed to block

independent unions up to 1986. An independent trade union movement grew out of the anti-

unionism of the authoritarian government and stubborn employers by overcoming all kinds of

anti-unionism.

Page 19: Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: The Example … · 2017-07-28 · Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: ... (1910-45) propelled modern production

19

© Professor Rowley

When independent unions have been successfully anchored at the workplace and exercised

strong bargaining power, as in the late 1980s and 1990s, anti-unionism became weaker.

However, new anti-unionism resulted from the interaction or confrontations between

assertive independent unions and employers since the 1990s. Another aspect of anti-unionism

was opposition to the industrial union movement and industrial bargaining.

The more fundamental challenge to trade unions in Korea has come from the two legal

changes in union regulation and their associated offensive strategy of management. These

changes are likely to weaken trade unions severely. Anti-unionism strategies by employers

aimed at taking advantage of those changes favourable to employers and attacking weak trade

unions directly. However, what effects the recent fundamental changes finally result in

remains to be seen because the full effects of those changes are yet to be materialised.

Enterprise unions may expose their risks and weaknesses outside under the new waves of

anti-unionism.

Anti-unionism in Korea reflects, and altered with, political transition and changes, power

relations between employers and trade unions, labour markets and firm organisation,

industrial changes and ideologies of major actors. The main characteristics of anti-unionism

in Korea comes from the varying patterns of influences stemming from three sources. First,

the historical legacies of confrontation with Communist North Korea and Korean War.

Second, the enterprise unionism system. Third, the context of compressed industrialisation,

political democratisation, industrial upgrading, financial crisis and new division of labour

with rapidly industrialising China. The kaleidoscope of these forces is still in play in Korean

industrial relations.

Page 20: Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: The Example … · 2017-07-28 · Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: ... (1910-45) propelled modern production

20

© Professor Rowley

References Bae, Kiu-Sik․Noh Yong Jin and Shim SangWan. 2007, Employment Relations in Non-union Firms – Labor-management Council and Alternative Employee Representative Body. Seoul, Korea Labour Institute. Kawanishi, Hirosuke. 1992. Enterprise Unionism in Japan. London: Kegan Paul Kim, Hwang-Joe. 1993. The Korean Union Movement in Transition, in Organized Labor In the Asia-Pacific Region: A Comparative Study of Trade Unionism in Nine Countries, edited by Stephen Frankel Ithaca, ILR Press. Kim, Junghan. 2010. Changes in Industrial Relations after the Revision of Labour Law and the Response of Trade Unions to them. Korea Labour Institute. Kim, Samsoo. 2002. Labour Policies and Industrial Relations under the Era of president Park

Junghee – Labour Policies of Ban on Freedom of Association and Labour-management

Councils within Enterprises. No 18. Social Criticism(in Korean).

Korea Labour Institute. 2009. 2011. Workplace Panel Survey 2007, 2009. Koo, Hagen. 2001. Korean Workers: The Culture and Politics of Class Formation. Kwon, S. and O’Donnell, M. (2001) The Chaebol and Labour in Korea, Routledge. Ministry of (Employment and) Labour. Dec 2011. Monitoring the degree of implementation of Time-off Arrangement. Park, Duk-je. 1992. Industrial Relations in Korea. International Journal of Human Resource

Management, 3(1).

Rowley, C. and Yoo, K.S. (2008) ‘Trade Unions in South Korea’ in J. Benson and Y. Zhu (eds) Trade unionism in Asia, Routledge, pp.43-62. Ithaca. Cornell University Press Rowley, C.; Yoo, K.S. and Kim, D.H. (2011) ‘Labour Movments in South Korea’ in J. Benson and Y. Zhu (eds) The Dynamics of Asian Labour Markets, Routledge, pp. 61-82 Kim, Junghan. 2010. Changes in Industrial Relations after the Revision of Labour Law and the Response of Trade Unions to them. Korea Labour Institute Korea Labour Institute. 2009. 2011. Workplace Panel Survey 2007, 2009.

Page 21: Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: The Example … · 2017-07-28 · Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: ... (1910-45) propelled modern production

21

© Professor Rowley

Table 1: Union Numbers, Membership and Density in Korea, 1965-94

Year Number Membership (’000) Density (%) Dependent employment (’000)

1965 2,634 302 11.6

1970 3,500 473 12.6 3,746

1975 4,091 750 15.8 4,751

1980 2,635 948 14.7 6,464

1985 2,551 1,004 12.4 8,104

1986 2,675 1,036 12.3 8,433

1987 4,103 1,267 13.8 9,191

1988 6,164 1,707 17.8 9,610

1989 7,883 1,932 18.6 10,389

1990 7,698 1,887 17.2 10,950

1991 7,656 1,803 15.9 11,349

1992 7,527 1,735 15.0 11,568

1993 7,147 1,667 14.2 11,751

1994 7,025 1,659 13.5 12,297

1995 6,606 1,615 12.7 12,736

1996 6,424 1,599 12.1 13,200

1997 5,733 1,484 11.1 13,404

1998 5,560 1,402 11.4 12,296

1999 5,637 1,481 11.7 12,663

2000 5,698 1,527 11.4 13,360

2001 6,148 1,569 11.5 13,659

2002 6,506 1,538 10.8 14,181

2003 6,257 1,550 10.8 14,402

2004 6,107 1,537 10.3 14,894

2005 5,971 1,506 9.9 15,185

2006 5,889 1,559 10.0 15,551

2007 5,099 1,668 10.4 15,970

2008 4,886 1,666 10.5 16,206

2009 4,689 1,640 10.1 16,196

2010 4,420 1,643 9.8 16,804 Source: The Ministry of Employment and Labour. 2011. Statistics on Union Organisation in 2010

Page 22: Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: The Example … · 2017-07-28 · Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: ... (1910-45) propelled modern production

22

© Professor Rowley

Table 2: Union Organisation by Establishment Size

Employees/site Less than 30 30-99 100-299 At least 300 Wage earners 9,969,000 3,432,000 1,711,000 2,041,000

Union membership 11,341 82,504 249,616 886,671 Union density (%) 0.1 2.4 14.6 43.4 Source: Ministry of Employment and Labour. 2011. 2011. Statistics on Union Organisation in 2010

Figure 1: Trends in Industrial Action, 1970-2010

Source: Ministry of Labour (now Ministry of Employment and Labour)

Page 23: Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: The Example … · 2017-07-28 · Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: ... (1910-45) propelled modern production

23

© Professor Rowley

Table 3: Labour-Management Councils Set-up at Non-Union Establishments (unit: %)

Year Establishment Types Existent Existent, but name only

Non-existent

2007 (N=31,045)

30~99 employees 47.6 23.5 28.9 100~299 69.0 18.4 12.6 300~499 72.9 23.2 3.9

at least 500 89.3 6.5 4.1 private sector 53.1 22.2 24.7 public sector 71.9 20.8 7.3

manufacturing 59.4 23.2 17.4 non-manufacturing 47.1 21.1 31.8

total 53.2 22.2 24.7

2009 (N=30,877)

30~99 employees 38.1 34.7 27.3 100~299 62.3 29.7 8.0 300~499 61.0 21.7 17.3

at least 500 62.0 31.3 6.7 private sector 43.4 33.4 23.2 public sector 73.5 23.5 3.1

manufacturing 47.2 37.8 15.0 non-manufacturing 40.0 29.0 31.0

total 43.5 33.4 23.1 Source: Korea Labour Institute. 2008. 2010. Workplace Panel Survey 2007, 2009.

Table 4: Working Days Lost Due to Strikes by Large Unions (unit: days, %)

Year Total

working days lost

Hyundai Motor Union/ Kia Motor Union

5 large enterprise unions

10 large enterprise unions

Working days lost

ratio Working days

lost ratio

Working days lost

ratio

2001 1,083,079 173,176 16.0 408,709 37.7 540,292 49.9 2002 1,580,404 138,255 8.7 523,045 33.1 744,694 47.1 2003 1,298,663 429,193 33.0 540,059 41.6 657,700 50.6 2004 1,198,779 280,605 23.4 451,314 37.6 627,553 52.3 2005 847,697 332,135 39.2 453,079 53.4 558,884 65.9 2006 1,200,567 522,011 43.5 789,291 69.0 928,575 77.3 2007 536,285 133,510 24.9 296,402 55.3 391,279 72.9

Source: Ministry of Employment and Labour. Labour Disputes statistics

Page 24: Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: The Example … · 2017-07-28 · Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: ... (1910-45) propelled modern production

24

© Professor Rowley

Table 5: Union Types, Number and Membership (As of the end of 2007)

Type Number (%) Membership (‘000) Enterprise unions 4,713 (92.4) 822 (48.7) General unions or regional unions

305(6.0) 126 (7.5)

Industrial unions 40 (0.8) 739 (43.8) Industrial federation of

enterprise unions 39 (0.8) -

National Center 2 (0.0) - Total 5,099 (100.0) 1,688 (100.0)

Source: Ministry of Employment and Labour

Table 6: Extent of Negotiations, Consultations or Discussion on Wage Increases Taking Place at Labour Management Councils of Non-union Establishments (unit: %)

Year

Types of establishment

2005 (N = 18,319)

2007 (N=22,820)

2009 (N=23,681)

30~99 employees 49.6 45.0 24.6 100~299 57.6 46.9 23.6 300~499 54.4 58.5 38.9

at least 500 51.1 58.5 28.5 private sector 51.3 48.8 24.9 public sector 41.1 51.9 37.9

manufacturing 57.0 53.6 26.9 non-manufacturing 43.3 45.1 22.5

total 51.3 49.0 24.9 Source: Korea Labour Institute. 2006. 2008. 2010. Workplace Panel Survey 2005. 2007, 2009

Table 7: Number of Full-Time Union Officers Before New Labour Law

Year Number of employees per one full-time union officer at organized enterprises

Collective agreements In reality

2008 172.6 149.2 2005 159.1 152.7 2002 123.9 121.6

Source: Ministry of Labour. 2010

Page 25: Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: The Example … · 2017-07-28 · Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: ... (1910-45) propelled modern production

25

© Professor Rowley

Table 8: Degree of Implementing the New Arrangement of Time-off for Union officers

Number of applicable workplaces with at least

100 employees

Workplaces where agreements on time-off arrangements instead of full-time union officers were made

Total Workplaces observing

legal provisions Workplaces still above legal

provisions

2,499 2,185 2,162 (98.9%) 22 (1.1%)

Source: Ministry of Employment and Labour. 2011

Table 9: Number of Full-Time Union Officers After New Labour Law

Membership size Number of full-time union officers provided by paid time-off arrangement50-99 0.33

100-299 0.58300-499 1.35500-999 1.52

1000-4999 3.29at least 5,000 12.86average per

enterprise union 0.69 Source: Kim 2010

Table 10: Reductions in Number of Paid Full-Time Officers

Number up to June 2010

By end of 2010 Paid Unpaid

Kia Motor 243 21 70 Ko-Rail 64 16.5 14

Korean Red Cross 22 5 4 Ko-Gas 10 5 3

Seoul National University Hospital 8 5 0 SLS shipbuilding 5 3 0

Hyundae Heavy Industries 50 15 15 KBS Broadcasting 24 12

Source: Ministry of Employment and Labour

Page 26: Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: The Example … · 2017-07-28 · Causes and Consequence of Types of Anti-Trade Unionism: ... (1910-45) propelled modern production

26

© Professor Rowley

Figure 2: Five Types of Employee Representation in non-union firms

Source: Bae et al. 2007.