Byzantine empire and Italy

17
The poverty of the Patriarchate of Grado and the Byzantine – Venetian Treaty of 1082 John Mark Nicovich* Department of History and Social Science, William Carey University, Box 157, Hattiesburg, MS 39401, USA The imperial chrysobull granted to the Venetian state in 1082 provided the Venetians with considerable economic advantages throughout the Byzantine Empire, and had a major impact on the political relationship of the two powers down to the Fourth Crusade. Yet the chrysobull also granted considerable monies to the metropolitan of Venice, the Patriarch of Grado. In the decades prior to 1082 Grado had suffered from systemic poverty, and various attempts by the Doge to solve this problem failed. The grant of large sums in gold in the chrysobull was aimed at solving this problem. Even this ultimately failed, and another proviso of the chrysobull, the grant of a merchant quarter in Constantinople to Venice, eventually became a funding tool for Grado and other Venetian ecclesiastical institutions. Keywords: Venice; Byzantium; Grado; chrysobull; patriarch; Gregory VII; Paschal II Much scholarly work has been done by historians of Venice and Byzantium concerning the chrysobull of 1082, the treaty that established the basic economic and diplomatic relationship of the Byzantine Empire with the Venetian state down to the Fourth Crusade (1204). 1 Venice had a history of close ties to Byzantium, first as a frontier province, and later, as Byzantine power faded in the west, as a trading partner. In 992 Basil II had reduced the taxes owed by Venetians to the imperial government and modified their supervision, yet this limited grant paled in comparison to the extensive concessions of 1082. Alexius I Komnenos’s desperate need for naval aid in 1082 allowed the Venetians to renegotiate the terms of their relationship from a position of strength. The resulting document vastly increased the power of Venetian merchants, allowing them access to virtually every port in the Empire, establishing a Venetian quarter within the walls of Constantinople, and relieving Venetian merchants of all kommerkion, or customs duties. It is the last of these, the exemption from kommerkion and all other customs imposts throughout the Empire that has most concerned modern historians. As Silvano Borsari has noted, the chrysobull of 1082 accelerated the process of the disintegration of imperial control of its economy and the Latin infiltration of the Empire. The unintended consequence of the treaty was to place Venetian merchants in a better economic position, not only over other Italians, but also over native Greek merchants, who still had to pay the kommerkion. 2 Venetian merchants, due to their lower overall costs, could easily undercut Greek trade and shipping, especially between outlying Aegean ports and Constantinople. This chrysobull acted as an exemplar to other Italian maritime states. By the mid-twelfth century the Genoese and the Pisans would seek and gain their own less ISSN 0951-8967 print/ISSN 1743-940X online q 2009 Taylor & Francis DOI: 10.1080/09518960903000736 http://www.informaworld.com *Email: [email protected] Mediterranean Historical Review Vol. 24, No. 1, June 2009, 1–16

description

Article about the Byzantine empire and Italy

Transcript of Byzantine empire and Italy

Page 1: Byzantine empire and Italy

The poverty of the Patriarchate of Grado and the Byzantine–VenetianTreaty of 1082

John Mark Nicovich*

Department of History and Social Science, William Carey University, Box 157, Hattiesburg,MS 39401, USA

The imperial chrysobull granted to the Venetian state in 1082 provided the Venetianswith considerable economic advantages throughout the Byzantine Empire, and had amajor impact on the political relationship of the two powers down to the FourthCrusade. Yet the chrysobull also granted considerable monies to the metropolitan ofVenice, the Patriarch of Grado. In the decades prior to 1082 Grado had suffered fromsystemic poverty, and various attempts by the Doge to solve this problem failed. Thegrant of large sums in gold in the chrysobull was aimed at solving this problem. Eventhis ultimately failed, and another proviso of the chrysobull, the grant of a merchantquarter in Constantinople to Venice, eventually became a funding tool for Grado andother Venetian ecclesiastical institutions.

Keywords: Venice; Byzantium; Grado; chrysobull; patriarch; Gregory VII; Paschal II

Much scholarly work has been done by historians of Venice and Byzantium concerning

the chrysobull of 1082, the treaty that established the basic economic and diplomatic

relationship of the Byzantine Empire with the Venetian state down to the Fourth Crusade

(1204).1 Venice had a history of close ties to Byzantium, first as a frontier province, and

later, as Byzantine power faded in the west, as a trading partner. In 992 Basil II had

reduced the taxes owed by Venetians to the imperial government and modified their

supervision, yet this limited grant paled in comparison to the extensive concessions of

1082. Alexius I Komnenos’s desperate need for naval aid in 1082 allowed the Venetians to

renegotiate the terms of their relationship from a position of strength. The resulting

document vastly increased the power of Venetian merchants, allowing them access to

virtually every port in the Empire, establishing a Venetian quarter within the walls of

Constantinople, and relieving Venetian merchants of all kommerkion, or customs duties.

It is the last of these, the exemption from kommerkion and all other customs imposts

throughout the Empire that has most concerned modern historians.

As Silvano Borsari has noted, the chrysobull of 1082 accelerated the process of the

disintegration of imperial control of its economy and the Latin infiltration of the Empire.

The unintended consequence of the treaty was to place Venetian merchants in a better

economic position, not only over other Italians, but also over native Greek merchants, who

still had to pay the kommerkion.2 Venetian merchants, due to their lower overall costs,

could easily undercut Greek trade and shipping, especially between outlying Aegean ports

and Constantinople. This chrysobull acted as an exemplar to other Italian maritime states.

By the mid-twelfth century the Genoese and the Pisans would seek and gain their own less

ISSN 0951-8967 print/ISSN 1743-940X online

q 2009 Taylor & Francis

DOI: 10.1080/09518960903000736

http://www.informaworld.com

*Email: [email protected]

Mediterranean Historical Review

Vol. 24, No. 1, June 2009, 1–16

Page 2: Byzantine empire and Italy

extensive concessions from the Komnenoi emperors, further exacerbating the economic

drain on Greek merchants. The arrival of the Genoese and Pisans also brought Italian

maritime rivalries into the walls of Constantinople, leading to multiple incidents of

violence between the respective communities in the 1160s and 1170s. It was just such an

attack by the Venetians on the Genoese community, as well as a growing distance between

Byzantine and Venetian political interests, that led to the mass arrest of all Venetians

throughout the Empire in March 1171.3 Further anti-Latin sentiment among the Byzantine

populace was tapped by Andronikos I during his usurpation of the imperial throne in April

1182, leading to the massacre of Genoese, Pisans, and other Latins within Constantinople.

The tense atmosphere thus created between Byzantine and Latins deeply influenced the

subsequent conquest of Constantinople during the Fourth Crusade (1204).

Not all the concessions within the chrysobull were economic, for it also devolved title

and monies on the Doge of Venice and various ecclesiastical institutions within the

lagoons. The Doge received the title of protosebastos,4 and an attached allowance, while

20 libre of gold was to be distributed each year to the overall Venetian church as the Doge

saw fit. San Marco, the ducal chapel, received the annual tax, diverted from the imperial

treasury, of three hyperpyra levied upon each Amalfitan workshop or warehouse within

the Empire. The Venetians also received church buildings in Constantinople and

Dyrrachium. The chrysobull reconfirmed the pre-existing Venetian possession of St

Akindynos, but in addition granted the church a bakery with an annual revenue of 20

nomismata.5 In Dyrrachium the church of San Andrea went to the Venetians, together with

an imperial pension.6 Of primary concern here is the grant of title and monies to the

metropolitan of Venice, the Patriarch of Grado. The Patriarch received the title of

hypertimos, or ‘most revered’, with an allowance of 20 libre of gold per annum. Scholars

have mentioned these terms of the chrysobull in detail, but have failed to elaborate on their

significance and implications.7 These terms are considered an afterthought to the primary

economic concessions, a kind of sweetening for the overall negotiation. However, in the

context of the poverty of the Patriarch of Grado, these terms take on a particular meaning.

In the decades prior to 1082, the patriarchate suffered from endemic poverty, and it is our

thesis that this particular clause was negotiated and included in the chrysobull specifically

to assuage this poverty.

The poor patriarch

In July 1073 Pope Gregory VII addressed a letter to Michael VII Doukas, Emperor of

Byzantium. Michael had recently sent ambassadors to Gregory, seeking aid against the

Empire’s numerous enemies, and offering discussions on the reunion of the churches in

return. Gregory was eager to send his own representative to begin high-level discussion,

and he proposed ‘our brother Domenico [Marango], Patriarch of Venice and one most

faithful to the Roman Church and to your Empire’.8 The so-called ‘Patriarch of Venice’

here was actually the Patriarch of Grado, Domenico Marango, an ideal candidate for such

a legation. He was Metropolitan of Venice, a state with a long history of political, cultural,

and economic ties to Byzantium, and would be well received by the imperial court. He was

also ideologically acceptable to the papacy. Marango (c.1053–c.1073) had been an ardent

supporter of the papal reform movement, travelling to numerous reform synods in

Germany and Italy, acting as a papal legate to Benevento along with Humbert of Silva-

Candida, and was a signatory to the Papal Election Decree of 1059, affixing his

subscription second after Pope Nicholas II himself.9 Furthermore, Marango had acted

previously as an intermediary with the Orthodox Church. During the Schism of 1054

J.M. Nicovich2

Page 3: Byzantine empire and Italy

Marango had written in support of papal primacy to Peter, Patriarch of Antioch. Marango

had received a stern rebuke from Peter and from Michael Keroularios, Patriarch of

Constantinople, but this did not dissuade Gregory from sending Marango as an emissary

two decades later.10

No further mention of this mission appears in the historical record, for it probably

never took place. Marango disappears at this point, dying not long after Gregory VII’s

letter, and was subsequently replaced as patriarch by Domenico Cerbano; yet Marango’s

death does not seem to have been the primary factor preventing a legation to Byzantium.

Rather, poverty was the cause. In December 1074, Pope Gregory wrote to Domenico

Silvio, Doge of Venice, and to the Venetian people. He began by reminding them that they

had been blessed ‘by the honour of a patriarchate . . . the very prerogative of its name and

duty is so restricted and rare that not more than four may be found in the whole world.’ Yet

despite such a considerable honour, the Venetian people had proven ungrateful:

Although this is so, amongst you what is so great a glory and the ornament of so exalted a highpriesthood have by consequence of a dearth of temporal possessions and the diminution of itspower become so contemptible and have fallen so far from the rightful standing of its honour,that so great a dearth of possessions would appear not to beseem the see of a simple bishopricor to be able to provide for its necessities.

As Gregory went on to explain, this poverty was not a new problem, but was seemingly

endemic to the office:

For we recall that Dominico [Marango] of blessed memory, the predecessor of him who nowis [Domenico Cerbano] had wished to abandon the place on the account of extremedestitution. And his successor declares himself to be constrained by a like necessity.11

It would seem that Marango had complained of Grado’s poverty not long before his death,

and that his successor suffered from the same problem. Thus the papal legation Gregory VII

proposed to Michael VII probably never took place owing to Grado’s systemic poverty, and

it was probably the failure of the legation that prompted Gregory’s letter to Venice.

Poverty was an endemic condition for the Venetian church, a by-product of the

geography of the lagoons.12 The lagoon dwellers were forced to turn to other means of

production suitable to an aquatic environment where dry land was at a premium, including

salt-works, fisheries, and vineyards. The bishoprics, monasteries and parishes of the

lagoons faced similar constraints, and thus lived off similar sources of income, ones often

donated to them by pious laymen within the lagoons. One of the more prominent

institutions, the Benedictine convent of San Zaccaria, possessed considerable property on

the mainland, granted either by local nobles, prominent landowners, or in one notable case,

by Emperor Conrad II.13 Yet San Zaccaria was an exception rather than the rule.

Typically, a member of the Doge’s household, a daughter or sister, was the abbess, and

numerous daughters of prominent Venetian families took their vows there.14 It comes as

no surprise that the mainland nobility would patronize San Zaccaria, if only for political

reasons. There is no evidence that other institutions within the lagoons possessed any such

properties on the mainland, and they had little property within the lagoons.

Grado seems to have possessed even less than its suffragans. Again, geography played a

major role, exacerbating the situation. Grado was surprisingly remote from the political and

economic centre of the lagoons, and located on a small island situated at the easternmost

edge. In fact Grado was far closer to the rival Patriarchate of Aquileia than it was to the

Rialto.15 On their small island the patriarch had little room for agriculture, and yet there may

not have been enough residents to work what land they did hold.16 Unlike other

ecclesiastical institutions in the lagoons, they enjoyed few alternative sources of income.

Mediterranean Historical Review 3

Page 4: Byzantine empire and Italy

Despite their own prominence, they could not expect donations from the mainland

nobility. The mainland nobles were partisans of Aquileia, and in their eyes Grado was a

suffragan bishop arrogating the patriarchal title. The situation was further exacerbated by

the rise of the Reform papacy and its alliance with Grado. Domenico Marango and

Domenico Cerbano, both partisans of reform, could expect no backing from the imperial

nobility of the mainland, who were largely imperial supporters. More surprising is the lack

of donations from within the lagoons. During the first three quarters of the eleventh

century, only two pious donations to the Patriarchate of Grado are recorded. The family of

the late Doge Tribuno Memo made a donation in May 1012, and a chaplain of San Marco

did the same in February 1058, in both cases of salt works.17 Even taking into account that

many documents related to Grado have not survived, the lack of pious donations from

those under Grado’s jurisdiction is striking.

While noting the Pontiff’s letter to the Venetians, Gregory VII’s most recent biographer

H.E.J. Cowdrey cites ‘tensions between the city and the patriarchate’ as the reason for their

lack of support.18 To what tensions Cowdrey refers is not clear, and there is no evidence of

any political or ideological disconnect between the patriarchate and the Venetian

government, and subsequent events would demonstrate that the Doge and his councillors

were quite active in assuaging Grado’s poverty.19 As far as the Venetian populace was

concerned, again there is no evidence of any specific animus against Grado. However, as

noted Grado was remote, sitting well apart from the Rialto, Torcello, Chioggia, and most of

the other population centres of the lagoon. This may simply have been an issue of distance.

Venetian citizens had bishops, parishes, and monasteries immediately within their own

communities to which they could donate their property. Pious donations were motivated by

the immediate concern for one’s soul and those of one’s kin, and it is only natural that

individuals and families sought out familiar institutions with which they had generational

connections to patronize with donations. Grado had no local population from which they

could expect such pious donations. As a result of their foundation in such a remote corner of

an already poor lagoon, the patriarchs were left to struggle for a livelihood.

The Doge knew of Grado’s plight, and by the time Gregory’s letter to Venice had

arrived, the Venetian government had already acted to alleviate the poverty of Grado.20

Doge Domenico Silvio convened a meeting of the prelates of the lagoon in the ducal

palace in September 1074. Present before Silvio were the bishops of Caorle, Castello,

Cittanova, Jesolo, Malamacco, and Torcello, along with the abbots of San Ilario,

San Giorgio Maggiore, Santa Trinita di Brondolo, and San Felice di Ammiana, four judges

of the ducal court, and 27 other leading citizens of the city. Clearly it was an occasion of

great importance to the Venetian state and to the church:

We, Domenico Silvio, by the grace of God, Doge of Venice and of Dalmatia, at one with thebishops, abbots, judges, and the greater part of our faithful citizens, among others who pertainto the advancement of our country, gather to deliberate concerning our Patriarch of Grado,who to all of Venice is the head of all our churches.21

The document does not deal with the actual deliberations of this gathering, nor does it

mention the poverty of Grado directly; yet it immediately turns to a list of lands, goods,

monies, and rights that various constituents agreed to give annually to Grado, beginning with

the Doge himself, and proceeding through the bishops and abbots: ‘All of this the mentioned

bishops and abbots have given to pay, on the kalends of September, our patriarch for every

year.’22 The list of property, goods-in-kind, and specie given over is as follows:

1. The Doge: Silvio agreed to give over lands at Villa, near to Cittanova, as well as

devolving the annual concession of the Caprensi of Istria, 100 amphorae of wine.

J.M. Nicovich4

Page 5: Byzantine empire and Italy

He also agreed to a one-time payment totalling 460 libre denariorum23 from several

funds under the control of the Doge, including 100 libre denariorum from the

treasury of San Marco, 200 libre denariorum from the roga, or the ducal treasury,

and another 160 libre denariorum from the roga magistratus, or the revenues of the

ducal council.24

2. The bishop of Castello: 20 libre denariorum.

3. The bishop of Torcello: 20 libre denariorum.

4. The bishop of Malamacco: half a fishery at Favirago and five modii of grain per

annum.

5. The bishop of Jesolo: seven modii of grain per annum.

6. The bishop of Cittanova: six measures of land with vines at Mugla.

7. The bishop of Caorle: a salt work.

8. The abbot of SS. Trinita e Michelangelo: 12 modii of grain per annum.

9. The abbot of SS. Ilario e Benedetto: 25 libre denariorum.

10. The abbot of San Giorgio Maggiore: 10 libre denariorum.

11. The abbot of San Felice di Ammiana: six modii of grain.25

This document represents the concession of considerable monies, land, and in-kind goods.

The one-time donation of monies by the Doge amounted to 110,400 denari, an enormous

sum, probably meant to act as a long-term endowment.26 The 75 libre conceded by the

bishops and abbots amounted to a yearly provision of 18,000 denari for the patriarch’s

coffers. The donations of land and the in-kind payments are far more difficult to quantify,

but the intended effect is clear. The Doge was attempting to deal with the problem of

Grado’s poverty once and for all by endowing the patriarchate with public funds,

donations of land, and annual concessions on the part of the ecclesiastical institutions of

the lagoons. It appeared that the entire issue was solved three months before Gregory’s

stinging reprimand.

There is much evidence to suggest that Grado remained poor despite Doge Silvio’s

best efforts. The charter of September 1074 was not the first time a Doge had tried to deal

with the issue. The charter specifically mentions that similar measures had been taken by

Silvio’s immediate predecessor, Domenico Contarini (1043–1070), ‘with the approval of

the bishops, abbots, judges and certain other good men’.27 In reality the charter of

September 1074 was not a new concession but the reissuing of an old one. The implication

is clear, for either the previous measures were not sufficient to offset Grado’s

expenditures, or the concessions were simply not being paid. The latter is the obvious

explanation, but why? In the absence of direct evidence, it is tempting to assume, as

Cowdrey does, that there was a political reason behind this failure. Perhaps the Doge,

bishops, and abbots disagreed with Patriarch Marango’s reformist tendencies, and chose to

express their displeasure by withholding funds.

However, the evidence does not bear out Cowdrey’s assumption. There is no record of

any disagreements between the Patriarchate of Grado and his immediate suffragans in the

eleventh century, regarding reform or any other issue. Thus we are left with only two

possibilities, that the suffragans of the lagoons either could not or would not hand over the

conceded monies and in-kind items. The bishops and abbots of the lagoons were not overly

rich, but they did possess property, far more than the tiny island of Grado. They also did

not protest the tithes laid upon them under Doges Contarini or Silvio, so they seemed able

to pay. Therefore, Grado’s suffragans within the lagoons could have supported their

metropolitan, but they simply chose not to. They obviously had not done so under

Contarini, and would probably not do so under Silvio. This was possibly due to political

Mediterranean Historical Review 5

Page 6: Byzantine empire and Italy

considerations, although not related to reform. The concerns of the bishops and abbots

were more immediate. Marango and Cerbano had been active patriarchs outside of the

lagoon, and the suffragan prelates were probably afraid that they would become active

within the lagoons, asserting greater authority over them. The high clergy of the lagoons

wished to keep their patriarch poor, thereby limiting his overall power as a metropolitan.

A poor patriarch was less likely to concern himself with their business.

Grado and the chrysobull of 1082

It is clear that by the middle of the eleventh century Grado’s poverty neared destitution,

resulting in intercessory reprimands from the Pope and the repeated interventions of the

Venetian government. In light of this systemic poverty and the governmental attempts to

alleviate it, the economic concessions to the Venetian church within the chrysobull of

1082 appear to be aimed directly at the issue. As noted above, the chrysobull provided

several concessions to Venetian ecclesiastical institutions, including monies to be

distributed to the overall Venetian church and a specific concession for San Marco.28

However, the concession to Grado is the most significant, in which the patriarch was to

receive the ecclesiastical title of hypertimos, or ‘most revered’, and a respective donation

of 20 libre of hyperpyra per annum.

Was this sum, 20 libre of hyperpyra, enough to meet Grado’s needs, or was it merely a

token sum? It is difficult to ascertain medieval exchange rates in any period, and no

evidence contemporary to 1082 exists. However, data from the mid-twelfth century

establishes a range of exchange rates for gold coinage in Venice, from 12 solidi

veronensium to 20 solidi veronensium, depending on the type of coin.29 If we assume the

lower rate of exchange for 1082, 12 solidi veronensium, or 144 denari per hyperpyra, then

20 libre of hyperpyra (1440 hyperpyra) would equal 864 libre veronensium. There is also

the problem of the coinage itself. The monies conceded in 1074 were almost certainly of

coinage minted in Venice, which was repeatedly devalued in the late eleventh century,30

and in all likelihood the exchange rate was even higher in terms of the local Venetian

currency of 1082 than that of the Veronese currency of the mid-twelfth century.

Despite the difficulty in determining the exact exchange rate, it is obvious that the

concession of gold coinage within the chrysobull was worth far more than the monies

previously conceded to the patriarchate. In the 1074 charter the patriarch was to receive

535 libre, but only 75 libre were to be given per annum. The remainder was a one-time

endowment. The chrysobull clearly conceded hundreds of libre denari every year.

Regardless of the exact exchange rate, it is clear that the terms of the chrysobull would

drastically increase the yearly income of the Patriarchate of Grado. It would seem as if the

Venetian negotiators were using the chrysobull as an opportunity to solve the systemic

poverty of the Venetian church. The very size of the gifts illustrates the poor economic

condition of the bishops, abbots, and the rest of the Venetian church, as well as the

inadequacies of previous attempts to fix the problem.

The failure of the chrysobull

Over the long term, the chrysobull failed to yield the expected results. On 31 October 1109

Pope Paschal II sent a letter to the Venetian people concerning, once again, their patriarch:

Paschal II to the bishops and clerics, the Doge, the nobles and people of Venice: themetropolitan of Grado suffers much poverty in distress, yet should not a patriarch be able tosafely and properly persist in himself and also should he not hold his diocese to some degree,which he is owed in order to remain in the manner of his dignity?31

J.M. Nicovich6

Page 7: Byzantine empire and Italy

Once again the papacy addressed the continued poverty of the patriarchate; yet how could

this poverty continue in the aftermath of 1082? While we do not have information

regarding the expenses of the patriarchate, given the largesse inherent in 20 libre of

gold per annum, Grado should have been wealthy, most probably with considerable

surpluses of bullion in the coffers. How can the modern historian explain this seeming

contradiction?

The conceivable answer is that little, if any, of the gold promised in the chrysobull was

ever paid out, at least over the long term. There can be little doubt that the Venetian

negotiators in 1082 intended the terms of the chrysobull to deal with the ongoing problem

of Grado’s poverty; but like Doge Silvio’s 1074 agreement with the local bishops and

abbots, this agreement relied on good faith. Again, that good faith had failed. Why did the

Venetians fail to demand fulfilment of these terms of the chrysobull? Those particular

terms were not the crux of the agreement. Rather, the chrysobull of 1082 was primarily an

economic agreement detailing the trading privileges granted by the Empire to Venice. The

yearly payments to Grado and the other Venetian churches were merely added bonuses.

Given the serious advantages that the chrysobull gave to Venetian merchants, it seems

unlikely that the Doge would have complained much about a Byzantine failure to deliver

the yearly donations to the Venetian church. Such complaints could have potentially

soured the relationship between Byzantium and Venice. After all, a chrysobull was

granted at the pleasure of the emperor, and could be abolished by him. It should also

be remembered that the chrysobull was granted at a time of crisis for the Empire, when it

was in urgent need of Venetian naval aid; yet later in the reign of Alexius I Komnenos

(1081–1118) the circumstances changed dramatically. Alexius ultimately defeated a

series of Norman attacks, successfully negotiated the chaos brought on by the First

Crusade, and regained significant territories in Anatolia from the Seljuk Turks.32 By 1100

Alexius was in a much stronger position and was no longer as reliant on foreign aid.

Alexius could negotiate from a position of political and military strength, making it

unlikely that the Venetian state would complain about the abrogation of non-essential

portions of the chrysobull.

As a result the patriarch’s poverty persisted, but in the end the chrysobull would

provide an indirect solution. The Doge had no control over the funds promised to the

churches of Venice by the 1082 chrysobull, and either the Byzantines lived up to the

bargain or they did not. However, the chrysobull did give the Venetian state direct control

over one form of capital wealth in Constantinople, namely, the Venetian quarter itself. The

chrysobull expressly devolved real estate upon the Venetians as a specific quarter. This

quarter was located on the northern side of the city, bordering on the Golden Horn, in the

Perama district between the Droungarious (or Viglae) gate and the Hebraica (Jewish)

Gate. Within the walls of Constantinople the Venetians would possess a complex of

houses, mansions, storefronts, warehouses, a bakery, and outside the walls they would

hold three waterfront landing stages or scalae.33 It also provided the Venetians with the

church of St Akindynos, along with a nearby bakery yielding a subsidy of 20 nomismata

per annum.34

The Venetian quarter supplied the merchants of Venice with space to live, negotiate

business deals, store products, worship according to the Latin rite, and conduct their life as

temporary or permanent expatriates far from their homes. It also supplied Venice with a

means to solve its continual problem of funding Grado and other ecclesiastical institutions.

From rather early in their first tenure in Constantinople (1082–1171) the Venetian

government seems to have realized the value of their real estate as a means of funding. The

first record of land in the quarter being donated to an ecclesiastical foundation occurred in

Mediterranean Historical Review 7

Page 8: Byzantine empire and Italy

July 1090, when Doge Vitale Falier made a major concession to San Giorgio Maggiore,

one of the chief monastic houses of the lagoons:

Therefore, we, Vitale Falier Dodoni, by the grace of God Doge of Venice and Dalmatia, andimperial protosebastos, one with our judges and other good men of our faith, with oursuccessors and heirs, in knowledge of our sins . . . and of good and spontaneous will for theremedy of our souls we give, we donate, we concede and contract, we offer and transact withyou, the venerable Carimann, abbot of San Giorgio [Maggiore] and your successors inperpetuity all of our property of land and of houses, roofed or unroofed, sited in the cityof Constantinople, which we acquired from the Emperor Alexius in a chrysobull andpraktikon.35

This concession was clearly a pious donation, as evidenced by the phrases ‘in knowledge

of our sins’ and ‘for the good of our souls’. This was the donation of property owned by the

state, and the donation was made on behalf of the Doge, his judges, and other leading

citizens of the city-state. The signatories included the Doge himself, five of his judges, and

129 leading citizens of the city. This was not a private donation, but a public concession

for the good of all Venetian souls.

The properties conceded were quite substantial. The cartulary effectively awarded the

lion’s share of land and houses, ‘terrarum et casarum’, whether made of stone or wood,

‘aedifitiis petrinis et ligneis’, to San Giorgio. The charter also awarded the monastery a

series of ergasterii, which were workshops or warehouses, critical real estate assets for any

expatriate merchant quarter. The intent of this cartulary was clearly to endow San Giorgio

with significant rental properties in Constantinople as a ready source of annual income.

Venetian merchants establishing permanent or semi-permanent trading businesses within

Constantinople would be forced to do business with San Giorgio, assuming that they

wished to reside within the bounds of the Venetian quarter.

This was not only a pious donation, for as Silvano Borsari notes, ‘it rendered more

articulate the system of utilization of the quarter’.36 By devolving much of its property in

Constantinople upon an ecclesiastical institution, the Venetian government rid itself of the

onerous administrative function of renting out real estate far across the waves. Thus, by

working through an ecclesiastical institution the state could ensure the fair utilization of

land in the Venetian quarter, without having to supply government administrators.

The same document of July 1090 that delivered so much property into the hands of San

Giorgio Maggiore also reveals that the latter was not the first Venetian monastic house to

receive land in Constantinople. The charter specifically excludes ‘all those lands we have

given to the monastery of San Nicolo by a charter of confirmation’.37 The document

further reveals that San Giorgio’s property abutted that of San Nicolo di Lido.38 Obviously

these statements were ancillary to the actual purpose of the document, simply stating that

this charter did not include land previously conceded to San Nicolo.39 The charter

devolving such lands on San Nicolo does not survive, so we are unable to know exactly

what properties and goods were ceded to them, nor do we know the exact date of that

transaction, although we must assume that the concession took place between the time of

the chrysobull of 1082 and July 1090, the date of the San Giorgio charter. It follows that

the Venetian state had a policy of devolving Constantinopolitan property on its

ecclesiastical institutions well before Paschal II decried Grado’s poverty.

However, as in December 1074 when Gregory VII had written to Venice, the

Venetians had already acted to correct the problem. Doge Ordelafo Falier convened a

meeting of leading Venetians and clergy in September 1107 once again to discuss the

problem of Grado. The charter produced by the meeting was a kind of compromise for

finding internal sources of funding as opposed to external sources. The beginning of

J.M. Nicovich8

Page 9: Byzantine empire and Italy

the charter reaffirmed several previous concessions explicitly mentioned in the 1074

document:

Because we, Ordelafo Falier, by the grace of God Doge of Venice and imperial protosebastos,with our successors ought to give and to render to our Patriarchate of Grado every year 160pounds of denari out of our palace, as contained in the promissory charter which was made byDomenico Silvio, the deceased Doge, with the Bishops and Abbots and people of Venice, andanother 100 pounds of denari which were of the treasury of San Marco, which were disbursedfor Giovanni Saponario, the late Patriarch.40

The charter makes clear reference to the agreement of 1074, when Doge Silvio promised

100 libre denariorum from the palace treasury, 200 libre denariorum from the treasury of

San Marco, and 160 libre denariorum from the roga magistratus,41 the same source for the

160 libre mentioned in the document of 1107. Although the Doge was now to pay a lower

amount, significantly it was to be a yearly sum, not a one-time grant as in 1074.

At this point the charter diverges from that of 1074. The meeting of September 1074

had resulted in the bishops and abbots of the lagoon agreeing to make certain concessions,

in specie and in kind, to Grado. Although present, this time the bishops and abbots were

conspicuously silent. In fact, of the six bishoprics promising tithes to Grado in September

1074, five were signatories in September 1107: Castello, Torcello, Malamacco, Cittanova,

and Caorle. Only the bishop of Jesolo does not appear. Of the four monasteries represented

in 1074, the abbots of three were signatories in 1107, including SS. Trinita e Michelangelo

Arcangelo, SS. Ilario e Benedetto, and San Giorgio Maggiore. The abbot of San Felice di

Ammiana was missing, but the abbot of San Giorgio di Pineto appears as a signatory.

The concessions their predecessors had promised in 1074, themselves a re-statement of

a previous agreement, were not repeated at this venue. There is no mention of any

concessions at all. Rather, it seems that the ducal court and the patriarchate had given up

on concessions from the suffragan churches of the lagoon. This time the Doge was taking

care of the problem himself, rather than relying on the goodwill of the Venetian church for

their patriarch; so the Doge relied on funds from sources he directly controlled, such as the

ducal treasury and the treasury of San Marco, the ducal chapel.

This was not new, yet in 1107 the Doge also controlled another source of revenue,

Venetian property in Constantinople. Just as the state had provided land to support San

Nicolo di Lido and San Giorgio Maggiore, it could do the same for Grado, and a

substantial complex of buildings in the quarter remained to be given out:

For all that we, the aforementioned Ordelafo, by the grace of God Doge of Venice andimperial protosebastos, together with our bishops and judges and the people of Venice, withour successors and heirs, from this day give and concede to you, lord Giovanni Gradenigo,venerable Patriarch of Grado and to your successors in perpetuum, that church of St.Akindynos, sited in the regal city of Constantinople, with all its territory and benefices, whichis of old by right of our palace according to confirmation by an imperial chrysobull.42

St Akindynos was an important structure within the Venetian quarter, for it represented a

strong connection to the religious allegiance of the Venetians. Despite all their cultural

connections to Byzantium, which included a predilection for Byzantine ecclesiastical

architecture and art, the Venetians remained ardently tied to the western church, both in

liturgical rite and in hierarchical matters. Therefore they required a church in

Constantinople to conduct the cure of souls according to the Latin rite. This also made

it an obvious choice to devolve upon Grado, the metropolitan of the Venetian church.43

The confirmation of St Akindynos included more than just the church building. As

noted above, the chrysobull of 1082 also included a bakery with a yearly revenue of 20

nomismata as a benefice for the church, and these are clearly conceded in the above

Mediterranean Historical Review 9

Page 10: Byzantine empire and Italy

passage: ‘with all its territory and benefices’. However, such a donation could do little

actually to improve Grado’s financial situation. The next clause of the charter was clearly

intended to provide a considerable income for Grado:

Then, as such, the aforementioned and designated church with all its treasury and itsvestments and its books, with all its possessions and pertinences, inside and outside . . .with allits warehouses and its bakery and with all its balances and weights together with all themeasures for oil, as well as for wine, and all our taverns which in that previously noted city areconsidered under our authority.44

As one would expect from such a concession, the chattel of the church would remain with

the church, from its monies to its vestments and books. Then the charter takes a different

turn, granting the Patriarch of Grado control over decidedly non-ecclesiastical properties,

including three major items of note. The bakery conceded in the chrysobull of 1082 was

turned over to the patriarchate, thus insuring that those proceeds would go into the coffers

of Grado. The next two concessions are of even greater import. Grado would also receive

all the taverns within the quarter, probably intended as rental properties. The yearly

proceeds from these two sets of properties alone must have been significant.

However, the most significant concession was the authority over the weights and

measures used in the Venetian quarter. St Akindynos appears to have possessed weights and

measures even before the chrysobull of 1082, and this was apparently a continuation of

Byzantine legal custom.45 Having possession of their own weights and measures was

important to the Venetian merchant community. The Venetian presence in Constantinople

was predicated on trade. The presence of Venetian clergy in the Byzantine capital was

required to provide the cure of souls for Venetian merchants doing business there, and

critical to that business was the fair and proper usage of weights and measures. In any culture

without modern universal standards of measurement agreed upon, localized standards were

absolutely necessary for the fair and free exercise of business, and placing this operation in

the hands of clergy may have given the process a greater degree of legitimacy.46 Also, by

placing the quarter’s weights and measures under the authority of Grado, the Venetian state

disposed of the administering of the weights and measures. Grado, by holding St Akindynos

as a suffragan church, would take over the administration of the weights and measures,

provide personnel to oversee their usage, and ultimately reap the economic benefits.

The impetus behind the concession of the weights and measures to Grado was clearly

economic. Each use of the weights and measures by merchants entailed the payment of a

fee, either a set fee or a percentage of the goods being weighed, thus resulting in a

sizeable revenue for the patriarchate. The exact amount charged for use of the weights

and measures at Constantinople is unclear,47 but the overall income is obvious

from a document of 1172, which reveals the lease of Grado’s revenues from its

Constantinopolitan properties to Romano Mairono, a noted Venetian merchant, for 500

pounds of denarii veronensium per year. Hendy argues that the majority of this revenue

was produced by the weights and measures.48 There was also the danger that Venetian

merchants would attempt to use another set of weights and measures, either to gain a more

favourable outcome in the measuring process or to lower fees. The donation of 1107 also

addressed this issue:

And therefore no other balance or weight or measure, in Constantinople or in the quarter oughtto be in the possession of anyone else, except the balances and weights and measures of theaforementioned church [of Grado].49

Furthermore the donation described the penalties for those who might attempt to

circumvent the legitimately constituted system of weights and measures, a fine of 10 libre

J.M. Nicovich10

Page 11: Byzantine empire and Italy

of gold, which was a substantial sum for a serious infraction.50 The proper respect for the

weights and measures was absolutely necessary to protect honest Venetian merchants

from fraud, but also to protect the patriarchate from a loss of revenue. It is notable that the

fine against such circumvention was collected directly by Grado, not by the state, since it

was Grado’s property rights that were being infringed in the first place.

The charter of 1107 was once again an attempt to assuage the continuous poverty of

Grado. How then do we explain Paschall II’s letter of July 1109? The previous recorded

attempts to solve the problem, Domenico Silvio’s charter of September 1074, and the

clauses of the chrysobull of 1082 had failed because they relied on external parties not

directly controlled by the Doge. The churchmen of the lagoon and Alexius I Komnenos

had failed to meet their obligations. However, in September 1107 the momentum was

firmly in the hands of Doge Ordelafo Falier. He controlled the promised funds, properties,

and rights in Constantinople. Was Paschal addressing a failure of the Doge to make good

his own promises? This is highly unlikely. The chrysobull of 1082, and to a lesser degree

the charter of September 1074, were intended to be comprehensive solutions to Grado’s

poverty. The chrysobull seems to have been a kind of economic overkill, enriching the

patriarchate with yearly donations that would more than solve Grado’s problems. Ordelafo

Falier’s donation was tame in comparison. The yearly donations of denari were

significant, but were not a full solution. As for the properties and rights in Constantinople,

they were a tangible, renewable source of income, but it was not an instant fix.

After September 1107 Patriarch Gradenigo would have assigned priests, deacons and

lay representatives to St Akindynos, and they would sail to Constantinople. It would take

time for the clergy or other representatives to establish themselves both as clergy and as

administrators. They would busy themselves with recording the contents of St

Akindynos’s treasury, the stores, and properties, and to assess their value for rental

purposes, as well as to establishing procedures for the operation of the weights and

measures. Simply, it would have taken some time to get the personnel in place in

Constantinople and for them properly to acclimatize themselves to their environment and

new functions. By July 1109 only 22 months had elapsed since the original donation.

There would have been little time to make the patriarchate’s properties in Constantinople

profitable. Moreover, it is likely that the patriarchate had lost money in the short term in

setting up their operation overseas. Paschal’s complaints of July 1109 may thus have been

made too soon after the initial donation. It is also possible that the papal chancery may well

have had a backlog of work and had not yet issued Paschal’s letter for some time. In any

case the Venetians were working to solve the problem on their own without papal

exhortation.

Conclusion: the rise of the patriarchate

Notably, after 1109 there were no further papal letters to Venice decrying Grado’s poverty.

This very silence is ample evidence that the problem had been solved, at least in part, by

the donation of properties in Constantinople. Yet there is also later evidence of the long-

term efficacy of this solution, namely the growing power of the patriarchate within the

lagoons. Under the enterprising, zealous, and remarkably long-lived Patriarch Enrico

Dandolo (c.1134–c.1184), the patriarchate gained considerable new authority. An ardent

supporter of reform ideology as well as his own jurisdictional authority, Dandolo was

responsible for bringing Cistercians to the lagoons, establishing several houses of canons

regular, and asserting Grado’s status as ‘Primate of Dalmatia’, a further extension of

metropolitan authority. As Madden and Rando have both noted, none of this was achieved

Mediterranean Historical Review 11

Page 12: Byzantine empire and Italy

without significant conflict, both with the ducal court and with the bishop of Castello, the

diocesan head of the Rialto. In 1148 the Patriarch and his entire extended family were

exiled from Venice and the family home razed to the ground by ducal order. Yet Dandolo

ultimately triumphed, and in 1156 constructed a new patriarchal palace, not at Grado, but

at San Silvestro in the very heart of Venice itself, a tangible sign of the patriarchate’s

ascendancy.51 Dandolo, a forceful character, was clearly the driving force behind these

achievements, but it is difficult to imagine the political success of the Patriarchate without

the long-term solvency granted to the institution by its overseas properties. It may well be

that those rental properties in Constantinople, outside the lagoons and far from ducal

intervention, were what allowed Dandolo to survive his exile, while funding his other

struggles with the Doge and the bishop. Such funding for the Patriarch went well beyond

simple necessity. It was what allowed the Patriarch actively to assert authority over his

metropolitan see.

Acknowledgements

The author would like to thank Professors Thomas F. Madden and Warren Treadgold for theircomments on previous versions of this article, as well as the anonymous reader, whose commentsand suggestions were extremely helpful.

Notes

1. A chrysobull, or ‘golden bull’, refers to a variety of legal documents bearing the golden bullae,or seal, of the Byzantine Emperor. In many cases they were meant to confirm treaties withforeign powers, as in the case of Venice in 1082. Nicolas Oikonomides, ‘Chrysobull’, inOxford Dictionary of Byzantium, vol. 1, 451–2. A considerable body of literature concerningthe chrysobull of 1082 and its concessions to the Venetian church exists: H.F. Brown, ‘TheVenetians and the Venetian Quarter in Constantinople to the Close of the Twelfth Century’,Journal of Hellenic Studies 40 (1920): 70–1; Roberto Cessi, ‘Politica, Economica, Religione’,in Storia di Venezia, 318–21; Silvano Borsari, Venezia e Bisanzio nel XII secolo: I rapportiEconomici, 1–16; Donald M. Nicol, Byzantium and Venice: A Study in Diplomatic andCultural Relations, 59–63; David Jacoby, ‘Italian Privileges and Trade in Byzantium Beforethe Fourth Crusade: A Reconsideration’, Annuario de studios medievales 24 (1994): 349–69.The dating of the initial chrysobull has been the subject of considerable debate. Thomas F.Madden has recently summarized the various arguments, and through a fresh examination ofall available chronicles, cartularies as well as palaeographic and diplomatic evidence hesupports the traditional date of May 1082. Thomas F. Madden, ‘The chrysobull of Alexius IComnenus to the Venetians: The Date and the Debate’, Journal of Medieval History 28 (2002):23–41. David Jacoby has responded to Madden’s work, attacking Madden’s use ofpalaeographic evidence, but agreeing with his overall conclusions; essentially Madden iscorrect for the wrong reasons: David Jacoby, ‘Rejoinder: The chrysobull of Alexius IComnenus to the Venetians: The Date and the Debate’, Journal of Medieval History 28 (2002):199–204. Peter Frankopan has continued the discussion with a revisionist assault on the date of1082, asserting that there is much evidence for a date of 1092 instead. However, much ofFrankopan’s evidence is circumstantial at best, and he is forced to explain away a large amountof evidence for the traditional dating of 1082. Peter Frankopan, ‘Byzantine Trade Privileges toVenice in the Eleventh Century: The chrysobull of 1092’, Journal of Medieval History 30(2004): 135–60.

2. Borsari, Venezia e Bisanzio, 13. Nicol, Byzantium and Venice, 61. Thomas F. Madden, EnricoDandolo and the Rise of Venice, 8–9.

3. Madden, Enrico Dandolo, 52–3.4. The honorific title of protosebastos, roughly meaning ‘the preeminent one’, appeared in the

late eleventh century as a part of Alexios I’s general reform of the system of imperial titles, andwas usually given to members of the imperial family. See Alexander Kazdhan, ‘Sebastos’, inOxford Dictionary of Byzantium, vol. 3, 1862–3.

J.M. Nicovich12

Page 13: Byzantine empire and Italy

5. Borsari, Venezia e Bisanzio, 31.6. Marco Pozza and Giorgio Ravegnani, eds., I Trattati con Bisanzi 992–1198, 36–45.7. Cessi, ‘Politica, Economica, Religione’, 320; Borsari, Venezia e Bisanzio, 6–8; Nicol,

Byzantium and Venice, 60–1.8. Gregory VII, S. Gregorii VII Romani, coll. 0300D–0301B.9. Guido Bianchi, ‘Il Patriarca di Grado’, Studi Veneziani 8 (1966): 19–125.10. Transcriptions of the exchange betweenMarango, Peter ofAntioch, andMichael Cerulariusmay

be found in Luigi Lanfranchi, ed., Codice Diplomatico Veneziano 1050–1079 (transcription,Venice: Archivio di Stato, 1940–84), 29–35 [hereafter:CDV ]. See also Bianchi, ‘Il Patriarca diGrado’, 62–81.

11. H.E.J. Cowdrey, The Register of Pope Gregory VII, 129–30.12. Daniella Rando, Una Chiesa di Frontiera, 137–8; Madden, Enrico Dandolo, 23–4.13. Between 1006 and 1078 there are 10 surviving pious donations to San Zaccaria, and in all 10

cases the donors were residents of the terrafirma, and in several cases were members of theLombard nobility. The contessa of Treviso donated land in memory of her late husband in July1006, and the count of Vicenza gave land around Padua to the convent in March 1016.The comitial house ofVeronamade three separate donations in the 1050s.CDV, 1000–1049, 15,46–7;CDV, 1050–1079, 36–7, 38–9, 40–1. San Zaccaria also received several donations fromfamilies around the village of Monselice, dated March 1009, 31 January 1050, and 12 August1078.CDV, 1000–1049, 2–3;CDV, 1050–1079, 171. Themonastery even received an imperialconcession of lands near Verona from Conrad I in May 1027. CDV, 1000–1049, 104–5.

14. Irmgard Fees, Le Monache de San Zaccaria, 7–8.15. In 568 the Patriarch of Aquileia, fleeing the Lombard invasion, settled upon the small island of

Grado, a Novus Aquilensis. In subsequent decades the Lombards reestablished a mainlandPatriarchate at Old Aquileia, creating duelling claims to metropolitan authority over much ofthe region, even though the two Patriarchs were only a few scant miles apart. This jurisdictionalconflict, continued later by the Frankish conquerors of the region, was ongoing throughout theeleventh century.

16. Today Grado is a well-populated beach resort connected to mainland by a causeway, andincludes a substantial landmass. Much of this development involved the draining of marshlandin the nineteenth century, and throughout the Middle Ages Grado remained a small island withlittle noticeable population.

17. CDV, 1000–1049, 27; CDV, 1050–1079, 49.18. H.E.J. Cowdrey, Pope Gregory VII, 295.19. A by-product of the poverty of the Venetian church was a lack of corruption. Simony and

clerical marriage had not taken hold in the lagoons simply because there was littleecclesiastical property that important lay families wished to control. Rando, Una Chiesa, 137.

20. Gregory was likely unaware that the Venetians had already attempted to solve the problem.21. Dum Dei et Christi nomine quadam die resideremus in palacio nostro nos quidem Dominicus

Silvus per misericordiam Dei Venecie et Dalmacie dux una cum episcopis, abbatibus, iudicibuset maxima parte nostrorum fidelium, inter cetera que ad provectum nostre patrie pertinebant,pertractare cepimus de nostro Gradensi patriarchatu, qui nostrarum omnium ecclesiarum ettotius Venecie caput. Luigi Lanfranchi ed., San Giorgio Maggiore. vol. II (Venice: Comitatoper la Pubblicazione delle Fonti Relative alla Storia di Venezia, 1968), no. 31: 93 [hereafter:SGM].

22. Hec omnia predicti episcopatus et abbatie in kalendis septembris persolvere debent nostropatriarchatui per singulos annos. SGM, no. 31: 94.

23. The reference in the concession to centum libras nostrorum denariorum likely notes that thecoinage conceded was issued by the local Venetian mint in operation from 1056 to 1125, andnot from the imperial mint at Verona, the most prominent in Northern Italy. Louise Robbert,‘Il Sistema Monetario’ in Storia di Venezia, 410.

24. F.C. Hodgson, The Early History of Venice, 208.25. In primis itaque totam terram nostri ducatus que dicitur Villa, posita in Civitate Nova et

centum amphoras vini, quas Caprenses de comitatu Istrie ex antique consuetudine omni annopersolvere debent nostro palacio et centum libras nostrorum denariorum, que fuerunt decamera Sancti Marci et alias ducentas libras denariorum, que fuerunt de roga. Et iste trecentelibre ad lucrum esse debent, capetanea semper salva. Et insuper alias libras denariorumcentum sexaginta de roga magistratus– – – – –. De Olivensi etiam episcopatu libras

Mediterranean Historical Review 13

Page 14: Byzantine empire and Italy

denariorum viginti. De Torcellensi episcopatu libras denarorum viginti. De Metamaucensiepiscopatu dimidiam piscariam que est posita in loco qui dicitur Faviraga et insuper modiosfrumenti quinque. De episcopatu Equiliensi modios de frumento septem. De episcopatuCivitatis Nove sex dies de terra araturia ubi sunt vine, in loco qui dicitur Mugla. De episcopatuCaprulensi fundamentum salinarum, secundum firmamentum cartule quam ipse Bonusepiscopus fecit nostro patriarchatui. De monasterio Sancte Trinitatis de Brutulo modiosfrumenti duodecim. De monasterio Sancti Illarii libras denariorum viginti quinque. Demonasterio Sancti Georgii libras denariorum decem. De monasterio Sancti Felicis de Amianasmodios frumenti sex. SGM, vol. II, no. 31: 93–4.

26. The standard ratio for silver coinage, established in the Carolingian period, was 1 libra ¼ 12solidi ¼ 240 denari. Robbert, ‘Il Sistema Monetario’, 410.

27. Hoc videlicet quod processor noster bone memorie Dominicus Contarenus dux laudationeepiscoporum, abbatium, iudicium, ceterorumque complurium bonorum hominum statuit. SGM,no. 31: 93.

28. See above, 2.29. The wide range of the exchange rate is due to differences in the gold coinage being exchanged,

and the documents are not clear as to their origins, either Byzantine, Muslim, or otherwise.Robbert, ‘The Venetian Money Market’, 65.

30. These local coins, produced between 1056 and 1125, imitated imperial coins produced out ofVerona, but were devalued by half over the period. Robbert, ‘Il Sistema Monetario’, 410.

31. Paschalis II episcopis et clericis, duci, nobililibus et populo Venetiae: dolet, metropolimGradensis tanta inopia laborare, ut patriarcha nec in ea tute ac decenter permanere valeatnec aliquam parochiam habeat, in qua secundum dignitatis suae modum debeat commoravi.G.F. Tafel and G.M. Thomas, eds., Urkunden zur alteren Handels-und Staatsgeschichte derRepublik Venedig, vol. I, 61–2 [hereafter: TTh].

32. For the considerable successes of the later reign of Alexios I see Warren Treadgold, A Historyof the Byzantine State and Society, 619–29.

33. David Jacoby, ‘The Venetian Quarter of Constantinople from 1082 to 1261’, 154–5.34. Pozza and Ravegnani, Trattati con Bisanzio, 30; Raymond Janin, Constantinople Byzantine,

map no. 1. Borsari, Venezia e Bisanzio, 31.35. Igitur nos quidem Vitalis Faletrus Dodoni Dei gratia Venetie et Dalmatie dux et imperialis

protonsevastos, una cum nostris iudicibus et aliis bonis hominibus nostris fidelibus cum nostrissuccessoribus et heredibus, nullo penitus cogente aut suadente nec vim inferente, sed iustaevoluntatis constitutione et oratione abbatis ac monachorum ius comoti, optima et spontaneanostra voluntate, pro remedio animarum nostrarum, tempore domni Karimanni venerabilisabbatis monasterii Beati Georgii, damus, donamus, concedimus et contradictimus, offerimus actransactamus eidem monasterio Beatis Georgii et prenominato eius abbati domno Karimannosuisque successoribus in perpetuum tantum de nostris proprietatis terrarum et casarum,cohopertis vel discoopertis, sitis infra urbem Costantinopolitanam, quas nos de imperatoreAlexio invenimus per grossovoli et pratico cartulas. Marco Pozza, ed. Gli Atti Originalidella Cancellari Veneziana I (1090–1198) (Venice: Il Cardo, 1994), no. 1: 31–2; SGM, no. 69:168–75; Borsari, Venezia e Bisanzio, 36–8.

36. Borsari, ‘L’Organizzazione dei Possesi Veneziani’, 195.37. Extra illud totum quod nos datum habemus ad monasterium Sancti Nicolai per cartulas

firmitatis. Pozza, Cancellaria Veneziana, no. 1: 32.38. Ex alio latere firmante in proprietas quae nunc est Sancti Nicolai. Ibid., no. 1: 32.39. Borsari, ‘L’Organizzazione dei Possessi’, 195; Borsari, Venezia e Bisanzio, 36–9.40. Quia nos quidem Ordelafus Faletro, gratia Dei Venetie Dux, et Imperialis Protosevastos, cum

nostris successoribus dare et persolvere debuimus nostro Gradensi Patriarchatui omni annode roga magistratus nostri palatii libras denariorum centum sexaginta, sicut continetus inpromissionis carta, quam fecit Domenicus Silvius, quondam Dux, cum Episcopis et Abbatibuset populo Venetiae, et alias centum libras denariorum, que fuerunt de camera Sancti Marci,que fuerunt expense pro Iohanne Saponario, defuncto Patriarcha. Archivio di Stato diVenezia, Mensa Patriarcale, busta 9, copia 1. TTh, vol. I, no. 32: 67.

41. SGM, vol. II, no. 31: 93.42. Idcirco nos praenominatus Ordelafus, gratia Dei Venetiae Dux et Imperialis Protosevastos,

cum nostris Episcopis et iudicibus et populo Venetiae cum nostris successoribus et heredibus,ab hodie in antea damus et concedimus vobis quidem, domno Iohanni Gradonico, venerabili

J.M. Nicovich14

Page 15: Byzantine empire and Italy

Gradensi Patriarchae, et vestris successoribus in perpetuum, videlicet Ecclesiam beatiArchidani cum omni suo territorie et benefitio, positam in regali urbe Constantinopoli, quae estantiquitus de iure et possessione nostri palatii secundum imperialis crisovoli confirmationem.TTh, vol. I, no. 32: 67–8.

43. There is no surviving information about what clergy would have served St Akindynos prior toits donation to Grado in 1107. Likely clergy from various parish churches in the lagoons orchaplains of San Marco would have been contracted to serve a set term in Constantinople.

44. Hanc namque preaenominatam et designatam ecclesiam cum toto suo thesauro et paliis etlibris et cum omnibus suis habentiis et pertinentibus ab intus et foris, quas nunc habet et inantea aliquot modo habitura est, cum suis argasteriis universis et cum suo mankipio et furno etcum omnibus stateris et rubis et ponderibus et cum cunctis metris tam ad oleum, quam advinum, et cum omnibus nostris tabernis, quae in praedicta urbe sub nostra potestate essevidentur. TTh, vol. I, no. 32: 68.

45. M.F. Hendy, Studies in the Byzantine Monetary Economy, c. 350–1450, 334–6.46. This remains only a suggestion. The Venetian clergy were drawn from the same population as

the sea-going merchants, and often such clerics were involved in merchant activity on behalf oftheir families as well. They could have the same potential for fraud as any other lay person, buttheir religious function added at least a pretence of fairness.

47. In 1149 San Giorgio di Rodosto, a Venetian church dependant on San Giorgio di Maggiore,charged Venetians two stamines, or billon trachea, to Venetians and four stamines toByzantines. An extra charge was levied for items above a set weight. See Hendy, ByzantineMonetary Economy, 335.

48. Ibid., 334.49. Itaque nulla alia statera, vel rubus, vel pondus et metrum in Constantinopoli, vel in imbolo sub

manu alicuius esse debeant, nisi statera et ruba et pondera et metra praedictae Ecclesiae. TTh,vol. I, no. 32: 68.

50. Ibid.51. Madden, Enrico Dandolo, 24–37; Rando, Una Chiesa di Frontiera, 173–90.

Notes on contributor

John Mark Nicovich is an assistant professor of History at William Carey University, located inHattiesburg, Mississippi. He earned his PhD at Saint Louis University under the direction of ThomasF. Madden and Warren Treadgold. His current research involves Venice and the crusadingmovement in the fourteenth through sixteenth centuries.

Bibliography

Bianchi, Guido. ‘Il Patriarca di Grado Domenico Marango tra Roma e l’Oriente’. Studi Veneziani8 (1966): 19–125.

Borsari, Silvano. ‘L’Organizzazione dei Possesi Veneziani nell’Impero Bizantino nel XII secoli’. InStudi Albanologici, Balcani, Bizantini e Orientali, 191–204. Florence: Olski, 1986.

———. Venezia e Bisanzio nel XII secolo: I rapporti Economici. Venice: Deputazione Editrice,1988.

Brown, H.F. ‘The Venetians and the Venetian Quarter in Constantinople to the Close of the TwelfthCentury’. Journal of Hellenic Studies 40 (1920): 68–88.

Cessi, Roberto. ‘Politica, Economica, Religione’. Storia di Venezia. 68–476, Venice: Centrointernazionale delle arti e del costume, 1957.

Cowdrey, H.E.J. Pope Gregory VII, 1073–1085. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2002.Cowdrey, H.E.J., trans. The Register of Pope Gregory VII 1073–1085. Oxford: Oxford University

Press, 2002.Fees, Irmgard. Le Monache de San Zaccaria a Venezia nei secoli XII e XIII. Venice: Centro Tedesco

di Studi Veneziani, 1998.Frankopan, Peter. ‘Byzantine Trade Privileges to Venice in the Eleventh Century: The chrysobull of

1092’. Journal of Medieval History 30 (2004): 135–60.Gregory, VII. S. Gregorii VII Romani pontificis Epistolae et Diplomata pontificalia. In Patrologiae

cursus completes, Series Latina, vol. 148, ed. J.P. Migne. Paris: J.P. Migne, 1853.Hendy, M.F. Studies in the Byzantine Monetary Economy, c. 350–1450. Cambridge: Cambridge

University Press, 1985.

Mediterranean Historical Review 15

Page 16: Byzantine empire and Italy

Hodgson, F.C. The Early History of Venice from the Foundation to the Conquest of ConstantinopleA.D. 1204. London: George Allen, 1901.

Jacoby, David. ‘Italian Privileges and Trade in Byzantium Before the Fourth Crusade: AReconsideration’. Annuario de studios medievales 24 (1994): 349–69.

———. ‘Rejoinder: The chrysobull of Alexius I Comnenus to the Venetians: The Date and theDebate’. Journal of Medieval History 28 (2002): 199–204.

———. ‘The Venetian Quarter of Constantinople from 1082 to 1261: TopographicalConsiderations’. In Novum Millenium: Studies on Byzantine History and Culture Dedicated toPaul Speck, ed. Claudia Sode and Sarolta Takacs. Aldershot: Ashgate, 1999.

Janin, Raymond. Constantinople Byzantine: Development Urbain et Repertoire Topographique,Editione revisee. Paris: Institut Francais D’etudes Byzantines, 1964.

Kazdhan, Alexander. ‘Sebastos’. In Oxford Dictionary of Byzantium, vol. 3, ed. Alexander Kazdhan,1862–3. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1991.

Lanfranchi, Luigi, ed. Codice Diplomatico Veneziano 1050–1079 (transcription). Venice: Archiviodi Stato, 1940–84.

———, ed. San Giorgio Maggiore, vol. II. Venice: Comitato per la Pubblicazione delle FontiRelative alla Storia di Venezia, 1968.

Madden, Thomas F. ‘The chrysobull of Alexius I Comnenus to the Venetians: The Date and theDebate’. Journal of Medieval History 28 (2002): 23–41.

———. Enrico Dandolo and the Rise of Venice. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins, 2003.Nicol, Donald M. Byzantium and Venice: A Study in Diplomatic and Cultural Relations. Cambridge:

Cambridge University Press, 1988.Oikonomides, Nicolas. ‘Chrysobull’. In Oxford Dictionary of Byzantium, vol. 1, ed. Alexander

Kazdhan, 451–2. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1991.Kazdhan, Alexander, ed. Oxford Dictionary of Byzantium. 1862–3, Oxford: Oxford University

Press, 1991.Pozza, Marco, ed. Gli Atti Originali della Cancellari Veneziana I (1090–1198). Venice: Il Cardo,

1994.Pozza, Marco, and Giorgio Ravegnani, eds. I Trattati con Bisanzi 992–1198. Venice: Il Cardo, 1993.Rando, Daniella. Una Chiesa di Frontiera: Le istitutiozioni ecclesiastiche veneziane nei secoli

VI–XII. Bologna: Il Mulino, 1994.Robbert, Louise. ‘Il Sistema Monetario’. In Storia di Venezia dale origini alla caduta della

Serenissima: II, L’Eta del Comune. 409–36. Venice: Istituto della Enciclopedia Italiana, 1995.———. ‘The Venetian Money Market, 1150–1229’. Studi Veneziani XIII (1971): 3–94.Tafel, G.F., and G.M. Thomas, eds. Urkunden zur alteren Handels-und Staatsgeschichte der

Republik Venedig. vol. I. Vienna: Kaiserlich-koniglichen Hof-und Stattsdruckereri, 1856–7.Treadgold, Warren. A History of the Byzantine State and Society. Stanford: Stanford University

Press, 1997.

J.M. Nicovich16

Page 17: Byzantine empire and Italy