Behavioral finance.ppt

52
An Introduction to Behavioral Finance SIP Course on “Stock Market Anomalies and Asset ManagementProfessors S.P. Kothari and Jon Lewellen March 15, 2004

description

 

Transcript of Behavioral finance.ppt

Page 1: Behavioral finance.ppt

An Introduction to Behavioral Finance

SIP Course on “Stock Market Anomalies and Asset Management”

Professors S.P. Kothari and Jon Lewellen

March 15, 2004

Page 2: Behavioral finance.ppt

2

An Introduction to Behavioral Finance

Efficient markets hypothesis Large number of market participants Incentives to gather and process information about

securities and trade on the basis of their analysis until individual participant’s valuation is similar to the observed market price

Prices in such markets reflect information available to the participants, which means opportunities to earn above-normal rates of return on a consistent basis are limited

Prediction: Stock returns are (almost) impossible to predict Except that riskier securities on average earn higher rates of

returns compared to less risky firms

Page 3: Behavioral finance.ppt

3

An Introduction to Behavioral Finance

Behavioral finance Widespread evidence of anomalies is inconsistent with the

efficient markets theory Bad models, data mining, and results by chance Alternatively, invalid theory

Anomalies as a pre-cursor to behavioral finance Challenge in developing a behavioral finance theory of

markets Evidence of both over- and under-reaction to events

Event-dependent over- and under-reaction, e.g., IPOs, dividend initiations, seasoned equity issues, earnings announcements, accounting accruals

Horizon dependent phenomenon: short-term overreaction, medium-term momentum, and long-run overreaction

Page 4: Behavioral finance.ppt

4

An Introduction to Behavioral Finance

Behavioral finance theory rests on the following three assumptions/characteristics Investors exhibit information processing biases that

cause them to over- and under-react Individual investors’ errors/biases in processing

information must be correlated across investors so that they are not averaged out

Limited arbitrage: Existence of rational investors should not be sufficient to make markets efficient

Page 5: Behavioral finance.ppt

5

Behavioral finance theories

Human information processing biases Information processing biases are generally

relative to the Bayes rule for updating our priors on the basis of new information

Two biases are central to behavioral finance theories

Representativeness bias (Kahneman and Tversky, 1982) Conservatism bias (Edwards, 1968). Other biases: Over confidence and biased self-attribution

Page 6: Behavioral finance.ppt

6

Behavioral finance theories

Human information processing biases Representativeness bias causes people to over-

weight recent information and deemphasize base rates or priors

E.g., conclude too quickly that a yellow object found on the street is gold (i.e., ignore the low base rate of finding gold)

People over-infer the properties of the underlying distribution on the basis of sample information

For example, investors might extrapolate a firm’s recent high sales growth and thus overreact to news in sales growth

Representativeness bias underlies many recent behavioral finance models of market inefficiency

Page 7: Behavioral finance.ppt

7

Behavioral finance theories

Human information processing biases Conservatism bias: Investors are slow to update their

beliefs, i.e., they underweight sample information which contributes to investor under-reaction to news

Conservatism bias implies investor underreaction to new information

Conservatism bias can generate short-term momentum in stock returns The post-earnings announcement drift, i.e., the tendency of

stock prices to drift in the direction of earnings news for three-to-twelve months following an earnings announcement also entails investor under-reaction

Page 8: Behavioral finance.ppt

8

Behavioral finance theories

Human information processing biases Investor overconfidence

Overconfident investors place too much faith in their ability to process information

Investors overreact to their private information about the company’s prospects

Biased self-attribution Overreact to public information that confirms an

investor’s private information Underreact to public signals that disconfirm an investor’s

private information Contradictory evidence is viewed as due to chance Genrate underreaction to public signals

Page 9: Behavioral finance.ppt

9

Behavioral finance theories

Human information processing biases Investor overconfidence and biased self-attribution

In the short run, overconfidence and biased self-attribution together result in a continuing overreaction that induces momentum.

Subsequent earnings outcomes eventually reveal the investor overconfidence, however, resulting in predictable price reversals over long horizons.

Since biased self-attribution causes investors to down play the importance of some publicly disseminated information, information releases like earnings announcements generate incomplete price adjustments.

Page 10: Behavioral finance.ppt

10

Behavioral finance theories

In addition to exhibiting information-processing biases, the biases must be correlated across investors so that they are not averaged out

People share similar heuristics Focus on those that worked well in our evolutionary past Therefore, people are subject to similar biases Experimental psychology literature confirms systematic

biases among people

Page 11: Behavioral finance.ppt

11

Behavioral finance theories

Limited arbitrage Efficient markets theory is predicated on the

assumption that market participants with incentives to gather, process, and trade on information will arbitrage away systematic mispricing of securities caused by investors’ information processing biases

Arbitrageurs will earn only a normal rate of return on their information-gathering activities

Market efficiency and arbitrage: EMH assumes arbitrage forces are constantly at work

Economic incentive to arbitrageurs exists only if there is mispricing, i.e., mispricing exists in equilibrium

Page 12: Behavioral finance.ppt

12

Behavioral finance theories

Behavioral finance assumes arbitrage is limited. What would cause limited arbitrage? Economic incentive to arbitrageurs exists only if there

is mispricing Therefore, mispricing must exist in equilibrium Existence of rational investors must not be sufficient Notwithstanding arbitrageurs, inefficiency can persist

for long periods because arbitrage is costly Trading costs: Brokerage, B-A spreads, price impact/slippage Holding costs: Duration of the arbitrage and cost of short

selling Information costs: Information acquisition, analysis and

monitoring

Page 13: Behavioral finance.ppt

13

Behavioral finance theories

Why can’t large firms end limited arbitrage? Arbitrage requires gathering of information about a firm’s

prospects, spotting of mispriced securities, and trading in the securities until the mispricing is eliminated

Analysts with the information typically do not have the capital needed for trading

Firms (principals) supply the capital, but they must also delegate decision making (i.e., trading) authority to those who possess the information (agents)

Agents cannot transfer their information to the principal, so decisions must be made by those who possess information

Agents are compensated on the basis of outcomes, but the principal sets limits on the amount of capital at the agent’s disposal (the book)

Limited capital means arbitrage can be limited

Page 14: Behavioral finance.ppt

14

Behavioral finance theories

Like the efficient markets theory, behavioral finance makes predictions about pricing behavior that must be tested Need for additional careful work in this respect

Only then can we embrace behavioral finance as an adequate descriptor of the stock market behavior

Recent research in finance is in this spirit just as the anomalies literature documents inconsistencies with the efficient markets hypothesis

Page 15: Behavioral finance.ppt

15

Stock Returns, Aggregate Earnings Surprises, and Behavioral Finance

 S.P. Kothari, Jonathan Lewellen,

Jerold B. Warner

 

 

SIP Course on “Stock Market Anomalies and Asset Management”

March 15, 2004

Page 16: Behavioral finance.ppt

16

Objective of the study

We study the relation between market index returns and aggregate earnings surprises We focus on concurrent and lagged

surprises Do prices react slowly? Is there discount rate information in

aggregate earnings changes?

Page 17: Behavioral finance.ppt

17

At the firm level, post-earnings announcement drift is well-known

The slow adjustment to public information is inconsistent with market efficiency

Slow adjustment is consistent with behavioral finance Barberis/Shleifer/Vishny (BSV, 1998) Daniel/Hirshleifer/Subrahmanyam (DHS, 1998) Hong/Stein (HS, 1999)

Aggregate return-earnings relation serves as an out-of-sample test of the behavioral hypothesis of investor underreaction

Literature concentrates on cross-sectional return predictability

We provide time-series evidence

Motivation

Page 18: Behavioral finance.ppt

18

Main findings Aggregate relation does not mimic the firm-level

relation Market returns do not depend on past earnings surprises Inconsistent with underreaction (or overreaction)

Market returns are negatively (not positively) related to concurrent earnings news

#s seem economically significant Earnings and interest/ discount rate shocks are positively

correlated Good aggregate earnings news can be bad news

Decomposing earnings changes does not fully eliminate the negative correlation between earnings news and returns, a troubling result

Page 19: Behavioral finance.ppt

19

Firm level drift and behavioral models

Drift could occur if investors systematically ignore the time-series properties of earnings.

Bernard/Thomas (1990) show that quarterly earnings changes have positive serial dependence (.34,.19,.06 at the first 3 lags)

If investors underestimate the dependence, prices will respond slowly and they will be surprised by predictable changes in earnings.

Consistent with this, the pattern of trading profits at subsequent earnings announcements matches the autocorrelation pattern.

Page 20: Behavioral finance.ppt

20

Evidence

Time-series properties of earnings Stock returns and aggregate earnings

surprises Returns, earnings, and discount rates

Page 21: Behavioral finance.ppt

21

Earnings series Compustat Quarterly database, 1970 – 2000 NYSE, Amex, and NASDAQ stocks with …

Earnings before ext. items, quarter t and t – 4 Price, quarter t – 4 Book value, quarter t – 4

 Plus … December fiscal year end Price > $1 Exclude top and bottom 0.5% based on dE/P

Page 22: Behavioral finance.ppt

22

Sample

Quarterly returns (%), 1970 – 2000

Returns N VW EW

CRSP avg. 6,062 3.34 3.82 std. deviation -- 8.79 12.60 Sample avg. 2,423 3.26 3.42 std. deviation -- 8.38 11.40

Page 23: Behavioral finance.ppt

23

E/P, 1970 – 2000

-0.04

-0.02

0.00

0.02

0.04

0.06

1970.1 1974.1 1978.1 1982.1 1986.1 1990.1 1994.1 1998.1

E/P-agg

E/P-ew

Page 24: Behavioral finance.ppt

24

Firms w/ positive earnings, 1970 – 2000

0

1000

2000

3000

4000

5000

1970.1 1974.1 1978.1 1982.1 1986.1 1990.1 1994.1 1998.1

0.0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1.0

Number of firms (left scale)

Fraction E > 0 (right scale)

Page 25: Behavioral finance.ppt

25

Quarterly earnings changes (%),

1970 – 2000 Aggregate VW EW

dE/P dE/B dE/E dE/P dE/P Full sample avg 0.15 0.25 8.26 0.10 0.30 stdev 0.39 0.59 18.58 0.36 0.55 Small stocks avg 0.42 0.39 -- 0.56 0.86 stdev 1.18 1.14 -- 0.90 1.13 Large stocks avg 0.14 0.25 7.90 0.10 0.08 stdev 0.37 0.58 17.60 0.35 0.38 Low B/M avg 0.17 0.54 12.11 0.16 0.60 stdev 0.23 0.73 16.69 0.22 0.69 High B/M avg 0.19 0.11 -- 0.09 0.22 stdev 1.13 0.81 -- 1.02 1.21

Page 26: Behavioral finance.ppt

26

Aggregate earnings growth, 1970 – 2000

-0.60

-0.40

-0.20

0.00

0.20

0.40

0.60

1970.1 1974.1 1978.1 1982.1 1986.1 1990.1 1994.1 1998.1

dE/E-AGG

Page 27: Behavioral finance.ppt

27

dE scaled by lagged price, 1970 – 2000

-.015

-.010

-.005

.000

.005

.010

.015

1970.1 1974.1 1978.1 1982.1 1986.1 1990.1 1994.1 1998.1

dE/P-VWdE/P-EW

Page 28: Behavioral finance.ppt

28

Autocorrelations

Seasonally-differenced earnings (dE = Et – Et-4)

Estimation  dE/St = 0 + k dE/St-k + t 

dE/St = 0 + 1 dE/St-1 + 2 dE/St-2 + ….. +

5 dE/St-5 + t

Market: Time-series regressions Firms: Fama-MacBeth cross-sectional

regressions

Page 29: Behavioral finance.ppt

29

Autocorrelations, dE/P, 1970 – 2000

Simple regressions Multiple regressions

Lag Slope T-stat Adj. R2 Slope T-stat Adj. R2

Firms 1 0.38 18.48 -- 0.40 18.39 -- 2 0.22 14.58 -- 0.14 11.20 3 0.08 5.67 -- 0.06 6.47 4 -0.28 -16.82 -- -0.42 -22.83 5 -0.11 -7.03 -- 0.16 12.93

EW 1 0.64 8.81 0.39 0.61 6.33 0.43 2 0.40 4.62 0.14 0.11 1.05 3 0.14 1.49 0.01 0.00 0.01 4 -0.15 -1.62 0.01 -0.30 -2.76 5 -0.21 -2.26 0.03 0.04 0.40 VW 1 0.73 11.54 0.52 0.73 7.75 0.57 2 0.52 6.65 0.26 0.22 1.93 3 0.23 2.55 0.04 -0.22 -1.92 4 -0.00 -0.03 -0.01 -0.18 -1.62 5 -0.12 -1.30 0.01 0.07 0.80

Page 30: Behavioral finance.ppt

30

Implications

Basic message Pattern similar for firms and market Persistence stronger for market – good for tests

Specifics Transitory, idiosyncratic component in firm

earnings Aggregate earnings changes are permanent Earnings changes predictable but volatile ( = 18.6%)

AR1 similar to AR5

Page 31: Behavioral finance.ppt

31

Returns and earnings surprises

Rt+k = + dE/Pt + et+k

 k = 0, …, 4  Changes and surprises  Market: Time-series regressions  Firms: Fama-MacBeth cross-sectional

regressions

Page 32: Behavioral finance.ppt

32

Returns and earnings, 1970 – 2000

Earnings change Earnings surprise

k Slope T-stat Adj. R2 Slope T-stat Adj. R2

Firms 0 0.53 26.94 -- 1 0.58 28.70 -- 2 0.20 10.66 -- 3 0.09 5.24 -- 4 0.00 0.03 --

EW 0 -1.30 -0.90 0.00 1.54 0.85 0.04 1 -3.75 -2.60 0.05 -3.70 -2.04 0.05 2 -2.81 -1.97 0.02 -3.03 -1.65 0.01 3 -1.36 -0.95 0.00 1.15 0.63 0.03 4 -3.14 -2.23 0.03 -4.48 -2.43 0.03 VW 0 -4.98 -2.31 0.03 -2.59 -0.83 0.04 1 -5.23 -2.41 0.04 -10.10 -3.34 0.07 2 -0.80 -0.37 -0.01 0.51 0.16 -0.01 3 -1.34 -0.63 -0.01 -1.41 -0.45 -0.01 4 -0.90 -0.42 -0.01 -3.05 -0.97 -0.01

Page 33: Behavioral finance.ppt

33

Contemporaneous relation

Explanatory power: 4 – 8%  Fitted values: dE/P-vw

Std. dev. of earnings surprises = 0.25% Slope = –10.10 Two std. deviation shock –5% drop in prices

 Historical Earnings change in top 25%: return 1% (s.e. =

1.7%) Earnings change in bottom 25%: return 7% (s.e. =

1.6%)

Page 34: Behavioral finance.ppt

34

Contemporaneous relation

Early overreaction No theory Not in firm returns 

Movements in discount rates 

Rt = d,t – r,t

Cash flow news vs. expected-return news

Page 35: Behavioral finance.ppt

35

Returns and past earnings Zero to negative No evidence of under-reaction Inconsistent with behavioral theories Results are robust

Alternative definitions of earnings Subperiods Annual returns and earnings Subsets of stocks (size, B/M terciles)

Page 36: Behavioral finance.ppt

36

Summary observations

Large portfolio Earnings more persistent Initial market reaction more negative Puzzling from a cashflow-news perspective

Small portfolio Reversal at lag 4 Negatively related to CRSP, but not own

returns

Page 37: Behavioral finance.ppt

37

Earnings and discount rates

Rt = d,t – r,td,t = cashflow newsr,t = expected-return news = discount-rate news

Returns and earningscov(dEt, Rt) = cov(dEt, d,t) – cov(dEt, r,t)cov(dEt, r,t)?

inflation and interest rates (+) consumption smoothing (–) changes in aggregate risk aversion (–)

Page 38: Behavioral finance.ppt

38

Earnings and the macroeconomy, 1970 – 2000: Correlations

Nominal dE Real dE

EW VW EW VW

TBILL 0.35 0.60 0.27 0.50 TERM -0.35 -0.52 -0.33 -0.52 DEF -0.59 -0.37 -0.66 -0.49

SENT 0.37 0.13 0.39 0.20

GDP 0.40 0.54 0.61 0.67 IPROD 0.67 0.65 0.72 0.74 CONS 0.29 0.42 0.53 0.52

dE = seasonally-differenced earnings Macro = annual changes or growth rates, ending in qtr t

Page 39: Behavioral finance.ppt

39

Earnings and the macroeconomy, 1970 – 2000

dEt = + TBILLt + TERMt + DEFt + dEt-1 + Nominal dE Real dE

EW VW EW VW

TBILL 0.04 0.04 0.02 0.03 1.39 2.72 0.73 1.78

TERM 0.00 -0.01 -0.01 -0.02 0.09 -0.29 -0.23 -0.69

DEF -0.55 -0.22 -0.64 -0.26 -4.95 -3.96 -5.70 -4.79

dEt-1 0.39 0.53 0.35 0.53 4.62 7.53 4.29 7.71

Adj. R2 0.49 0.62 0.53 0.62

Adj. R2 w/o AR1 0.41 0.44 0.46 0.43

Page 40: Behavioral finance.ppt

40

Controlling for discount rates

Two-stage approach

dEt = + TBILLt + TERMt +

DEFt + dEt-1 + Rt+k = + Fitted(dEt) + Residual(dEt) + et+k

Timing?

Rt Rt+1 Rt+2 Rt+3 Rt+4

dEt

Page 41: Behavioral finance.ppt

41

Returns and earnings, 1970 – 2000

Rt+k = + Fitted(dEt) + Residual(dEt) + et+k, Fitted dE Residual dE

k Slope T-stat Slope T-stat Adj. R2

EW 0 -6.86 -3.44 3.57 1.89 0.10 1 -5.01 -2.51 -3.02 -1.55 0.05 2 -2.93 -1.45 -2.44 -1.23 0.01 3 -4.20 -2.09 1.47 0.75 0.02 4 -1.55 -0.76 -4.53 -2.28 0.03 VW 0 -9.08 -3.27 0.76 0.23 0.07 1 -2.58 -0.95 -9.27 -2.84 0.05 2 -2.84 -1.02 2.30 0.69 0.00 3 -1.09 -0.39 -1.65 -0.49 -0.01 4 0.29 0.10 -2.53 -0.75 -0.01

Page 42: Behavioral finance.ppt

42

Annual dE/P, 1970 – 2000 Rt+k = + Fitted(dEt) + Residual(dEt) + et+k, Fitted dE Residual dE

k Slope T-stat Slope T-stat Adj. R2

EW 0 -4.49 -2.03 -2.30 -1.15 0.11 1 -0.64 -0.26 1.29 0.58 -0.06 2 2.19 0.88 0.71 0.32 -0.04 3 1.11 0.45 -0.27 -0.13 -0.07 VW 0 -5.86 -2.04 -3.97 -1.23 0.11 1 -1.19 -0.40 7.74 2.29 0.11 2 2.95 0.91 -1.75 -0.48 -0.04 3 1.41 0.44 0.71 0.20 -0.07

Page 43: Behavioral finance.ppt

43

How big are the effects?

Over the last 30 years, CRSP VWT portfolio Increased 6.5% in value in the quarters with

negative earnings growth Increased 1.9% in value in quarters with

positive earnings growth

Page 44: Behavioral finance.ppt

44

Conclusions

Market’s reaction to earnings surprises much different at the aggregate level Negative reaction to good earnings news Past earnings contain little (inconsistent) information

about future returns Investment strategy: Long in quarters when aggregate

earnings changes are negative Open questions

Do earnings proxy for discount rates? Is there a coherent behavioral story for the patterns?

Page 45: Behavioral finance.ppt

45

Richardson and Sloan (2003): External

Financing and Future Stock Returns Prior evidence: Market is sluggish in rationally

incorporating information in managers’ market timing motivation for external financing

Market timing: Raise funds when the firm is overvalued and repurchase shares when the firm is undervalued.

Slow assimilation of the information can be because of investors’ information processing biases

Sluggish reaction means opportunities for abnormal returns

How large are the returns to a trading strategy? What is the source of the abnormal returns? Is it related to the

use of proceeds from external financing? Richardson and Sloan: Examine returns to a trading rule

based on net external financing (not individual decisions like share repurchasing)

Page 46: Behavioral finance.ppt

46

Returns following external financing

Prior evidence Low returns following equity offerings, debt offerings,

and bank borrowings High returns following share repurchases Managers seem to time external financing

transactions to exploit mispricing Market’s immediate reaction to the financing decisions

is incomplete (underreaction to public announcements of voluntary decisions)

Market gradually reacts over the following one-to-three years – inconsistent with market efficiency and consistent with some of the information-processing biases

Page 47: Behavioral finance.ppt

47

Returns following external financing

Richardson and Sloan show that Net external financing generates a 12-month

abnormal return of about 16% (Table 5) The return is on long-minus-short position that has

a zero initial investment Long position is in firms that raise the least external

financing (i.e., repurchase shares or retire debt) Short position is in firms that raise the most

external financing – issue equity or debt or borrow from a bank

Page 48: Behavioral finance.ppt

48

Returns following external financing

Richardson and Sloan show that Use of the proceeds from external financing

matters (Table 6) Investment in operating assets generates highest

return on the zero-investment portfolio Suggests managers over-invest in assets Market fails to fully assimilate information in accruals

What are accruals? Earnings (X) = CF + Accruals (A) When you sell on credit, earnings increase, cash flow

does not, but accruals in the form of accounts receivables increase

Investment in operating assets is a form of accrual

Page 49: Behavioral finance.ppt

49

Returns following external financing

Acrobat Document

Page 50: Behavioral finance.ppt

50

Returns following external financing

External financing decisions as well as exceptional corporate performance (high sales growth or extreme decline) are all associated with large accruals A large increase in sales translates into a large

increase in receivables, so an accrual increase is associated with increased sales

Accruals also present opportunities to the management to manipulate them and/or create them fictitiously A fictitious dollar of sales and receivables accruals

contributes dollar for dollar to earnings before taxes and also enhances profit margin (because the cost of goods sold is not increased with fictitious sales)

Page 51: Behavioral finance.ppt

51

Returns following external financing

Since extreme performance or financing activities or fictitious sales are typically not sustainable, accruals revert

If investors suffer from information processing biases, do they recognize the time-series properties of accruals and its implications for future earnings?

In particular, does the market recognize that “The persistence of current earnings is decreasing in the magnitude of accruals and increasing in cash flows?”

Market overvalues accruals (i.e., fails to recognize that accruals-based earnings are not permanent)

Trading strategy implication: Long in low accrual stocks and short in high accrual stocks to generate above-normal performance.

Trading strategy based on external financing is based on accruals – raise capital means high accruals means go short

Page 52: Behavioral finance.ppt

52

Conclusions

Investors exhibit many behavioral biases If the biases are similar across individuals and arbitrage

forces are limited, then the behavioral biases can cause prices to deviate systematically from economic fundamentals

Recent attempts to test the effects of behavioral biases in stock price data

Aggregate earnings data and stock returns Individual firms’ financial data and stock returns

Stock returns associated with external financing decisions Stock returns due to investors’ alleged inability to process

information in accounting accruals Next set of issues

How large is the mispricing? Can it be exploited? What are the barriers to implementation and what are the implications for asset management?