axT and development: Lessons from recent empirical research · 2017-07-03 · Elasticity of taxable...

42

Transcript of axT and development: Lessons from recent empirical research · 2017-07-03 · Elasticity of taxable...

Page 1: axT and development: Lessons from recent empirical research · 2017-07-03 · Elasticity of taxable income I raditionallyT , the welfare cost estimates have been based on labour supply

Tax and development: Lessons from recentempirical research

Jukka Pirttilä (UNU-WIDER and University of Tampere)([email protected])

University of Pretoria, 3 July 2017

1 / 42

Page 2: axT and development: Lessons from recent empirical research · 2017-07-03 · Elasticity of taxable income I raditionallyT , the welfare cost estimates have been based on labour supply

Outline

Motivation

Conceptual framework

Estimating ETI

South-African evidence

Results

Conclusion

2 / 42

Page 3: axT and development: Lessons from recent empirical research · 2017-07-03 · Elasticity of taxable income I raditionallyT , the welfare cost estimates have been based on labour supply

How to evaluate the welfare costs of taxation?

I Developing countries and emerging markets need su�cientresources to �nance public services and to reduce inequalities

I This must be made in a manner that is not too distortive forthe economy

I We need reliable information about the distortionary costs oftaxation

I This information can then be weighted againts thedistributional goals

I necessary in order to take a stand on the e�ciency-equitytrade o�

3 / 42

Page 4: axT and development: Lessons from recent empirical research · 2017-07-03 · Elasticity of taxable income I raditionallyT , the welfare cost estimates have been based on labour supply

Credible estimation of welfare costs

I In developed countries, the accepted standard of evidence isbased on exogenous variation

I E.g. tax reforms that divide taxpayers into a treatment groupand a control group, enabling a di�erence-in-di�erencesstrategy

I kink points and other discontinuities can also be used

I The impacts are typically evaluated using large taxpayer panelsdirectly from revenue authorities

I For non-OECD countries, very little such credible evidence

I This lecture presents some of this recent work

4 / 42

Page 5: axT and development: Lessons from recent empirical research · 2017-07-03 · Elasticity of taxable income I raditionallyT , the welfare cost estimates have been based on labour supply

Outline

Motivation

Conceptual framework

Estimating ETI

South-African evidence

Results

Conclusion

5 / 42

Page 6: axT and development: Lessons from recent empirical research · 2017-07-03 · Elasticity of taxable income I raditionallyT , the welfare cost estimates have been based on labour supply

Outline

Motivation

Conceptual framework

Estimating ETI

South-African evidence

Results

Conclusion

6 / 42

Page 7: axT and development: Lessons from recent empirical research · 2017-07-03 · Elasticity of taxable income I raditionallyT , the welfare cost estimates have been based on labour supply

Elasticity of taxable income

I Traditionally, the welfare cost estimates have been based onlabour supply elasticities

I However, hours of work is only one of the many margin howtaxes can a�ect the economy

I Other margins includeI the participation decisionI e�ort (which is re�ected in the hourly wage)I avoidance and evasion

I Feldstein (1999) shows how estimating the elasticity of taxableincome is su�cient to evaluate the welfare costs of taxes

7 / 42

Page 8: axT and development: Lessons from recent empirical research · 2017-07-03 · Elasticity of taxable income I raditionallyT , the welfare cost estimates have been based on labour supply

The basic setup

I Government levies linear tax t on reported taxable income

I Agent makes N labour supply choices: l1, .., lNI Each choice has a disutility ψi (li ) and wage w1

I Agents can shelter e of income from taxes by paying cost g(e)

I Taxable income (TI ) is

TI = ∑i

wi li − e

I Consumption is given by

c = (1− t)TI + e

8 / 42

Page 9: axT and development: Lessons from recent empirical research · 2017-07-03 · Elasticity of taxable income I raditionallyT , the welfare cost estimates have been based on labour supply

Taxable income formula

I Quasi-linear utility

u(c ,e, l) = c−g(e)−∑i

ψi (li )

I Social welfare

W (t) =

{(1− t)TI + e−g(e)−∑

i

ψi (li )

}+ tTI

I Di�erentiating and applying envelope conditions for li((1− t)wi = ψ ′i (li )) and e (g ′(e) = t) implies

dW

dt=−TI +TI + t

dTI

dt= t

dTI

dt

I Intuition: marginal social cost of reducing earnings througheach margin is equated at optimum => irrelevant what causeschange in TI

9 / 42

Page 10: axT and development: Lessons from recent empirical research · 2017-07-03 · Elasticity of taxable income I raditionallyT , the welfare cost estimates have been based on labour supply

Taxable income formula: critique

I Simplicity of identication in Feldstein's formula has led to alarge literature estimating elasticity of taxable income

I However, there are caveats to the approach:I Chetty (2009) questions validity of assumption that g ′(e) = t

I Costs of some avoidance/evasion behaviors are transfers toother agents in the economy, not real resource costs

I Ex: cost of evasion is potential �ne imposed by government

I Income shifting between tax bases: if one increases the tax onlabour income, people may claim capital income instead. Partof the lost revenue is recouped from the increased capitalincome tax base

I => In the end, 'real' costs determined by the reaction of totalincome

10 / 42

Page 11: axT and development: Lessons from recent empirical research · 2017-07-03 · Elasticity of taxable income I raditionallyT , the welfare cost estimates have been based on labour supply

An aside: link to optimal taxes

I The taxable income elasticity (e) for high income taxpayerscan be used to obtain the revenue maximizing marginal taxrate in the top bracket (Saez, 2001):

t∗= 1

1+a∗ e

I where a is the Pareto paramater if the right tail of the incomedistribution is Pareto distributed. It is a measure of thethinness of the top tail: the thicker is the tail the smaller is a

I Current top marginal tax rate at the top in S-A around 47 percent [(0.40 + 0.14)/1.14], when the VAT rate is 14%

I Wittenberg (2015): Pareto parameter 1.8, earlier 2 was used

11 / 42

Page 12: axT and development: Lessons from recent empirical research · 2017-07-03 · Elasticity of taxable income I raditionallyT , the welfare cost estimates have been based on labour supply

Implied optimal top marginal tax rates

0.1 0.25 0.5

1.8 0.85 0.69 0.53

2 0.83 0.67 0.50

Table: Optimal top tax rates. Pareto parameter (rows) and ETI(columns)

12 / 42

Page 13: axT and development: Lessons from recent empirical research · 2017-07-03 · Elasticity of taxable income I raditionallyT , the welfare cost estimates have been based on labour supply

Outline

Motivation

Conceptual framework

Estimating ETI

South-African evidence

Results

Conclusion

13 / 42

Page 14: axT and development: Lessons from recent empirical research · 2017-07-03 · Elasticity of taxable income I raditionallyT , the welfare cost estimates have been based on labour supply

Empirical work using administrative data

I Unlike in the case for the evidence for the developed countries,there is extremely little evidence on tax responsiveness

I for the long time, the exception was the work on Pakistan(Best, Brockmeyer, Kleven, Spinnewijn, and Waseem, 2015;Kleven and Waseem, 2013)

I now, studies emerging also using data from other countries(Boonzaaier, Harju, Matikka, and Pirttilä, 2017; Bachas andSoto, 2015)

I A growing body of literature utilize admin data + �eldexperiments

I see Pomeranz (2015) for an example and Mascagni (2014) fora review

I Complementary approaches

14 / 42

Page 15: axT and development: Lessons from recent empirical research · 2017-07-03 · Elasticity of taxable income I raditionallyT , the welfare cost estimates have been based on labour supply

Estimating ETI using bunching

I Below, the approach by Boonzaaier et al. (2017) is presentedin more detail

I They utilize the idea of Saez (2010) (for a survey, see (Kleven,2016))

I kink points in the tax schedules create incentives for taxpayersto locate just below the kinks

I they can do so by lowering their taxable incomeI this creates excess mass below the kink pointI the more excess mass there is, the greater is the elasticity ofthe tax base, and the higher are the distortions created by thesystem

I Devereux, Liu, and Loretz (2014) show how kink points in thecorporate tax schedule can be used to estimate the elasticity ofcorporate tax base, and the elasticity is a su�cient statistic

15 / 42

Page 16: axT and development: Lessons from recent empirical research · 2017-07-03 · Elasticity of taxable income I raditionallyT , the welfare cost estimates have been based on labour supply

Bunching graph 1

16 / 42

Page 17: axT and development: Lessons from recent empirical research · 2017-07-03 · Elasticity of taxable income I raditionallyT , the welfare cost estimates have been based on labour supply

Bunching graph 2

17 / 42

Page 18: axT and development: Lessons from recent empirical research · 2017-07-03 · Elasticity of taxable income I raditionallyT , the welfare cost estimates have been based on labour supply

Outline

Motivation

Conceptual framework

Estimating ETI

South-African evidence

Results

Conclusion

18 / 42

Page 19: axT and development: Lessons from recent empirical research · 2017-07-03 · Elasticity of taxable income I raditionallyT , the welfare cost estimates have been based on labour supply

The study by Boonzaaier et al. (2017)

I This paper o�ers evidence of the impact of a progressivecorporate income tax on SME behavior

I is a graduated, progressive tax rate schedule e�ective inincreasing economic activity?

I We use population-wide administrative data from the SouthAfrican Revenue Service (SARS)

I bunching responses to CIT kinksI utilize reforms in the locations of the CIT kinks

I The paper contributes to the literature byI providing one of the �rst results using administrative data fromAfrica

I adding to the scarce literature on the impacts of taxes on SMEbehavior

I examining the anatomy behind the response: real vs. evasion

19 / 42

Page 20: axT and development: Lessons from recent empirical research · 2017-07-03 · Elasticity of taxable income I raditionallyT , the welfare cost estimates have been based on labour supply

The taxation of SME pro�ts

I If certain conditions are met AND turnover is below 20 millionZAR (1 USD≈13 ZAR)→ Corporate pro�ts are taxed according to a progressiveschedule, the SBC schedule

Taxable income Marginal tax rate

R1 – R59,750 0%R59,751 – R300,000 10%R300,001 and above 28%

I Outside the SBC schedule a �at rate of 28% is used

20 / 42

Page 21: axT and development: Lessons from recent empirical research · 2017-07-03 · Elasticity of taxable income I raditionallyT , the welfare cost estimates have been based on labour supply

Changes in tax rate thresholds in 2010�2013

I The lower threshold increased on an annual basis byapproximately 3,000 ZAR

I from 54,000 to 63,500 ZAR in 2010�2013

I The upper threshold was increased by 17% in 2013I from 300,000 to 350,000 ZARI no annual in�ation adjustment of this threshold in 2010�2013I provides our main source of variation in terms of changes inincentives over time

21 / 42

Page 22: axT and development: Lessons from recent empirical research · 2017-07-03 · Elasticity of taxable income I raditionallyT , the welfare cost estimates have been based on labour supply

Estimation

I As standard in the literature, we estimate a counterfactualdistribution, c , around the kink point using a polynominalfunction. Comparison of the actual distribution then gives anestimate of the excess bunching, b(TI ∗), at the kink point CITkinks

I The elasticity of taxable income is given by

εTI ∗ =dTI

d(1− τp)

1− τp

TI' b(TI ∗)

TI ∗ ∗ c ∗ log(

(1−τP )(1−τP−4τP )

) ,I The elasticity tends to be the greater when

I excess bunching is largeI there are less �rms around the kink pointI one sees a big change in behaviour relative to a small changein tax incentives

22 / 42

Page 23: axT and development: Lessons from recent empirical research · 2017-07-03 · Elasticity of taxable income I raditionallyT , the welfare cost estimates have been based on labour supply

Data

I Data from a pilot project in cooperation with UNU-WIDER,South African Revenue Service (SARS), and National Treasury

I Tax return data for 2010�2013I directly from the e-�ling system of SARSI micro-level data including all �rms (with �rm pseudo-ID's)

I The sample: �rms that are eligible for the progressive incometax (SBC panel)

I The data has been subject to substantial cleaning work andhas now been used by a number of research groups

I SARS views that data prior to 2010 is not su�ciently reliable

23 / 42

Page 24: axT and development: Lessons from recent empirical research · 2017-07-03 · Elasticity of taxable income I raditionallyT , the welfare cost estimates have been based on labour supply

Data

24 / 42

Page 25: axT and development: Lessons from recent empirical research · 2017-07-03 · Elasticity of taxable income I raditionallyT , the welfare cost estimates have been based on labour supply

Outline

Motivation

Conceptual framework

Estimating ETI

South-African evidence

Results

Conclusion

25 / 42

Page 26: axT and development: Lessons from recent empirical research · 2017-07-03 · Elasticity of taxable income I raditionallyT , the welfare cost estimates have been based on labour supply

Baseline results: SBC tax kinks (Upper kink)

020

040

060

080

010

00F

requ

ency

−75 −65 −55 −45 −35 −25 −15 −5 5 15 25 35 45 55 65 75Distance from the kink

Observed Counterfactual

Excess mass: 11.025 (.755), Elasticity: .165 (.011)

Upper kink, 2010−2013

26 / 42

Page 27: axT and development: Lessons from recent empirical research · 2017-07-03 · Elasticity of taxable income I raditionallyT , the welfare cost estimates have been based on labour supply

Baseline results: SBC tax kinks (Lower kink)

010

0020

0030

0040

00F

requ

ency

−50 −40 −30 −20 −10 0 10 20 30 40 50Distance from the kink

Observed Counterfactual

Excess mass: 4.519 (.452), Elasticity: .718 (.072)

Lower kink, 2010−2013

27 / 42

Page 28: axT and development: Lessons from recent empirical research · 2017-07-03 · Elasticity of taxable income I raditionallyT , the welfare cost estimates have been based on labour supply

Baseline bunching results

I Firms respond very strongly to the SBC tax scheduleI Large and distinctive excess bunching at both kink pointsI No signi�cant di�erences between industries etc.

I Local elasticities at SBC kinks are relatively highI Particularly among smaller �rms around the lower kink pointI Nevertheless, a large incentive change at the upper thresholdimplies a rather moderate elasticity

I More scattered response to the lower kinkI behavioural story (?): increased incentives to avoid positive taxpayments? (tax rate 0% →10%)

28 / 42

Page 29: axT and development: Lessons from recent empirical research · 2017-07-03 · Elasticity of taxable income I raditionallyT , the welfare cost estimates have been based on labour supply

Nature of the response & bunching

I Sharp bunching response is an indication of reportingresponses

I Real responses would entail more scattered responses aroundthe kink points

I The response at the upper kink is very sharp → �rst piece ofevidence of avoidance/evasion

I Similarly, large and immediate responses to changes in thelocations of the kinks suggest reporting behavior

I Real responses would require adjustments along multiplemargins (sales, costs, demand side etc.)

I Real response margins likely to be a�ected by various frictions→ more sluggish responses to relocation of kink points

I Our main evidence comes from the 17% increase in the upperCIT kink

I from R300,000 to R350,000 in 2013

29 / 42

Page 30: axT and development: Lessons from recent empirical research · 2017-07-03 · Elasticity of taxable income I raditionallyT , the welfare cost estimates have been based on labour supply

Changes in kink points: results

2013 − Excess bunching: 10.59 (1.328), Elasticity: .136 (.017)

2012 − Excess bunching: 11.428 (1.485), Elasticity: .171 (.022)

Old kink New kink

050

100

150

200

250

Fre

quen

cy

275 300 325 350 375 400 425Corporate income (in bins of R1,000)

Observed 2013 Observed 2012

Upper CIT kink

30 / 42

Page 31: axT and development: Lessons from recent empirical research · 2017-07-03 · Elasticity of taxable income I raditionallyT , the welfare cost estimates have been based on labour supply

Characterizing reporting behavior

I The above evidence suggest that reporting responses explainthe response

I In general, various types of responses could be involved:I avoidance, evasion and real responses

I We turn to the detailed tax return data to look for thesemechanisms

I how reported items respond to the CIT kink point relocation?I how �rm-level factors evolve around the kink?

31 / 42

Page 32: axT and development: Lessons from recent empirical research · 2017-07-03 · Elasticity of taxable income I raditionallyT , the welfare cost estimates have been based on labour supply

Responses of relocating �rms vs. others

Bunchers in 2013 and 2012

42013�2012 4Sales 4Cost of sales 4Expenses 4CTI 4Equity 4Cash

Mean .145 .089 .052 .154 .472 .351

SE .024 .068 .050 .001 .147 .149

CTI>150 & CTI<250 in 2012

42013�2012 4Sales 4Cost of sales 4Expenses 4CTI 4Equity 4Cash

Mean .090 .101 .166 .015 .338 .063

SE .009 .018 .011 .006 .0287 .038

Bunchers in 2013, not bunching in 2012

42013�2012 4Sales 4Cost of sales 4Expenses 4CTI 4Equity 4Cash

Mean .138 .134 .179 .121 .349 .086

SE .024 .036 .031 .012 .067 .090

32 / 42

Page 33: axT and development: Lessons from recent empirical research · 2017-07-03 · Elasticity of taxable income I raditionallyT , the welfare cost estimates have been based on labour supply

Firm-level factors around the upper kink point

33 / 42

Page 34: axT and development: Lessons from recent empirical research · 2017-07-03 · Elasticity of taxable income I raditionallyT , the welfare cost estimates have been based on labour supply

Bulk of evidence towards reporting responses

I Several factors point to the direction that reporting isresponsible for a large bulk of the response

I sharp bunchingI sharp and immediate responses to relocation of the kink pointI the observed sales responses for moving �rms not consistentwithout allowing for signi�cant reporting e�ects

I or that these �rms were unrealistically productive

I suggestive evidence of both sales underreporting and taxplanning activities � showing more pro�ts now when it hasbecome more tax favourabl

34 / 42

Page 35: axT and development: Lessons from recent empirical research · 2017-07-03 · Elasticity of taxable income I raditionallyT , the welfare cost estimates have been based on labour supply

Outline

Motivation

Conceptual framework

Estimating ETI

South-African evidence

Results

Conclusion

35 / 42

Page 36: axT and development: Lessons from recent empirical research · 2017-07-03 · Elasticity of taxable income I raditionallyT , the welfare cost estimates have been based on labour supply

Conclusion

I Conducting good tax policies requires evidence base

I There is not much of it, but it is expanding

I ETI is a useful framework, but there are issues

I Real elasticities typically smaller than reporting behaviourchanges

I How to reduce avoidance:I wide tax baseI extensive third party reportingI tax authority capacity

36 / 42

Page 37: axT and development: Lessons from recent empirical research · 2017-07-03 · Elasticity of taxable income I raditionallyT , the welfare cost estimates have been based on labour supply

References I

Bachas, P., and M. Soto (2015): �Not(ch) your average tax system:corporate taxation under weak enforcement,� Mimeo, Universityof Berkeley.

Best, M. C., A. Brockmeyer, H. J. Kleven, J. Spinnewijn, andM. Waseem (2015): �Production versus Revenue E�ciency withLimited Tax Capacity: Theory and Evidence from Pakistan,�Journal of Political Economy, 123(6), 1311�1355.

Boonzaaier, W., J. Harju, T. Matikka, and J. Pirttilä (2017): �Howdo small �rms respond to tax schedule discontinuities? Evidencefrom South African tax registers,� Discussion Paper VATTWorking Papers 85.

Chetty, R. (2009): �Is the Taxable Income Elasticity Su�cient toCalculate Deadweight Loss? The Implications of Evasion andAvoidance,� American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 1(2),31�52.

37 / 42

Page 38: axT and development: Lessons from recent empirical research · 2017-07-03 · Elasticity of taxable income I raditionallyT , the welfare cost estimates have been based on labour supply

References II

Devereux, M. P., L. Liu, and S. Loretz (2014): �The Elasticity ofCorporate Taxable Income: New Evidence from UK TaxRecords,� American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 6(2),19�53.

Feldstein, M. (1999): �Tax Avoidance and the Deadweight Loss ofthe Income Tax,� The Review of Economics and Statistics,81(4), 674�680.

Kleven, H. (2016): �Bunching,� Annual Review of Economics, 8,435�464.

Kleven, H. J., and M. Waseem (2013): �Using Notches to UncoverOptimization Frictions and Structural Elasticities: Theory andEvidence from Pakistan,� 128(2), 669�723.

Mascagni, G. (2014): �A Review of Tax Experiments: from the Labto the Field,� Evidence report 97, Institute for DevelopmentStudies.

38 / 42

Page 39: axT and development: Lessons from recent empirical research · 2017-07-03 · Elasticity of taxable income I raditionallyT , the welfare cost estimates have been based on labour supply

References III

Pomeranz, D. (2015): �No Taxation without Information:Deterrence and Self-Enforcement in the Value Added Tax,�American Economic Review, 105(8), 2539�69.

Saez, E. (2001): �Using Elasticities to Derive Optimal Income TaxRates,� The Review of Economic Studies, 68(1), 205.

(2010): �Do Taxpayers Bunch at Kink Points?,� American

Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 2(3), 180�212.

Wittenberg, M. (2015): �The top tail of South Africa's earningsdistribution 1994-2011,� Mimeo, University of Cape Town.

39 / 42

Page 40: axT and development: Lessons from recent empirical research · 2017-07-03 · Elasticity of taxable income I raditionallyT , the welfare cost estimates have been based on labour supply

Chetty transfer cost model setup

I Individual chooses e (evasion/avoidance) and l (labour supply)to max u = c−ψ(l) s.t.

c = y +(1− t)(wl − e)+ e− z(e)

I Social welfare is now

W (t) = {y +(1− t)(wl − e)+ e− z(e)−ψ(l)}+ z(e)+ t(wl − e)

I Di�erence: z(e) now appears twice in SWF, with di�erentsigns

40 / 42

Page 41: axT and development: Lessons from recent empirical research · 2017-07-03 · Elasticity of taxable income I raditionallyT , the welfare cost estimates have been based on labour supply

Excess burden with transfer cost

I Let LI = wl be the total (pretax) earned income andTI = wl − e denote taxable income

I The FOC:

dW

dt=−(wl − e)+(wl − e)+

dz

de

de

dt+ t

d(wl − e)

dt

= tdTI

dt+

dz

de

de

dt

= tdLI

dt− t

de

dt+

dz

de

de

dt

I FOC for individual's choice of e: t = dz/de. =>

dW

dt= t

dLI

dt

I Now welfare costs depend on real economic decisions only

I Std ETI would overestimate the welfare costs41 / 42

Page 42: axT and development: Lessons from recent empirical research · 2017-07-03 · Elasticity of taxable income I raditionallyT , the welfare cost estimates have been based on labour supply

Chetty (2009) formula

I With both transfer cost z(e) and resource cost g(e) of evasion:

dW

dt= t

dLI

dt−g ′(e)

de

dt

= t

{µdTI

dt+(1−µ)

dLI

dt

}=− t

1− t{µTI εTI +(1−µ)wlεTI}

I Excess burden depends on weighted average of taxable income(εTI ) and earned income (εLI ) elasticities

I Important to know the composition of income response

I Often one only �nds relatively indirect evidence for µ

42 / 42