Asset Price Bubbles and Minsky Approach to Asia Crisis

download Asset Price Bubbles and Minsky Approach to Asia Crisis

of 26

Transcript of Asset Price Bubbles and Minsky Approach to Asia Crisis

  • 8/3/2019 Asset Price Bubbles and Minsky Approach to Asia Crisis

    1/26

    Asset Bubbles and Minsky Crises in East Asia:

    A Spatialized Minsky Approach

    Gary A. Dymski*

    Associate Professor of EconomicsUniversity of California, Riverside

    Riverside CA 92521-0427 USA

    [email protected]

    April 1999

    ABSTRACT

    Some economists have suggested that the economic crises in East Asia were preceded by

    asset bubbles because of some nations inadequate bank supervision and myopic (or

    even criminal) bank lending behavior. Others have developed an alternative approach

    based on Hyman Minskys financial instability hypothesis: in this view, these nations

    have experienced boom-bust financial cycles, with asset-price booms generating Minsky

    crises and eventually a series of crashes. Minskys policy prescriptions for financial

    cycles big banks and big governmentthen present remedies for these nations

    ills.

    This paper also applies Minskys ideas to the Asian financial crisis, but modifies them to

    to incorporate cross-border financial flows. Ironically, this modification is based on

    earlier work done by Minsky himself in the mid-1960s. This extension of Minskys

    framework shows first that asset bubbles can arise whenever cross-border inflows offinancial claims on capital exceeds the growth rate of real asset production. Since cross-

    border imbalances occur frequently, asset bubbles and/or asset-price deflations are ever-

    present tendencies. Second, shifting cross-border flows can bring about Minsky crises

    even without Minsky cycles. Finally, this paper shows that Minskys big bank and big

    government prescription for recovery is more difficult to apply when cross-border

    constraints matter. Japans ability to apply these remedies in the current Asian crisis is

    complicated in ways that do not arise in the U.S. case highlighted in Minskys work.

    *The research reported here was supported by the Pacific Rim Research Program of the

    University of California and by the Center for Global Partnership. The author has receivedhelpful comments on earlier versions of this manuscript from Jim Crotty, Tokutaro Shibata,

    Fernando Carvalho, Fernando Costa, and Luiz Fernando de Paula, from participants in seminars

    at Seoul National University, Fukyong National University, Ehime University, the University of

    Tokyo, UNICAMP, and the Federal University of Rio de Janeiro, and from all the participants in

    the March 1999 Housing Finance Futures conference held at the University of California,

    Riverside. All remaining errors are the authors responsibility.

  • 8/3/2019 Asset Price Bubbles and Minsky Approach to Asia Crisis

    2/26

    1

    The most significant economic event of the era since World War II is something that has not

    happened: there has not been a deep and long-lasting depression.

    --Hyman Minsky, Can It Happen Again? A Reprise (1982)

    All things I pick up

    Are moving, awash upon

    The beach at low tide

    -- Chiyojo (trans. from the Japanese by Buchanan, 1973, page 69)

    1. Introduction

    In one way, the Asian financial crisis has had a paradoxical effect on the economics

    profession. It has been a boon, giving rise to many new questions and some new answers. For a

    profession which increasingly uses rhetorical puzzles as launching points for theoreticalinquiry, the Asian crisis has been a godsend: why did Southeast Asian equities markets with

    different fundamentals all lose value? Why did the Korean won collapse? Why was Brazil

    dragged in?

    However, the Asian crisis has jarred economists confidence that they understand the

    issues that policy-makers and economic agents now face in the real world. For one thing,

    economists efforts to explain this crisis have demonstrated their models ambiguity as much as

    their relevance.1 Further, this crisis challenges behavioral assumptions that many economists

    regard as self-evident. For example, the interrelated ideas that asset prices respond to

    fundamentals and that financial investors are rational have been profoundly damaged. The World

    Bank and IMF, two institutions whose economists have largely celebrated the centrality offundamentals in economic outcomes, have put out a series of working papers on (expectationally

    arational, fundamentals-defying) contagion effects in Asian currency and asset markets. Finally,

    1For example, Krugman (1998) explains the Asian financial crisis as the result of an asset bubble

    resulting from perverse credit-market outcomes; when these nations domestic banks underwrote

    risky projects, they ignored the possibility of failure, and thus drove asset prices out of sight. The

    culprits in these price spirals, and hence in the crisis, are thus banks, bank regulatory systems,

    and East Asian governments provisions against bank failure. The asset bubbles burst when low

    returns generated bank losses that governments were unable or unwilling to absorb, setting off

    contagion effects ranging from depositor flight to currency crisis.Before the current crisis,

    however, incentive-based models with asymmetric information have been used to explain why

    East Asias banking structures have supported (not undermined) the East Asian miracle. For

    example, Stiglitz and Uy wrote, financial sector interventions in East Asia incorporated

    design features that improved the chances of success and reduced opportunities for abuse;

    interventions that did not work out were dropped unhesitatingly; and policies were adapted to

    reflect changing economic conditions (Stiglitz and Uy, 1996: 249).

  • 8/3/2019 Asset Price Bubbles and Minsky Approach to Asia Crisis

    3/26

    2

    the continually evolving character of this crisis has revealed many economic insights to be valid

    only for one moment: in effect, they are written on wet sand at low tide.

    The persistence of economic effects that werent supposed to happen has generated new

    interest in alternative approaches to financial phenomena; and the ideas of Hyman P. Minsky

    about financial crises, long overlooked by mainstream financial economists, have in this

    reconsideration come to the fore. Akyuz (1998) and Kregel (1998), among others, havedemonstrated the significance of Minskian financial instability in the Asian financial crisis.

    This paper too uses Minskys ideas to explain the role of asset bubbles in creating,

    transmitting, and resolving financial crises in Japan and Korea. At the same time, this paper

    suggests some alterations to Minskys core ideas about the emergence and resolution of asset

    bubbles and boom-bust financial cycles. Specifically, exploring the role of financial instability in

    the Japanese and Korean crises requires that Minskys core framework be spatializedthat is,

    it must take explicit account of spatial economic borders and foreign-exchange constraints.

    Minskys core financial boom-bust model is aspatial--it implicitly assumes that the financial

    cycle plays itself out in a closed, homogeneous economy.2

    Once we have allowed for trade imbalances and factor flows across borders, it is easy to

    see that cross-border imbalances in capital movements can be an independent contributing source

    of financial fragility, aside from the financial fragility that arises due to the economys cyclical

    momentum. Ironically, Minsky himself suggested the building blocks of a spatially-aware

    approach in work predating most of his writing on financial instability per se; in effect this paper

    unites two strands of thought that Minsky left unconnected. We go on to argue that financial

    fragility and instability in an economy depends not just on the business cycle factors emphasized

    by Minsky, but also on the real/financial-sector tensions inherent in flows of capital across its

    borders. Whether asset bubbles and tendencies toward financial crisis emerge depends in part on

    any economys institutional mechanisms for channeling inflows of capital into investment

    outlets. The paper concludes by considering whether Minskys policy prescriptions can beapplied in the case of the spatialized financial and economic crisis of East Asia.

    2. The Minskian approach to financial fragility and asset bubbles

    The twin entry points for any model building on the work of Hyman Minsky are

    Keynesian uncertainty and real time. Keynesian uncertainty refers to the key methodological

    insight in Keynes General Theory (1936): the future is uncertain because events that unfold in

    real time do not obey pre-given probability distributions. For example, there is no way to know

    objectively whether asset prices are rising because the fundamentals are improving, or instead

    because the fundamentals are being evaluated differently. In a world with uncertainty, people

    cannot be fully rational because parametric information is not out there to be had. Real time, inturn, means that agents seeking to accumulate wealth must purchase and hold partially or wholly

    illiquid assets for a series of short periods, during which market conditions may change

    substantially. Because of these two characteristics of the lived environment, humans will

    fluctuate between being willing to make irreversible commitments, and instead seeking liquid

    assets that maximize flexibility and minimize exposure to risk. Uncertainty also has implications

    2 The ideas developed here are indebted to the insights of Gray and Gray (1994).

  • 8/3/2019 Asset Price Bubbles and Minsky Approach to Asia Crisis

    4/26

    3

    for how agents form expectations and make decisions: for one thing, they cannot formulate

    expectations of asset values that are time-invariant; further, they will have some degree of

    disbelief in their own estimates, as well as some doubt that these estimates will guide market

    price formation.

    An immediate implication of this dual entry point is that it becomes impossible to know

    when a given market is subject to a bubble. For even the perceived line separating sound fromunsound investments is inconstant and shifting through time; and there is no objective grounds

    for deciding. As Grant observes, Every loan, even if fully secured, is a kind of speculation. (5,

    1992) When decisions are made under uncertainty, the passage of time always threatens to

    undermine well-laid plans. We make our way through this world under a condition of

    fundamental uncertainty that denies us knowledge about those things we most need to know.

    These dimensions of an uncertain economic environment immediately suggest the

    importance of institutional structures. As Crotty (1993) has emphasized, people construct rules of

    thumb to guide their behavior; when widely adopted, these conventions can create conditional

    stability for periods of time by channeling behaviors in a way that bounds the consequences of

    uncertainty. These conventions provide people with assurance that they are minimizing theirexposure to mistakes and permit them to make longer-term commitments (such as purchases of

    land and fixed assets). Crotty goes on to observe that while conventions will bound uncertainty,

    they do not reduce it to probabilistic risk; indeed, the very conventions that generate conditional

    stability for a time eventually have behavioral consequences that undermine that apparent

    stability and bring us face to face again with the consequences of uncertainty.3

    Minskys financial instability hypothesis. But economic events are not only molded by

    behavioral conventions; they unfold within aggregate structural settings that both give shape to

    economic dynamics and set limits on feasible outcomes. Many theorists have followed Keynes

    and Kalecki in observing that the relation between investment and saving can give rise to

    business cycles. Further, Keynes observation that economic agents will discount liquidity inperiods of economic growth and rising asset values, but run to liquidity when these magnitudes

    turn down, suggests a financial source of cyclical fluctuation. This was exposited definitively by

    Hyman Minsky (1975). He showed that just as expectations vary with the state of the business

    cycle, balance-sheet relationships too evolve systematically during the cycle. Initially, balance

    sheets are robust because assets are conservatively priced and debt commitments modest; but

    during the course of an expansion phase, asset prices rise and debt burdens grow until finally

    liability commitments outpace asset returns and a downturn is induced. An economy becomes

    more financially fragile as an expansion proceeds, with the consequence that a period of financial

    instability is eventually reached: asset values fall, and a debt-deflation cycle may be unleashed.

    In Minskys model, the evolution of balance sheets over the cycle would be accompaniedby a cyclical pattern in the relationship between the stock-market and production-cost prices of

    capital assets, which he terms PKand PIrespectively. Minsky argues that as a boom period

    proceeds, an asset bubble emerges: specifically, the asset bubble arises when the ratio (PK/P

    I)

    exceeds one for an extended period of time. Figure 1 shows a stylized picture of a Minsky crisis,

    3An example of a self-undermining rule of thumb is the notion that real estate in a given market

    area is at once the highest-return and safest asset one can hold.

  • 8/3/2019 Asset Price Bubbles and Minsky Approach to Asia Crisis

    5/26

    4

    emphasizing the key role of asset bubbles in cyclical fluctuations. The rapid pace of output

    growth eventually exhausts industrial capacity and forces firms to take on debt to expand

    production. The combination of euphoric expectations and competitive pressure drives up

    debt/income ratios and asset prices simultaneously; leverage is rewarded. When the collapse

    comes, it comes fast.

    Note that two financial characteristics define the difference between prosperity and crash:the collapse of the (PK/PI) ratio and the collapse of asset prices relative to liabilities. Income

    flows too are low relative to debt obligations. DefiningL as liabilities, the crash period can be

    characterized as one in which PK< PI= L. In the debt-deflation state, the inability to serviceL

    leads to defaults, forcing the sale of assets on markets with few buyers, sinking PKfurther. Note

    that a contraction in real prices (a fall in PI) will only worsen the burden of debt. We denote this

    crash state herein as aMinsky crisis. Minskys writings on financial dynamics suggest that a

    Minsky cycle (as described in Figure 1) precedes a Minsky crisis; implicitly, a Minsky crisis can

    be generated in Minskys work by a prior Minsky cycle.

    Responding to Minsky crises: the big bank and big government. Minsky crises have

    devastating effects on advanced economies with sophisticated and interlinked financial markets.Consequently, recurring outbreaks of these crises lead to several systematic adaptations and

    institutional changes. Minsky (1975, 1986) described these adaptations in his 1970s and 1980s

    writing on financial instability; Kregel (1998) has suggested the colorful terms big bank and

    big government for the two central developments. Big bank means the intervention of a

    central bank as a lender of last resort, providing liquidity to support banks ability to provide

    credit to businesses that would otherwise default on their loans and cease to function. To

    intervene in this way, the central bank must provide as much liquidity as is required to meet

    financially fragile cash-flow needs; and of equal importance, market participants must perceive

    the big bank as being willing to play this role.

    The second adaptation is the rise of big government. Minsky shows howcountercyclical government spending by a public sector that constitutes a significant share of

    aggregate demand can check the tendency toward debt-deflation that emerges in the crisis. If

    liquidity provision by banks and the central bank in the face of a crisis is to stabilize cash flows,

    someone must spend it that is, exchange liquidity for goods; and if business firms have little

    capacity to spend, and households are too scared to spend, then government can spend. This

    blocks the panic that otherwise emerges, and creates a floor on prices that previously would have

    been driven (as in the Great Depression) substantially below their current levels. The importance

    of big government in economic dynamics was so fundamental that Minsky divided the

    performance of the US economy into two periods: a small government era from the end of the

    Civil War to the Depression; and a big government era dating from World War II. It is indeed

    true that government spending as a share of GDP rose from about 5% prior to World War II to20% or more thereafter.

    Pollin and Dymski (1994) show that, as Minsky suggests, many key aggregate variables

    in the US economy demonstrate very different cyclical behavior in the two eras. In particular,

    cyclical downturns in the small government era were typically accompanied by falling prices,

    debt deflation, and high bankruptcy rates among banks and non-financial firms alike. Because of

    the deflationary trend of prices, the real cost of capital rose precipitously in the turndown.

  • 8/3/2019 Asset Price Bubbles and Minsky Approach to Asia Crisis

    6/26

    5

    However, in the big government era, cyclical downturns had different effects. Because of the

    intervention of the big bank and big government, price levels did not fall, nor did debt deflation

    occur. The average real cost of capital changed little in recessionary periods during the 1947-79

    period. Non-financial business failure rates were vastly reduced, and bank failure rates almost nil.

    This depiction of the big-government era makes it seem that the problems associated with

    macroeconomic and financial instability should recede into insignificance in this era. However,Pollin and Dymski went on to argue that the macroeconomic effects of the big-government/big-

    bank era were somewhat ambiguous, and that this eras macroeconomic benefits weakened

    substantially after 1980. For one thing, the reduction of business and bank failure rates was a

    mixed blessing: failures have the effect of cleansing balance sheets and opening the field for new

    capital investments; and weak businesses and banks that dont fail will continue to do business.

    For another thing, the price of avoiding the debt-deflations that killed off so many institutions in

    the small-government era was a persistent upward bias in the level of prices. This persistent

    inflationary pressure had deleterious effects on US competitiveness, and it was among the factors

    undercutting political support for the large-scale countercyclical fiscal policies and for welfare

    state policies.

    Pollin and Dymski also observed that tension began to emerge in the 1980s between the

    Federal Reserves lender-of-last-resort role and its monetary-policy role. When pushed, the Fed

    function as lender of last resort overrode its macroeconomic-policy commitments. In effect, the

    policy steps required to maintain financial stability became increasingly divorced from the policy

    steps required to maintain stable macroeconomic growth. This uncoupling was due in large part

    to the stresses placed on US banks and savings and loans by credit-market crises which could be

    traced to the effects of deregulation and to the globalization of US financial relations. We

    concluded that these changes had the cumulative effect of reducing the effectiveness of the tools

    available to government to respond effectively to episodes of macroeconomic and financial

    instability. The combined big-bank/big-government response to episodes of turbulence was

    becoming instead a big-bank-only response which focused on a narrower set of trigger events.Big-government stabilization became less feasible for several reasons: taxpayer revolts, reduced

    welfare benefits, and shifts in political ideology.

    3. Spatializing Minskys model

    These warning signs about the effectiveness of big-bank/big-government policies in the

    face of macroeconomic and financial instability will be explored further in the discussion of the

    East Asian crisis which follows. We first must suggest some modifications in Minskys boom-

    bust model, to permit it to be better able to encompass events observed recently in Korea, Japan,

    and other countries affected in the current global financial crisis.

    Two modifications are necessary. First, Minskys core model does not include the

    possibly significant difficulties associated with current-account/reserve relationships. Minskys

    mature model took a closed-economy approach because the U.S. was, for him, the paradigm case

    of a large economy with mature financial markets. But in recent experience, financial crises are

    especially likely in immature (Malaysia) or semi-mature (Korea); and current-account/reserve

    relationships are crucial in these open economies. In turn, the currency-crisis model ignores the

    impact of balance sheet and debt-income imbalances on target country asset prices. The second

    blind spot is complementary: because of the imbalances that may arise in cross-border financial

  • 8/3/2019 Asset Price Bubbles and Minsky Approach to Asia Crisis

    7/26

    6

    flows, a Minsky crisis may arise even if not preceded by a Minsky cycle. So the two

    modifications suggested here both imply that there are more paths to Minsky crisis than Minskys

    own characteristic interpretation anticipates; and these depend crucially on the particularities of

    historical time and place that underly financial flows.

    Here we focus first on some structural factors associated with the emergence of asset

    bubbles; then we turn to factors associated with Minsky crises. The key structural feature of assetbubbles is that they are inherently spatial as well as temporal phenomena. Specifically, we want

    to understand economies as bordered spaces. The idea is very general: any contiguous enclosed

    spatial area can be treated analytically as a bordered economy. The term is intentionally plastic: a

    country is a bordered economy, but so is a city within a country; a neighborhood within a city; a

    street within a neighborhood; and even a home along a street. Every bordered economy has a

    current account balance which may be unstable due to the cross-border migration of factors of

    production and wealth. And even when wealth and labor dont flow across one border of an

    economy (such as the national boundary), these factors do flow across intra-national boundaries.

    It is highly unlikely that the incremental resources required to fuel a given regions economic

    growth can all be found within its borders. Interestingly, this idea originated with Minskys own

    (1965) analysis of California high growth rate relative to the rest of the U.S.4

    The spatial segmentation that characterizes the division of income flows and asset and

    liability stocks gives rise to various structural complications for bordered economies, especially

    when flows across spatial borders are unbalanced. In neoclassical trade and finance theory, cross-

    border relationships are very simple--either a nation has an export surplus, and chooses between

    building up foreign exchange reserves or buying foreign assets; or it has an export deficit and

    must allow foreigners to acquire its assets. The country in question is viewed as passively

    adjusting to these flow equilibria. If movements of assets and goods are not impeded, regions

    with high consumption propensities will sell off their assets to support their spending habits; and

    vice versa. The countries in this simple story are just placeholders in a global

    consumption/saving-portfolio balance problem. The assets are out there and the right prices forthem can be found as long as exchange rates and domestic asset prices are free to adjust.

    But there is more to these processes. As Minsky always emphasized, asset accumulation

    requires liability growth. Further, assets and liabilities must balance on the flow and stock

    balance sheets of nations, as well as those of regions within nations. The nominal value of the

    capital assets emitted in a given region or nation may notindeed is unlikely to--correspond

    precisely to these assets production cost. This leads to the central point. There is no reason to

    expect nominal and real assets to correspond over time: hence asset bubbles and/or asset

    collapses are omnipresent in bordered economies. Bubbles thus continually affect economic

    outcomes; their impact is a matter of degree and perception, not kind.

    This alternative approach to bubbles rests both on the idea of bordered economies and on

    the idea that cross-border wealth flows are not real flows, but nominal flows--abstract wealth

    claims chasing real assets. Wealth itself is an inherently abstract concept, disembedded from

    the particular assets in which it is stored at any point in time. Capital mobility involves

    4Minsky pointed out that one of the truisms of economics is that the current account balance

    balances (1965). On this approach to regional growth, also see Thirlwall (1980).

  • 8/3/2019 Asset Price Bubbles and Minsky Approach to Asia Crisis

    8/26

    7

    movement in the geographic ownership pattern of wealth claims, not a shift in the spatial locus of

    real capital itself. This applies whether the capital movement in question consists of a reserve

    shift due to household migration, of foreign direct investment, or of portfolio investment.

    Several factors explain why asset bubbles arise in some bordered economies but not

    others. The first is the pattern of regional economic growth. We consider two scenarios vis--vis

    the growth rates of a bordered economy and of the region surrounding it: the bordered economycan grow faster than the surrounding region; or it can grow at the same pace. The faster-growth

    case here encompasses two cases: first, that the surrounding region is growing, but the bordered

    economy is growing faster; second, that the surrounding region is declining, in which case the

    bordered economy qualifies as a high-growth area even if it is declining less quickly. These two

    cases of uneven economic growth can give rise to asset bubbles in the bordered economy.

    Table 1 sets out the possible relationships between asset bubbles and high-growth

    economies. The factors emphasized in other models--asset bubbles due to asymmetric-

    information problems and to unregulated banking marketsare independent of the uneven-

    growth case, as shown in cell (1,2). Interest in Table 1 centers on the next three possibilities.

    Note first that uneven growth could arise without asset bubbles in the faster-growing area, aslong as its growth rate reflected superior productive capacity. An area with more skilled labor

    and more capital can generate more product and income than less well-endowed neighbors, all

    else equal; Japan in the 1970s is a case in point. Independent of productive capacity, however, an

    asset bubble may form in a bordered region due to its receiving wealth inflows at a higher rate

    than the surrounding region (of course, these inflows could originate within this surrounding

    region). This upward pressure on asset prices (relative to the real cost of producing assets) is

    evident, for example, in the virtually global rural-to-urban migration of the past four decades.

    Intra-national or international immigration, like that from foreign countries and other U.S. states

    into California can also generate asset-price pressure of this type. We can define a boom economy

    as a high-growth economy whose rapid growth is attributable in part or whole to significant,

    sustained inflows of labor and wealth.

    To understand the applicability of this framework to the current financial crisis, it is

    important to see that the capital-inflow scenario can also work in reverse. Suppose, for example,

    that all economies in a given region experience capital flight, including the failure of overseas

    lenders to renew short-term credits. Suppose further than one bordered area within this region has

    less capital flight than the region as a whole. Unless this bordered economy has some other

    advantages in productivity or capacity, its asset prices may be viewed as too highbubble prices--

    in the perverse sense that they have declined less than have other capital-asset prices in the

    region. And even when a bordered economy has avoided declines as large as those afflicting the

    remainder of the region, capital flight again can turn its asset prices into bubble prices. So the

    asset-bubble process works two ways, on the way up and on the way down.

    As Table 2 illustrates, the cross-border wealth flows of interest here are typically both

    intra-national and inter-national. The vertical dimension of Table 2 shows that wealth (and/or

    population) can move into a boom region from a hinterland or rustbelt region within a

    nation. This is equivalent, as Minsky (1965) points out, to a movement of funds across national

    borders under a strict gold standard. Every region is, of course, part of a nation that itself has a

    capital-account balance. If exports and imports balance, no wealth moves; and if exports are

  • 8/3/2019 Asset Price Bubbles and Minsky Approach to Asia Crisis

    9/26

    8

    greater than imports, then either foreign exchange will build up or foreign assets will be

    purchased. In the extreme cases constituted by 1980s California and 1980s and 1990s Seoul,

    wealth enters the boom economy across both intra-national and inter-national borders. At the

    other extreme is a region systematically losing wealth to more rapidly-growing regions within a

    nation that is a net buyer of overseas assetsthe case of rural Japan. Even when an economy has

    negative foreign savings, intra-national wealth shifts can create boom and hinterland economies

    within the nationthe case of Tokyo. The other ambiguous case combines a national tradedeficit with a regional capital (and possibly population) outflow--the case of the U.S. Midwestern

    rustbelt in the 1980s.

    There are important feedbacks between the pace of capital in- and outflows and the

    relative rate of growth of any economic region. Indeed, Keynes notion of a currency union can

    be understood here as precisely an effort to resolve imbalances by forcing adjustments on the part

    of countries with trade surpluses (capital outflows). Apart from wealth flows and economic

    growth, other spatial factors can help generate or block asset bubbles. Two such factors are

    singled out in Table 3. Table 3 focuses attention on factors affecting the rate of transformation of

    cross-border wealth flows into real capital assets. The cases of foreign direct investment and

    portfolio investment are differentiated. With foreign direct investment, financial inflows leaddirectly to the purchase or construction of real assets. Examples are phenomena as overseas

    firms construction of new factories and Midwestern families purchases of Los Angeles homes.

    Portfolio investment is more problematic because the claim is only on financial assets per se.

    One key factor identified here is the strength of the bordered economys intermediation capacity:

    the lending capacity of its banks, the strength of borrower-lender relationships, and so on. A

    second key is pertinent to international capital flows: the presence or absence of controls or

    conditions for capital inflows and outflows. Inward capital controls and a strong intermediation

    sector can be used to improve the financial-real capital compression rate. Inflows, even when

    they take the form of portfolio investments, can be longer-term in nature, generating increases in

    the real-asset base and multiplier benefits for other companies. Conversely, with weak banks and

    no controls over capital movements, the amount of financial-real compression is likely to besmall, all else equal.

    Our discussion has emphasized capital flows across borders; but movements of people

    across borders adds another dimension to boom-economy dynamics. While the interrelations

    between wealth and population movements deserve a lengthy discussion, here we make two

    points. First, a boom (capital-absorbing) economy like California grows seemingly without effort

    most of the time because it enjoys a steady stream of migrants who bring both their labor power

    and their wealth along with them. So Californias productive capacity expands even as more

    nominal wealth pours in. Second, a boom economy that enjoys inward migration and hence

    labor-absorption is more capable of sustained growth than a boom economy with a stationary

    population. Both factors of production are expanding in the former case, but only capital--oractually, wealth claims on capital--in the latter case. A boom economy without labor in-migration

    must continually shift to a higher capital/labor ratio to avoid asset-bubbles or unused resources.

    This of course is the case of Japan in the 1960s, as it shifts its textile manufactures to Korea; it is

    the case of Japan in the 1970s, as it automates its factories; it is the case of Japan in the 1980s, as

    it builds up productive capacity and office space too much, and suffers the collapse of a bubble.

  • 8/3/2019 Asset Price Bubbles and Minsky Approach to Asia Crisis

    10/26

    9

    Spatializing Minskian financial fragility. In his mature work on financial instability,

    Minsky argued that assets may often be overvalued in the late stages of a sustained period of

    cyclical expansion. Minsky asserts that the more powerful the boom, the greater the potential for

    an asset bubble; and the more rapid the growth of a bubble, the more certain are participants that

    the sky will not fall, the more likely a crash. So success breeds success, and this breeds fragility

    and eventually the reversal of the growth-generating conditions. At the core of this financial

    instability hypothesis is irreversibility. Agents in an overheated economy are carrying forwardasset positions acquired in the past, which tie them to balance sheet commitments in the present

    period. They must meet commitments in real time on those asset positions--and these units

    viability depends on meeting these commitments in a timely manner. The downturn is driven by

    both the asset and the liability side.

    The spatial conception developed here adds to Minskys notions about financial fragility

    in two ways. First, it suggests a new source of financially-fragile asset bubbles, independent of

    Minskys cyclical conception. Combining uncertainty with a structural approach to bordered

    economies, recognizing that most economies have wealth and/or labor inflows or outflows, and

    acknowledging that asset-augmentation capacity varies widely, leads to the conclusion that asset

    bubbles arise everywhere. So boom economies are commonplace, not rare; and boom economiesare very likely to become bubble economies; and boom economies are therefore likely to be

    financially fragile. Minsky himself recognized this in a 1965 volume predating his 1975 volume

    on Keynes and the financial instability hypothesis. Minsky wrote:

    Californias growth .. requires that capital be imported. The markedly greater growth rate

    of California proportional to the rest of the country has swamped, and will continue to

    swamp, the export surplus that California would enjoy if the two grew at the same rate.

    The reserve base of the states banks would tend to be dissipated unless it was

    supplemented by reserves acquired by way of capital imports. To import capital,

    California must either generate liabilities of the kind accepted throughout the country, or

    the migrants must carry with them sufficient capital to maintain the reserve base of theregions banks. (Minsky, 1965: 99)

    Because of uncertainty, the notion of an excessively high or low state of expectations

    cannot be well-defined, for there is no stable set of fundamentals to serve as a reference point.

    And even if one were to point to a set of firm characteristics as fundamentals, we have argued

    that border balances also matter. Indeed, there can be an asset bubble due to cross-border

    pressures even in the absence of expectational error--that is, as a purely structural supply and

    demand phenomenon. So real/nominal imbalances occur all the time; they become quantitatively

    important when enough wealth seeks out assets in a particular place with inflexible labor supplies

    that this places labor/capital wealth/asset relationships are disrupted. Then Minskys point about

    the liability side comes into play--the liability structures that geniuses of leverage exploited in thehigh-growth days become nooses for aggressive-growth firms when low growth hits.

    The second amendment to Minskys financial instability framework involves the

    recognition that border constraints create broader possibilities for asset-price reversals and

    Minsky crisis. Table 4 summarizes the relationships developed here. The middle row of Table 4

    presents the view of the Minsky cycle and crisis emphasized by Minsky himself. There are,

    however, two more rows. The top row illustrates the case of an economy that is in surplus vis--

  • 8/3/2019 Asset Price Bubbles and Minsky Approach to Asia Crisis

    11/26

    10

    vis the rest of the world.5 Such an economy is unlikely to have an asset bubble unless its asset

    prices are pulled up by an overseas asset bubble. This could occur if this economys wealth-

    owners are consistently buying financial and other assets in overseas markets; if prices there are

    high, domestic securities prices may rise to attract wealth-owners savings. The boom economy

    case occupies the bottom row. As noted, a boom economy can encourage the development of a

    domestic asset bubble independent of the Minsky cycle. This bubble can then be punctured,

    setting off a Minsky crisis, if wealth inflows slow gradually or are suddenly reversed in a capital-flight episode.

    Implications for big-government, big-bank policies. Spatializing the Minsky

    framework emphasizes complications that arise because of open-economy relations, and

    unexplored by Minsky. He liked to say that the sky did not fall after different episodes of

    financial disorder on Wall Street, such as the 1987 Crash. Preventing the sky from falling was a

    Federal Reserve playing a lender-of-last-resort role with the worlds reserve currency, the dollar.

    Such interventions promised to stabilize the unstable economy, in Minskys phrase, at the cost of

    occasional inflationary pressure.

    Section 2 has already discussed how Minskys suggested interventions for counteringfinancial disorder became less effective in the 1980s, with big government receding in

    importance and big bank interventions alone available to block financial disorders. Some

    additional problematic side-effects of big-bank/big-government interventions must be

    considered due to the special features of bordered economies. In particular, interventions by the

    Federal Reserve as lender-of-last-resort have an effect on exchange-market equilibria. Increasing

    liquidity without limit also increases the relative supply of dollars. What happens depends on

    whether a fixed or a flexible exchange-rate regime exists. If the former, then more dollars will

    end up offshore in foreign nations reserve holdings, and the trade balance will worsen. This

    creates the possibility of devaluation and makes foreign governments more reluctant to hold the

    dollars. If the latter, then the dollar will fall in value. This will, in turn, improve the US trade

    balance. Insofar as lender-of-last-resort interventions began in the fixed-exchange rate, theseinterventions would have been among the factors gradually undermining the Bretton Woods

    system.

    A second significant change in Minskys suggested interventions also arises because of

    the existence of multiple national currencies. This second change follows not from currency

    supply-demand balances, but from the fact that some currencies are more acceptable than others

    as international monies. The ability of any central bank to play a lender-of-last-resort role is

    circumcribed if that central bank provides liquidity that wealth-holders are not content to hold. A

    central bank in this categoryfor example, the Bank of Brazilcan issue its currency (reals)

    only insofar as it is willing to convert those reals freely into dollars (or whatever other currency

    may be demanded by those in a position to sell reals).

    This process works both ways. A government which issues a currency that is in demand

    by wealth-holders has a special privilege, essentially the ultimate seignorage right. This is the

    5 Because of intra-national capital flows, an economy as a whole can occupy one row, while a

    region within it occupies another. Japan, for example, chronically sits in the top row, while

    Tokyo falls into the bottom row.

  • 8/3/2019 Asset Price Bubbles and Minsky Approach to Asia Crisis

    12/26

    11

    case with the US in the current period. We have noted that big government spending has

    shrunk as a response to financial disorder. This implies that inflating away debt is no longer (or

    is less frequently) a feasible response to a Minsky crisis (a build-up of debt relative to asset

    values). This can mean that a debt overhang will simply persist. Fortunately for the US, the

    special circumstance of its dollar (and the ability of the US government to credibly underwrite

    asset-market risks) makes it easy to bundle and sell dollar-denominated debt to wealth-holders.

    Could the savings-and-loan crisis have been resolved so speedily without this special situation?

    A final set of constraints makes it more difficult to contain financial instability in the

    open-economy setting set out in Table 4. The presence of overseas asset owners who can engage

    in flightwhether a crawl or a sprint--away from local financial assets (and thus generate

    Minsky crises) reduces local authorities room for maneuver. This flight, if large enough, can

    bring on a Minsky crisis and trigger a debt-deflation regardless of what domestic asset owners

    do, and regardless of the state of the local economic cycle. And because the local central bank

    lacks the ability to act as lender-of-last-resort by issuing dollars, the complications thicken.

    Indeed, the collapse of asset prices as foreign investors retreat will have a double effect since it

    will also destabilize currency values.

    The next two sections focus on the emergence of asset bubbles in Japan and Korea in the

    late 1980s, and the relationship of these bubbles to these nations subsequent crises in the 1990s.

    To what extent are Minsky cycles and Minsky crises among the root causes of these crises?

    Section 6 will discuss the thorny question of what policy steps might be taken to ease these

    financial and macroeconomic crises.

    4. Boom and bubble and the crisis in Japanese growth

    The post-1984 Japanese asset bubble involved both stock-market and land prices. Figure

    2 shows annual change in land prices in Japan in the Tokyo metropolis. This figure demonstrates

    the rapid emergence of a bubble in the late 1980s. It also shows that Tokyo land prices have risenfaster in upswings and declined faster in downswings. In turn, the Nikkei and Tokyo stock-price

    averages moved up even more sharply than did Tokyo land prices in the late 1980s, spiked in

    1989, moved rapidly downward until 1992, and recovered some value in subsequent years.6

    One interesting feature of Japans experience is that the bubble in its market for land

    persisted. One reason for this may be Japans historic restrictions on equity-market participation.

    Consumers savings have had relatively few places to go, so real-estate prices might be expected

    to move with other consumer savings outlets. The inflation-adjusted increase in housing prices

    has been virtually identical, on average, to the return on time deposits and the cost of housing

    loans from 1971 to the present. Housing prices have, however, been extremely variable; this

    suggests, in effect, that Japanese households able to afford homes have to weigh safe, stabletime-deposit returns against a risky, time-varying return on a home. With this observation in

    mind, note the prediction of Table 2 vis--vis Japan: due in part to capital-flow pressures, a land-

    price bubble was likely, and that its most likely locus is in housing prices in Tokyo. Behind the

    equity-price bubble, in turn, lie two other structural factors: the Plaza Accord, which turned many

    6To understand the intensity of trends in Tokyo, note that while the new housing price/annual

    income ratio was 4.4 in Japan in 1989, in Tokyo that year it was 7.4 (Kanemoto 1997: 615).

  • 8/3/2019 Asset Price Bubbles and Minsky Approach to Asia Crisis

    13/26

    12

    Japanese intermediaries investment behavior inward; and the Japanese banking practice of

    lending primarily on collateral value.

    What is the consequence of an asset bubble that hangs on without crashing? The people

    who live in Japan must bear it, a burden that comes at considerable cost. Figure 3 investigates

    two aspects of this cost. It first depicts the estimated percentage of housing price financed, on

    average. A trend line fit to these data points shows that this percentage has been hovered around58% from 1971 to 1996. This figure also depicts the average ratio of housing price to the average

    income of home buyers. There is a clear upward trend here; the housing-price/income ratio drifts

    upward from just over 2.0 in the early 1970s to just under 3.5 in the mid-1990s. There is

    evidence here of the growing budgetary stress on households trying to buy homes. Figure 4

    further supports this conclusion with data on the ratio of savings and of liabilities to income,

    1960 to 1996. This figure shows savings-to-income and liabilities-to-income ratios for non-

    worker households and for worker households with liabilities. For non-worker households, the

    savings-to-income ratio is substantially higher than the liability-to-income ratio, and the

    savings/liability gap grows over time. But for worker households, the liability-to-income ratio is

    at least as high as the savings-to-income ratio--and it may be much higher. In other words,

    liability burdens are increasingly heavy on households who own homes, far outpacing savings. Itseems that most younger Japanese households either face futures without secure housing, or

    futures in which provisions for housing create considerable financial stress. Calculations not

    shown here suggest lower-income Japanese households are especially exposed to financial

    fragility of this sort.

    In sum, the striking fact about the Japanese asset bubble of the 1980s is its continuing

    grip on Japans economy. Resolving this widespread Minsky crisis requires measures either to

    stabilize and increase asset values and/or to reduce the effective weight of debt loads. Neither

    step has been taken. In California, a combination of population/wealth in-migration and

    industrial innovation have permitted asset-value recovery and renewed income growth. Such

    crisis-resolution mechanisms have not been deployed in Japan, for several reasons. Rural-urbanmigration is largely spent. Japans population is graying, and any in-migration in recent years has

    largely involved temporary service-sector workers. This leaves measures to increase spending.

    One possibility is industrial renewal; but with Japans industrial groups ossified, the stimulus for

    such a renewal would have to come from start-up and independent firms. Such firms have been

    among the most affected by the bubble: in many cases their collateral assets have declined in

    value and compromised their creditworthiness; and where such firms have remained viable the

    banks on which they depend for credit are unable to lend due to loan losses and shrunken capital

    value.7 With financially fragile banks unable to support industrial innovation, recent Japanese

    government reform plans have focused on two elements: first, using large-bank mergers

    combined with securitization of bad-loan portfolios to recapitalize banks and renew their lending

    capacity; second, using a fiscal stimulus to lift incomes and trigger a Keynesian multiplierprocess.

    Thus far, a two-pronged economic recovery package of this sort has not proven politically

    viable. The fiscal-policy initiatives proposed have involved modest stimuli, and temporary

    7Tier-one capital in Japanese banks consists in part of equity holdings. A rise in the Nikkei thus

    increases bank capital and loan-making capacity, and vice versa for a fall in the Nikkei.

  • 8/3/2019 Asset Price Bubbles and Minsky Approach to Asia Crisis

    14/26

    13

    measures. This has left the Japanese public without confidence in these stimulus packages

    efficacy and caused them to become still more conservative in their spending habits, putting

    more downward pressure on demand and pushing asset prices toward deflation rather than the

    required reflation. Meanwhile, government efforts to rescue banks by permitting mergers and/or

    bad-loan sales has met political resistance; policies permitting big businesses to work out their

    problems are regarded with skepticism by Japanese voters (whose post-bubble plight is

    illustrated in Figure 4). The household sector itself has its hands tied. While housing prices havedeclined, so have home-buyers incomes. Financial fragility has increased steadily for Japanese

    households, even as job security has lessened and unemployment increased. In the past four

    years, the yen has steadily fallen against the dollar as the crisis has lingered. It is as if the prior

    value of the yen itself and the previous glowing assessments of the Japanese model were

    themselves a bubble that has now burst. In sum, the Japanese economy is in the midst of

    intertwined general economic and Minsky crises, whose end is not in sight.

    5. Boom and bubble and the Korean crisis

    If the Japanese financial crisis has been a long, grinding crisis playing out over a period of

    years, the Korean financial crisis appeared like a tsunami that broke over the heads of the Koreanpeople in late 1997. This crisis had many of the hallmarks of a classic currency crisis. On the

    surface, it would seem that foreign investors realized that currency values were unsustainable

    given the Korean economys persistent trade deficit and declining reserves; their withdrawal

    triggered a precipitous decline in the value of the won from its former bubble level.

    Such an assessment of Koreas financial crisis should be resisted, however, for several

    reasons. For one thing, the pace of overseas long-term investments in Korea slowed in the past

    several years, as Figure 5 shows; but at the same time the volume of short-term investments in

    Korea exploded. The currency-crisis model doesnt handle this case. For another, Korea has been

    a classic boom economy; as in Japan, there has been a flow of population and wealth into Seoul

    from other areas in Korea. And as in the other two bubble economies considered here, an assetbubble in both equity prices and land prices emerged--but not at the end of the 1990s. Figure 6

    presents the basic data for Korean land and equity-market prices in the period 1982-98, using the

    same scale as for Figure 2. The Korean equity market experienced a bubble which peaked in

    1989 after gaining 250% in four yearseven larger than the Japanese asset bubble. After losing

    about half its value by 1992, the Korean equity market rose again to another peak in 1994. Since

    then, this market has lost value in four consecutive years; the 1998 average real value of Korean

    equities (using the KOSPI) has below the level of 1982. In sum, there was hardly anything

    resembling a bubble that needed bursting in the period preceding Fall 1997.

    While the events of recent months demand our attention, Koreas entire experience from

    the 1989 bubble on deserves analysis. For whereas Japans economy experienced a late-1980schill from which it never recovered, Koreas did not. One key is that Koreas bubble was less

    severe. While its equity markets hit a higher peak, these markets were less developed than

    Japans; so the effects of this price collapse were less widespread; further, land prices

    experienced a smaller bubble, which peaked two years after 1989. Koreas economy was

    certainly as susceptible to bubble and fragility problems. In the framework developed here, and

    given Koreas generally negative trade balance in the recent past, Korea clearly should be

    considered as a boom economy, especially Seoul and its environs. We have emphasized that the

  • 8/3/2019 Asset Price Bubbles and Minsky Approach to Asia Crisis

    15/26

    14

    special challenge for boom economies is to channel capital (and labor) inflows so that they do

    not bid up the prices on existing capital assets and generate rent-seeking opportunities. Whereas

    California historically relied on its powerful commercial banks to accomplish this conversion of

    financial claims into real capital, Korea became renowned for its public and corporate sectors

    success in building a world-class industrial economy. In Table-1 terms, Korea had an efficient set

    of institutions for converting intra- and international wealth inflows into real asset accumulation.

    Part of Koreas fascination for outsiders was its ability to accomplish this nominal/realconversion and accomplish rapid or late industrialization (Amsden, 1989) with minimal use of

    arms-length market relationsto govern the market, in Wades (1990) apt phrase.

    The land bubble of the early 1990s was one aspect of a profound challenge for Korea

    the shortage of affordable housing, health services, and other amenities for Korean families,

    especially the many lower- and middle-income families in the burgeoning urban areas. The very

    success of Koreas growth strategy, which had avoided extremes of wealth and poverty, became a

    threat to the widespread provision of adequate and affordable housing and other services, as

    Yoon (1994) and Kim (1997) describe in detail. Pushed in part by an energetic popular

    movement, Koreas government pursued an aggressive housing policy; a massive construction

    effort was begun, together with progressive taxes on the sale of existing homes which socializedsome of the gains from housing-price appreciation. Real government expenditures on housing

    and community development and on social welfare increased after the mid-1980s (admittedly no

    faster than did expenditures on economic services and defense). This effort to build homes and

    encourage ownership effectively countered the land (and housing) price bubble by putting new

    real assets in place. Thousands of new housing units have been put in place; thousands more are

    under construction.

    The economic situation of Korea was inexorably altered in the mid-1990s as it

    deregulated financial markets and took other steps to gain admission into the OECD.8

    A new set

    of non-bank intermediaries (the merchant banks) arose. In part these intermediaries speculated on

    the arbitrage opportunities arising from regional interest-rate mismatches; in part theseintermediaries channeled off-shore funds to chaebols seeking external finance to fuel their

    expansion plans. In any event, the Korean public sector lost control of the growth machine, and

    Korean dynamics flipped from boom-without-bubble to bubble economy. The funds flowing

    into Korea were almost entirely short-term (Figure 5). Using short-term off-shore funds to

    support currency speculation and chaebol investment, since these funds required continual roll-

    over, invited either a currency collapse, an attack on Korean industry, orin the event--both.

    Since late 1997, the withdrawal of foreign investment and the collapse of asset and

    currency values (Figure 6) has created unsustainable debt burdens for many businesses and

    households. Bankruptcies are occurring at historically unprecedented levels, spurred by banks

    need to reduce lending so as to build up capital-asset ratios. Firmly under the thumb of the IMF,the Korean economy is now caught in an excruciating squeeze. Real money-supply growth has

    turned sharply negative after 1996; real domestic credit has declined sharply as of 1997. Price

    inflation has rocketed upward as the devaluation of the won has taken hold ; the real rate of GDP

    growth has fallen below zero in 1998; and the debt/GDP ratio has trended steadily upward

    8A full accounting of Koreas liberalization and its consequences is beyond our scope here; see

    Chang, Park, and Yoo (1998), Wade and Veneroso (1998), and Crotty and Dymski (1998).

  • 8/3/2019 Asset Price Bubbles and Minsky Approach to Asia Crisis

    16/26

    15

    (except for a respite in 1998 attributable to the high bankruptcy rate). After Korea avoided

    Minskian fragility for years through careful economic management, a Minsky crisis has now

    arrived with a vengeance; and it is strangling businesses and households caught in Koreas

    arrested economic development. The principal strategies being pursued in the face of this

    collapse are increased ease of entry for overseas investors and, as in Japan, large bank mergers.

    6. Conclusion and policy implications

    Two views of Asias crisis have predominated until now. In the IMFs view, the Korean

    crisis can be traced to the Korean governments excessive intervention in credit flows in the

    Korean financial sector. As Koreas financial markets became more open, some of Koreas

    privileged inside players made excessively risky off-shore investments; when these went bad,

    money managers and investors outside of Korea reacted to Koreas unsound financial

    architecture by (rationally) withdrawing their funds. Once Koreas financial practices eliminated

    advantages for domestic players and ease cross-border commitments, credit and capital will flow

    back to Korea from abroad. Japans financial problems, too, can be traced to its historic antipathy

    to overseas capital and its non-market criteria for allocating financial resources. This view rests

    on the premise that investment capital is the globally scarce resource, whose presence or absencedetermines national welfare; then any nations micro and macro policies are wrong whenever

    they either inhibit capital mobility or the prerogatives of offshore bankers and investors. A

    contrary view has emerged based on the twin ideas of incentive incompatibility and asymmetric

    information in credit markets. The idea here is that asset bubbles and financial crises result from

    behavioral pitfalls to which human economic systems are chronically prone. Asset bubbles and

    financial crises then comprise a pattern repeated throughout history, mistakes made and made

    again.

    This paper has suggested a new contributing factor in the Asian crisis: asset bubbles can

    result from imbalances between inflows of financial capital and the growth rate of real capital

    assets. Far from being an unusual episode in economic dynamics, imbalances of this sort are achronic tendency in boom economiesthat is, in nations or regions that characteristically import

    capital and/or people from elsewhere. In a boom economy, what stands between stable asset

    prices and an asset-price collapse is an intermediation sector and/or a capital-controls policy

    dedicated to channeling inflows into appropriate real-asset accumulation. When these institutions

    are weakened, an asset price bubble and collapse become more likely. Indeed, we show that

    Minsky crises can be triggered by cross-border shifts of capital, not just by Minsky cycles. The

    interpretation of asset bubbles developed here spatializes Minskys notion of financial fragility

    that is, it shows the special balance-sheet tensions that emerge when financial positions extend

    across economic borders. Interestingly, this extension of Minskys well-known financial-

    instability model makes use of Minskys own earlier, neglected insights into the importance of

    cross-border relations in economic growth.

    This revised Minskian perspective throws new light on the recent experience of Japan and

    Korea, boom economies especially their recent asset bubble problems. We find that there is no

    one asset-bubble story that is told and retold over the millenia, no one lesson that can immunize

    policy-makers from the pitfalls of asset bubbles. Quite the opposite point is made here: asset

    bubbles are a chronic tendency of boom economies, and boom economies are recurring structural

    phenomena. One might argue that bubbles and busts are more likely given behavioral shifts

  • 8/3/2019 Asset Price Bubbles and Minsky Approach to Asia Crisis

    17/26

    16

    within the banking sector. In particular, an increasing number of firms within this sector are

    committed to making income by position-taking on asset projects initiated by others rather than

    by investing in extensive or intensive development. The no-bubble condition becomes less and

    less feasible the more wealth inflows are used to acquire existing assets on the premise that their

    monopoly rents will increase. As Minsky used to put it, firms and wealth-owners increasingly

    take position to make position; but expectations that asset prices will either continue to rise

    (the Japanese bubble of the late 1980s), or at least hold their value while cash-flow margins areexploited (the Korean situation of the late 1990s), invariably run afoul of structural constraints

    implicit in the Minsky cycle and/or in cross-border real-financial relations.

    Several policy implications follow from the model developed here. First, a nation

    characterized by large and sustained inflows of foreign exchange has a higher degree of financial

    fragility than a nation which does not, independent of the character of those nations internal

    balance-sheet relations. It is only prudent economic policy to insure that such inflows do not

    create asset bubbles by seeking out scarce real assets without being put to work in augmenting

    real-asset capacity. That is, a policy of inward capital-flow regulations is a prudent means of

    avoiding asset-price booms and collapses.

    Second, in a boom economy, a key mechanism for avoiding asset bubbles (and

    subsequent collapses) is the maintenance of a banking sector capable of directing and

    coordinating financial flows, instead of only reacting to flows. Loss of capacity of this sort

    suggests the importance of reestablishing it; and institutions that depend on position-taking

    should be reconsidered carefully in terms of their ability to affect resource flows within the

    overall structure of economic activity.

    Resolving the Asian crisis: Japans dilemma. The broader question addressed here is

    whether the Asian crisis can be ameliorated or even blocked through the application of the big-

    bank/big-government policies formulated by Minsky for the case of financial fragility. We have

    already suggested that these policies have grown weaker even for the US since the deregulationera took hold in the 1980s. There are reasons to believe that these policies are even more

    problematic for the Asian crisis per se. Japan is the obvious candidate for reviving East Asias

    growth through the application of such policies. However, several problems impede Japans

    application of these policies, even if she were willing to try them.

    The use of big bank policies involves several problems. First is that the Japanese must

    be willing to support the use of the yen as a reserve currency. This in turn means losing some

    control over the placement of yen-denominated assets, over the locus of yen holding, and over

    the terms and conditions of yen-denominated assets. All these steps will be controversial in

    Japan. Further, applying big-bank policies to the Asian crisis involves a multiple-currency

    problem. The asset bubbles in Asia grew up in a variety of countries; so intervention to stop theworst effects of debt deflation involves not one currency, but a chain of currencies. The problem

    of supporting any one currency (say, the baht or the ringgit) with yen is that this implicitly

    represents support for the government issuing this currency. This raises a moral-hazard issue that

    is lacking for a central bank that takes action to defend against financial meltdowns within one

    countrys borders.

  • 8/3/2019 Asset Price Bubbles and Minsky Approach to Asia Crisis

    18/26

    17

    Another problem is that the problem of debt overhang in Japan must be resolved before it

    is free to act. This in turn means either floating the debt away or inflating it away. Either course

    of action runs counter to deeply-seated attitudes in Japan. Floating it away requires opening up

    Japans financial markets to outside participation; so much bad debt has been built up in the

    Japanese bubble that offshore bond-holders participation will be required to offload significant

    amounts of this debt. This will require bundling, securitizing, and underwriting these debt claims.

    Experience with securitization in other nations has shown that this is readily done by experiencedinvestment bankers ifappropriate guarantees are extended (and if prospective holders are

    identified for whatever toxic waste remains after various cash tranches are stripped off). Of

    course, the provision of such guarantees requires public subsidies; and this has been a political

    sticking point. Once the debt is floated away to offshore holders, renewing economic growth in

    Japan requires revitalizing aggregate demand.

    This brings us to the other choice, inflating away the debt. Inflating away the debt

    requires identifying a sector willing and able to increase aggregate expenditure. The government

    sector has engaged in some increased expenditure, much of it focused on large-scale public

    works projects; this spending has been criticized as ineffective. Government spending would be

    more effectively used to address the problems of housing affordability and child-care availabilitywhich now bedevil Japanese households. A shift of fiscal policy toward such objectives would,

    however, run counter to long-standing social conventions concerning gender roles and the limits

    of state involvement. That the current arrangements are not working is evident in the ongoing

    marriage strike by women of child-bearing age, which has resulted in a plummeting Japanese

    birth rate (and in predictions of a declining Japanese population). What is required now is a way

    out of the years-long political stalemate which has straitjacketed Japan, long after the end of the

    era of income doubling has made a welfare-state system a social necessity.

    If government will not spend, households and corporations are the other sectors capable

    of increased aggregate demand. Household spending, however, has slowed dramatically in the

    current Japanese recession, especially on consumer durables. The increased insecurity associatedwith the ending of life-time employment arrangements hardly puts people in the spending mood.

    And corporate investment expenditure on Japanese goods and services will go only so far.

    If a sector willing to carry Japanese aggregate-demand expansion on its back is identified,

    further problems remain. A significant boost in aggregate demand will weaken Japans export

    balance. Ministry of Finance (MOF) officials characteristically view a trade surplus as a means of

    supporting a fiscal deficit: the idea is that the trade surplus earns the capacity for government

    deficit spending. A significant shift in thinking on the part of the MOF is thus required as a

    component of a new dedication to aggregate-demand expansion.

    In sum, any course of action that permits Japan to ease out of its Minsky crisis, and henceto play a more active role in ameliorating Minsky crises throughout Asia, will require significant

    shifts on the part of important players in Japans economic and political establishment. The

    capacity of Japan to pursue Minskys policies, and the effectiveness of these policies in the

    current global neo-liberal climate, is very much in question. Unless and until means of

    unwinding the Minsky crises in East Asia are found, the Asian financial crisis will remain a stone

    around the neck of world economic growth.

    Bibliography

  • 8/3/2019 Asset Price Bubbles and Minsky Approach to Asia Crisis

    19/26

    18

    Akyuz, Yilmaz. 1998. The East Asian financial crisis: Back to the future? Geneva: United

    Nations Commission on Trade and Development.

    Amsden, Alice. 1989. Asias Next Giant. Oxford and New York: Oxford University Press.

    Buchanan, Daniel C., 1973. One Hundred Famous Haiku. San Francisco: Japan Publications.

    Chang, Ha-Joon, Hong-Jae Park, and Chul Gyue Yoo. 1998. Interpreting the Korean crisis:financial liberalisation, industrial policy, and corporate governance. Cambridge Journal of

    Economics, 1998 (vol. 22, no. 6).

    Crotty, James. 1993. Are Keynesian uncertainty and macrotheory compatible? Conventional

    decision making, institutional structures, and conditional stability in Keynesian macromodels,

    pages 105-42, in Gary Dymski and Robert Pollin, editors, New Perspectives in Monetary

    Macroeconomics: Explorations in the Tradition of Hyman P. Minsky. Ann Arbor: University of

    Michigan Press.

    Crotty, James, and Gary Dymski. 1998. Can the global Neoliberal regime survive victory in

    Asia? The political economy of the Asian crisis.International Papers in Political Economy

    1998(2).

    Dymski, Gary A. 1997. Deciphering Minskys Wall Street paradigm.Journal of Economic Issues

    31(2), June: 501-508.

    Dymski, Gary A., and Robert Pollin. 1993. Hyman Minsky as hedgehog: The power of the Wall

    Street paradigm. In Financial Conditions and Macroeconomic Performance. Edited by Steven

    Fazzari and Dmitri Papadimitriou. Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe, 1993.

    Grant, James. 1992. Money of the Mind: Borrowing and Lending in America from the Civil War

    to Michael Milken. New York: Noonday.

    Gray, H. Peter, and Jean M. Gray, Minskian fragility in the international financial system,

    pages 143-68, in Gary Dymski and Robert Pollin, editors, New Perspectives in MonetaryMacroeconomics: Explorations in the Tradition of Hyman P. Minsky. Ann Arbor: University of

    Michigan Press.

    Keynes, John Maynard. 1936. The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Prices. London:

    Macmillan.

    Kim, Woo-Jin. 1997. Economic Growth, Low Income, and Housing in South Korea . London:

    Macmillan Press.

    Kregel, Jan. 1998. Yes, it did happen again A Minsky crisis happened in Asia. Mimeo,

    Jerome Levy Economics Institute, May.

    Krugman, Paul. 1998. What happened to Asia? MIT Department of Economics, January.

    Minsky, Hyman. 1965. Commercial banking and rapid economic growth in California. In

    California Banking in a Growing Economy: 1946-75., edited by Hyman Minsky. Berkeley, CA:

    Institute of Business and Economic Research, University of California. Pages 79-134.

    Minsky, Hyman. 1975. John Maynard Keynes. New York: Columbia University Press.

    Minsky, Hyman. 1982. Can It Happen Again?: Essays on Instability and Finance. Armonk, NY:

    M.E. Sharpe.

  • 8/3/2019 Asset Price Bubbles and Minsky Approach to Asia Crisis

    20/26

    19

    Minsky, Hyman. 1986. Stabilizing an Unstable Economy. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Stiglitz, Joseph E; and Marilou Uy. 1996. Financial markets, public policy, and the East Asian

    miracle. World Bank Research Observer11(2), August: 249-276.

    Thirlwall, A.P. 1980. Regional problems are balance of payments problems. Regional Studies

    14(5).

    Wade, Robert, and Frank Veneroso. 1998. The Asian crisis: The high debt model vs. the WallStreet-Treasury-IMF complex.New Left Review No. 228, March-April.

    Yoon, Il-Seong. 1994. Housing in a Newly Industrialized Economy: The Case of South Korea.

    Brookfield VT: Avebury Publishing Co.

  • 8/3/2019 Asset Price Bubbles and Minsky Approach to Asia Crisis

    21/26

    20

    Figure 1: A stylized picture of a Minsky crisis

    PK=PI

    Y! = 0

    PK=PI

    Stages: Robust Fragile Ponzi Collapse

    NOTE: The variables shown are measured against cyclical trend, with time elapsing

    from left to right in the diagram.

    Sl

    aughter ofPK/PI

    ratio

    Output

    rowth

    Debt/income

    Asset price

    collapse

    Capacity

    utilization

  • 8/3/2019 Asset Price Bubbles and Minsky Approach to Asia Crisis

    22/26

    21

    Table 1: Relationships between Regional Economic

    Growth Rates and Asset Bubbles

    Is an asset bubble likely to form

    in one economy within a region?

    No Yes

    Balanced regional

    growth

    No wealth or labor

    transfers, dispersed

    technology and

    productivity

    Moral hazard problems

    in banking, inadequate

    supervision

    One economy grows

    faster in a growing

    region

    Higher innovation rate

    or productivity in

    high-growth area

    Faster wealth inflows

    into growing region: The

    boom economy case

    Balanced regional

    slowdown or

    stagnation

    No capital flight, or

    offsetting capital

    outflows and inflows

    Uneven economy-by-

    economy pace of capital

    flight from region

    Patterns in

    regional

    economic

    growth

    rates:

    One region or nation

    grows faster (or

    declines less) than

    others in a stagnant or

    declining region

    Higher innovation rate

    or productivity in

    high-growth area

    Capital flight

    from the region, failure

    of overseas lenders to

    renew short-term loans

    Table 2: Cross-border wealth flows and asset price pressures

    International border condition:

    Net foreign savings > 0

    (wealth inflows)

    Net foreign savings < 0

    (wealth outflows)

    Wealth inflows into

    this domestic region

    from other domestic

    regions

    Strong upward asset-price

    pressure:

    More overseas and domestic

    claims on available real assets

    (1980s California,1990s

    Seoul)

    Possible upward asset-price

    pressure:

    Net acquisition of foreign

    assets, more domestic claims

    on available real assets

    (1980s Tokyo)

    Intra-

    national

    border

    condition:

    Wealth outflows

    from this domesticregion to other

    domestic regions

    Indeterminate asset-price

    pressure:

    More overseas claims, butfewer domestic claims, on

    available real assets

    (1980s US Midwest)

    Downward asset-price

    pressure:

    Net acquisition of foreignassets, fewer domestic claims

    on available real assets

    (other urban areas

    in Japan)

    NOTE: The asset price pressures indicated here do not take into account other influences on asset

    prices, such as income growth.

  • 8/3/2019 Asset Price Bubbles and Minsky Approach to Asia Crisis

    23/26

    22

    Table 3: Determinants of the Pace of Transformation of Financial Claims

    into Net New Real Assets

    Type of capital inflows into domestic region:

    Foreign direct investment

    (domestic asset constructionby overseas capital)

    Portfolio investment

    (domestic asset purchase byoverseas capital)

    Intra-national lending and capital-emitting capacity:

    Strong: robust banks,

    borrower-lender relations,

    and capital sources

    High financial-to-real asset

    transformation with local

    multiplier effects

    Strength of financial-to-real

    asset transformation depends on

    domestic allocation system

    Weak: undercapitalized banks,

    fragile borrower-lender links,

    and few capital sources

    High financial-to-real asset

    transformation with small

    multiplier effects

    Low financial-to-real asset

    transformation

    Cross-border capital-flow policies:

    Active: ex ante policiesencouraging long-term

    investment, punishing or

    preventing short-term flight

    High and stable financial-to-real asset transformation

    Enhanced financial-to-real assettransformation by discouraging

    short-termism

    Passive: no conditions or

    controls vis-a-vis capital

    inflows or outflows

    High sensitivity of local

    investment to external

    conditions, govt policies

    Low real-asset creation

    potential

    Table 4: Bordered economies, Minsky crises, and Minsky cycles

    No asset bubble:

    Financial prices and

    real prices are aligned

    Asset bubble: Financialasset prices rise above

    real asset prices in an

    expansion

    Asset-price collapse:Financial asset prices

    fall below real asset

    prices

    Foreign savings0,

    a capital-absorbing

    economy

    Boom without

    bubble

    A bubble economy can

    generate an asset bubble

    due to capital inflows

    Reductions in capital

    inflows or sudden

    capital flight can

    generate Minsky crisis

  • 8/3/2019 Asset Price Bubbles and Minsky Approach to Asia Crisis

    24/26

    23

    Figure 2: Land and Stock Price Index values, Japan

    50

    100

    150

    200

    250

    300

    350

    1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996

    All figures are detrended by the Japanese CPI.

    Tokyo land values Nikkei average Tokyo stock avg

    Source: Akira Matsum oto,

    Ehime University.

    Index value, 1985=100

    Figure 3: Japanese housing finance trends, 1971-96:

    Price/income ratio and borrowing/cost ratio

    0.00

    0.50

    1.00

    1.50

    2.00

    2.50

    3.00

    3.50

    4.00

    1971 1974 1977 1980 1983 1986 1989 1992 1995

    Pct financed = borrowing / (borrowing + own funds)

    0.00

    10.00

    20.00

    30.00

    40.00

    50.00

    60.00

    70.00

    Price/income

    Pct financed

    Price/income trendline

    Pct financed trendline

    Price/income records the ratio of average house price to

    average home-buyer income; percent financed records the

    percentage of housing price externally financed, on average.

    Left axis: Housing price/income ratio Right axis: Borrowing as % of housg cost

  • 8/3/2019 Asset Price Bubbles and Minsky Approach to Asia Crisis

    25/26

    24

    Figure 4: Financial savings and liabilities relative to income, average for

    Japanese households with liabilities, 1960-96

    0

    0.5

    1

    1.5

    2

    2.5

    3

    3.5

    1960

    1965

    1970

    1975

    1980

    1982

    1983

    1984

    1985

    1986

    1987

    1988

    1989

    1990

    1991

    1992

    1993

    1994

    1995

    1996

    Source: 1996 Family Savings Survey, Govt of Japan

    Sav ings/incom e, worker hshds Liab's/inc, workers w/liab's (A)

    Liab's/inc, workers w/liab's (B) Sav ings/incom e, non-worker hshds

    Liab's/income, non-workers w/liab'sNOTE: Figures for non-worker hshds assume average incom es are the same for those with and w ithout

    liabilities. The same assumption is made for worker hshds under assumption A. Assumption B assumesworker hshds with liabilities have average income levels double those of h shds without liabilities.

    Left axis: Ratio of savings or liabilities to

    income

    Figure 5: Capital accounts, Korea, 1979-April 1998

    Millions of US $ (excluding errors and omissions)

    -$8,000

    -$4,000

    $0

    $4,000

    $8,000

    $12,000

    $16,000

    1979 1981 1983 1985 1987 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997

    Direct investment Portfolio investment Other capital flows

    Source: Asian Development Bank.

  • 8/3/2019 Asset Price Bubbles and Minsky Approach to Asia Crisis

    26/26

    25

    Figure 6: Land and Stock Price Index values, Korea,

    1982-August 1998

    50

    100

    150

    200

    250

    300

    350

    1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998

    Figures are detrended by the Korean CPI.

    Urban land prices Stock mkt average

    Sources: land prices, Land Taxation in Korea (Ro,

    1997); 1990-96 stock prices, Korean Stock Exchange;1982-89 stock prices, author's calculations.

    Index value: 1985 = 100