Anti corruption in afghanistan

21
1 Universität Konstanz Politik- und Verwaltungswissenschaften Wintersemester 2011/2012 Comparative Policy Analysis Dr. Jale Tosun Efficiency of Anti-Corruption Strategies in Afghanistan and Pakistan What has worked and what hasn’t Submitted by: Ahmad Rashid Jamal Born 28/01/1985 Martikelnr: 01/778825 Hindeburg Str. 7 78467 Konstanz Winter semester 2011/12, paper handed in 15/04/2012

Transcript of Anti corruption in afghanistan

Page 1: Anti corruption in afghanistan

1

Universität Konstanz

Politik- und Verwaltungswissenschaften

Wintersemester 2011/2012

Comparative Policy Analysis

Dr. Jale Tosun

Efficiency of Anti-Corruption Strategies in Afghanistan and Pakistan

What has worked and what hasn’t

Submitted by: Ahmad Rashid Jamal Born 28/01/1985 Martikelnr: 01/778825 Hindeburg Str. 7

78467 Konstanz Winter semester 2011/12, paper handed in 15/04/2012

Page 2: Anti corruption in afghanistan

2

Efficiency of Anti-Corruption Strategies in Afghanistan and Pakistan

Abstract

Corruption is a severe problem in many Asian countries especially in Afghanistan and Pakistan, judging from their ranking and scores on Transparency International’s Corruption Perceptions Index (CPI). This paper assesses the effectiveness of anti-corruption strategies and the accountability of anti-corruption agencies in Afghanistan and Pakistan. It starts with a general background regarding the practice and control of corruption. It then gives some information about Afghanistan and Pakistan’s administrative set-up. This is followed by an overview of the problem of corruption in Afghanistan and Pakistan and then, an analysis of the anti-corruption policies in terms of its mandate. Corruption in Afghanistan and Pakistan is horrible, and urgent actions are needed to improve the situation. To be effective, anticorruption strategies must include numerous exertions to reduce corruption as, broad-based, multi-faceted, and sustained medium-term efforts. This paper will answer the question that, Do Anti-corruption Agencies (ACAs) have the potential to turn into effective organizations by themselves, while the implementations of anticorruption policies require several agencies?

1. Introduction

The nuisance of corruption has links to a mass of vices. Its roots are linked to

injustice, mistrust, suspicion, extremism and terrorist activities. It creates a sense of

insecurity, aggravates poverty and adds to the calamity of the vulnerable segments of the

society. It also instills a sense of hopelessness and misery and threatens the potency of

good values which have been established over centuries of civilized struggle.

The term corruption has various definitions. The United Nations Manual on Anti-

Corruption, the Transparency International, and the multilateral financial institutions like

the World Bank and Asian Development Bank define corruption as, “abuse of public

office for private gains” (USAID 2009; UNCAC 2006; World Bank 2009).

The decisive victim of corruption and poverty is the human dignity itself. Hence it causes

contravene in the social order and emerges as a latent threat to the prosperity and stability

of human civilization. Corruption in government spending leads to severe decline in

impact of improvements and results in continuous increase in cost of upholding of public

assets. This paper analyses the features of anti-corruption strategies and agencies of

Afghanistan and Pakistan. Therefore, this paper asses to address the questions: 1.Can

Page 3: Anti corruption in afghanistan

3

anti-corruption policies combat corruption with a particular agency or a jointly campaign

is needed? What are the essential preconditions to anti-corruption agencies and

strategies?

While the implementation of anticorruption acts by several anti-corruption agencies can

spread and intensify anti-corruption campaign, as of in India, the Prevention of

Corruption Act (POCA) is implemented by the Central Bureau of Investigation (CBI), the

Central Vigilance Commission (CVC), and the anti-corruption bureaus and vigilance

commissions at the state level (Quah, 2003: 66). Similarly, the Philippines have relied on

18 anti-corruption agencies to enforce anti-corruption strategies since the Integrity Board

was formed by President Quirino in May 1950 (Batalla, 2001, p. 47; Oyamada, 2005,

pp.99-101).

This paper compares the performance of the anti-corruption laws by assessing the extent

to which these two ACAs have met the four conditions of ACAs. It is essential to

illustrate the four crucial functions of the Anti-Corruption Agencies (ACAs).

To combat corruption these countries should rely on the endorsement of anti-corruption

policies without a specific agency (i.e. Anti-corruption office or High office of

oversight).

2. Functions and Characterization of Anti-Corruption Agencies

ACAs are recognized by governments for the explicit aim of minimizing corruption in

their countries (i.e. High Office of Oversight in Afghanistan and National Accountability

Bureau). According to John R. Heilbrunn (2006) important functions and features of

ACAs are as follows:

1. The universal model, which is used in Hong Kong. It was characterized with its

investigative, deterrent, and communicative functions.

2. The investigative model is exemplified by centralized investigative commission as

operates in Singapore’s CPIB.

3. The parliamentary model distinguished by commissions that report to parliamentary

committees and are independent from other branches of state (i.e. executive and judicial).

For example, the New South Wales Independent Commission Against Corruption.

Page 4: Anti corruption in afghanistan

4

4. The multi-agency model includes different agencies to combat corruption. Beside this,

they are autonomous with preventive approach as, the United States Office of

Government Ethics that complements the Justice Department and its investigative role (P.

136).

3. Components of Anti-Corruptions Strategies

Corruption passes on to the use of public office for private gain in ways that breach

declared rules. Bribery, extortion and fraud, for example, are classified as corruption

when they entail the use of executive administrators or bureaucrats. Corruption

potentially occurs in all branches of government—the bureaucracy, the armed forces

(police and military army), the courts and legislative institutions—and can rage from

small-scale transactions involving relatively low level officials to the comprehensive

pillage of public resources by those at the very top of the opinionated and political

structure. While corruption, involves those in official positions, it also frequently

involves members of society, as victims or co-beneficiaries. Nonetheless, it is the

involvement of office-holders that makes corruption vitally different from other types of

misdeed and crime (USAID 2009: 7-12; World Bank 2009).

Strategies to reduce corruption regularly conceptualize it as a principal agent problem:

abuses occur because the public (the principal) is unable to manage and control the

performance and behavior of political and bureaucratic agent. While the decisive set of

principals consists of the general public, principal-agent problems can be simulated

within government organizations and amongst different parts of government ( Solnick

1998; Rose Ackerman 1999). Some sorts of corruption are also sustained and continued

by a momentous collective action problem: because the costs of corruption are often

socialized, conniving in corruption may be individually rational for members of the

public, even when they have collective interest in averting it. This collective and joint

action problem facade the more anti-corruption strategies rely on the general public

playing a vigorous function as a set of principals.

Page 5: Anti corruption in afghanistan

5

Anti-corruption policies/strategies entail the composition of a set of incentives (both

positive and negative) for “rule-abiding” behavior by agents who are both self-absorbed

and opportunistic. Through rule (policy, strategy) and institutional reforms, their aim is to

shrink occasions for corruption, compose corrupt behavior more pricey to the agents,

enhance the probability of its exposure and positively prize non-corrupt behavior. Doing

this in extremely corrupt government systems is extraordinary intricate and difficult. Not

only may institutions for identifying and penalizing corruption (Committees of

parliament, audit and courts agencies, for example) themselves be corrupt, but the

rational idea that corruption, once established, tends to endure accords with more formal

replica of performance. Because an assessment of likelihood that corrupt action will be

detected and punished is essential to an agent’s analysis of whether it is more rewarding

to break the rules or abide by them, the professed level of corruption manipulates an

agent’s decision to act corruptly, and is therefore a major determinant of the level of

corruption (Bardhan 1997: 1,331-4). The more corruption becomes stabilized and

normalized, the more a culture of corruption develops.

Strategies to condense and reduce corruption are classified into three core categories:

A. Policy change: It raises the cost and price of corruption through sanctions and

external monitoring; with formulating systems of provoke self-restraint within

government organizations. Corruption can only occur when government actors have

prudence over the use of resources or the nuisance of costs on private actors. If the

policies and programs that give rise to this prudence are themselves eliminated, the

particular forms of corruption related with them inevitably vanish (Rose-Ackerman 1999:

39-42).

While plans such as significance licensing, finance loans and government commercial

activity are productive soil for corruption, a deregulatory key nevertheless has some

limitations. First, corruption can undermine the implementation of certain types of

deregulatory policy: import tariffs, for example, may be abolished but unofficial levies

may still be imposed. Second, the prescription to deregulate may be politically naïve

(McLeod 2000) - as in Afghanistan – powerful actors have an interest in economic

controls and the opportunities for corruption that they generate. Third, getting rid of the

Page 6: Anti corruption in afghanistan

6

scope for discretion among government actors is frequently undesirable: many forms of

guideline have sound economic and social. Privatization, for example, may simply open

up new avenues for corruption if pursued in the absence of an autonomous judiciary and

plausible enforcement institutions (Rose-Ackerman 1999: 43).

B. The second kind in which anti-corruption strategies fall is that of resolving the

principal-agent problem that underlies corruption by imposing peripheral and external

restriction on government actors. If the reason for agency problems is that principals lack

information, procedures, which provide information and authorize principals, should help

resolve them. Hence observing and auditing institutions such as a free press and

independent inspection and audit panels, the incorporation of community representatives

in monitoring bodies, and laws that mandate transparency are all mechanisms that

increase the stream of information and make corrupt behavior more likely to be detected.

The complement to this sort of monitoring is efficient sanctioning power, without which

potentially corrupt agents have no inducement to abide by the rules. Democracy and the

rule of law are often advocated as sanctioning systems that can provide external

constraints on government’s actors (Johnston 1998). Democracy as an external constraint

mechanism is, however, potentially hindered by collective action problems and political

corruption. And the “rule of law”- meaning , at a minimum, a political system in which

the government obeys its own laws and applies them consistently, without regard to the

identity or power of particular individuals-is a complex institution: “the exceptional, not

the usual, method of social ordering” (Goodpaster 1999: 27).

C. The third form of anti-corruption strategy intends to renovate government institutions

in ways that supply for internal order along Weberian rantional-legal lines (Weber 1978:

217-26, 956-68). Specific reforms include international monitoring, sanctioning and

inspection mechanisms (internal audit committees, reporting requirements and

disciplinary codes, for example), but enlarge to a greater set of positive and negative

incentives for truthful behavior. These rang from increased official salaries to selective

employment, merit-based promotion and the development of organizational routines that

reproduce habits of formalized, rule-based behavior (for example, Powell and DiMaggio

Page 7: Anti corruption in afghanistan

7

1991). While such characteristics are sometimes considered inefficient, there is

verification of a positive relationship between Weberian bureaucracy and economic

growth, even when initial per capita GDP and human capital are controlled for (Evans

and Rausch 1999).

Strategies and policies to shrink corruption by generating interconnected organizations

with strong inner incentive do not always combine easily with strategies to impose

external constraints and accountability on government. Historically, however, most

countries that successfully made the transition to systems of government with relatively

low levels of corruption eventually combined both types of strategy (Silbermann 1993).

Indication about the optimal sequencing of these different types of reform is mixed. Some

European states developed elements of the rule of law well before significant

bureaucratic rationalization occurred. The early introduction of electoral democracy,

however, has presented problems for subsequent bureaucratic rationalization in the

countries such as the Philippines (Sidel 1999). Some dispersion of political power is

essential if political leaders are to have any motivation to create the kinds of de-

personalized government institutions that decrease opportunities for corruption—but

political leaders whose positions are very unconfident and insecure also have petite

motivation to develop capable, incorrupt bureaucracies (Geddes 1994).

4. Afghanistan’s anti-corruption efforts and High Office of Oversight

Almost one decade after the collapse of the Taliban government, corruption has

become more than the standard issue bribery, nepotism, and extortion in government.

Corruption has become a system, through networks of corrupt practices and people that

reach across the whole of government to sabotage governance and administration system.

Particularly, these networks ensure that the guilty are not brought to justice; often the

officials and agencies that are supposed to be part of the solution to corruption are instead

a critical part of the corruption disease.

Corruption is a momentous and growing problem across Afghanistan which destabilizes

security, development and state-building objectives. Pervasive and systematic corruption

Page 8: Anti corruption in afghanistan

8

is now at an unprecedented scope in the country’s history. The government has or is

developing most of institutions needed to combat corruption. But these institutions, like

the rest of the government, are limited by lack of capacity and unwillingness to prosecute

high level corruption Thus corruption, a symptom of worse and poor governance, caused

a serious threat to Afghanistan’s entire development agenda. It has become widespread,

entrenched and pervasive in Afghanistan. The country’s ranking in Transparency

International’s Corruption Perception Index dropped from 117th out of 159 countries

covered in 2005 to 172nd of 180 countries in 2007 and subsequently to 176th out of 180

countries in 2008 (i.e. fifth-worst in the world). Finally, Afghanistan has positioned 180th

out of 182 countries in 2011 (Transparency International 2005; 2011).

Year (2005- 2011) Number of Countries Afghanistan’s Rank Afghanistan’s Score

( Out of 10)

2005 158 117 2.5

2006 163 NA NA

2007 179 172 1.8

2008 180 176 1.5

2009 180 179 1.3

2010 178 176 1.4

2011 182 180 1.5

Source: International Transparency

Page 9: Anti corruption in afghanistan

9

0

20

40

60

80

100

120

140

160

180

200

2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012

Number of Countries 158163

Afghanistan’s Rank 117NA

Afghanistan’s Score ( Outof 10) 2.5 NA

High rate of corruption significantly impacts in judicial, financial management and

service delivery of government most Afghans have little confidence in the formal justice

system. Some have claimed that the justice sector is the most corrupt in the country.

Investigators, prosecutors and judges are too often part of the problem, not the solution.

People saw justice as a commodity, they bought and sold. Many, especially those outside

the cities, turn not to courts for justice and dispute resolution but rather to community

structures (USAID 2009: 7).

Corruption affects natural resource extraction which is an essential development

potential. Afghanistan has substantial undeveloped sub-soil resources of many types.

Developing these resources, especially in ways that support the foundation and extension

of upstream and downstream linkages through inputs as well as processing, may afford

for considerable economic growth, employ expansion, tax revenues, and business growth

(USAID 2009: 6). Pervasive corruption can also make donors more unwilling to offer

funds through Afghan government budget channels, despite the findings of earlier and

recent assessments of public financial management performance that financial controls

and fiduciary standards are adequate and diminish the risk of fraud and other misuse of

budgetary funds (World Bank 2009: 2).

Page 10: Anti corruption in afghanistan

10

Further effect of corruption is uncommunicativeness in the media and civil society to slot

in with government – either to work with officials and elected leaders or on the other

hand to serve as watchdogs on their operations. In general, non-government organizations

have been created to deliver services and support particular groups, such as women. In

general, their interest in advocacy is low, let alone pushing on general issues of

governance like corruption. NGOs and the media can be intimidated by powerful local

interests. The “mafia” does threaten organizations, sometimes directly with violence, and

other times indirectly by pressuring business to reduce support and advertising. However,

more proactive task by civil society organizations and the media is necessary to shine the

light on government practices and combat corruption (USAID 2009: 7).

One of the considerable and fundamental issues of democracy and state building is

education, corruption weakens education system significantly. In adequate salaries

driving teachers to concentrate on personal tutoring, bribes for grades, teacher

performance/competency evaluation and salaries are beginning to be addressed by the

Ministry of Education (MoED). Corruption has affected the higher levels of public

bureaucrats in Ministry of Higher Education (MoHE), where university degrees can be

bought, often after students buy their way in and through their courses. New measures

and legislation should be undertaken to oversight responsibilities of MoHE of emerging

private universities in Afghanistan (USAID 2009: 5).

Furthermore, corruptions represent a solemn warning to Afghanistan’s state-building and

development programs. The serious threats include, in addition to depletion and loss of

funds and public sector’s assets; distortion of government decisions and strategies;

ineffectiveness of service delivery; unequal damage to the poor who can least afford to

pay bribes; adverse effects on private sector; loss of government assets and revenue; and

entrenchment of a criminal culture within the government (including buying and selling

of governmental positions).

In spite of strong statements against corruption by governmental bureaucrats, little

tangible evolution has been achieved in combat against corruption. The argument used to

Page 11: Anti corruption in afghanistan

11

be that the institutional environment for combating corruption in Afghanistan is

characterized by “a lack of clear policy support, explicit legal frameworks,

leadership, capability and/or clarity of functions in the different integrity institutions”

UNDP 2008), Central to these efforts is the High Office of Oversight (HOO), which was

created by Presidential Decree in July 2008. The dedicated AC agency has limited but

critical technical responsibilities and authority, but will provide oversight and technical

assistance to other key government agencies.

A high-level inter-institutional committee set up by President and has completed its

report which is now available, but this report is widely considered not to constitute a full-

blown anti-corruption strategy. More generally, “A number of separate, overlapping, and

to some extent competing government anti-corruption documents are in circulation

(including the Afghanistan National Development Strategy’s anticorruption document,

the anti-corruption roadmap paper, and others), which leads to risk of confusion and lack

of broad ownership of a clear anti-corruption agenda” (World Bank 2009: 2).

The legal framework to fight against corruption in Afghanistan is not clear enough and

the institutional arrangements are so weak like other governmental organs, moreover,

many organizations are working in isolation without coordination with Anti-corruption

agencies. There are lacks of political supports and interference by president, which is an

evident, that undermines the fight against corruption. Above all, lack of limited capacity

presents a grave constraint hindering anti-corruption efforts. Recently some progress has

been made on the legal and institutional front. Some new anti-corruption laws have been

adopted, under which a new anti-corruption agency (i.e. The High Office for Monitoring

Implementation of the Anti-corruption Strategy) has been established and it is directly

reporting to the president. Under new law, GIAAC is abolished. However, there are some

enduring technical issues with the new law, and more commonly the extent to which the

new legal and institutional arrangements may achieve better consequences than past

efforts, is not yet clear. Moreover, United Nations Convention Against Corruption

(UNCAC) has been ratified by Parliament, and the government is working with UN

organization on Drug and Crime (UNODC) to make Afghanistan’s laws consistent with

UNCAC. The current problem is that the HOO is not an independent agency, but has

Page 12: Anti corruption in afghanistan

12

been established within the Office of the President (USAID 2009; World Bank 2009,

ADB 2010).

The operations of all anti-corruption agencies are limited by a lack of capacity, rivalries

and poor integration, and an unwillingness to pursue and prosecute high-level corruption.

With development, the HOO may be able to both boost capacity and address integration.

But the HOO is not a substitute for high-level anti-corruption efforts in other institutions.

The HOO can nudge these other bodies and assist them – but cannot drive the needed

processes themselves. Monthly meetings of the High-Level Anti-Corruption Commission

(AC), chaired by the President, with the HOO participating and serving as the secretariat,

are the lever to push ministries and departments into building anti corruption capacity,

integrate actions across the government, and prosecute corrupt actions (USAID 2009:

12).

Summing up, the problem of corruption faced by Afghanistan is horrible, and urgent

actions are needed to improve the situation. There should be different anti-corruption

efforts as, a broad-based, multi-faceted, sustained medium-term effort. By itself, just

trying to catch and punish corrupt officials will not work or be sustainable. It needs a

holistic approach which co-ordinates all pillars and elements of anti-corruption strategy

(prevention through systems and capacity improvements, law enforcement,

administrative measures, consciousness rising, and external accountability). It is

important to have an anti-corruption lens because corruption is a cross-cutting issue. We

should not expect sudden, major infiltrate in the short run, but significant development,

sustained over time, is crucial.

5. Pakistan’s National Anti-corruption Strategy

Pakistan is making headlines in the globe on corruption these days and contemporary

discourse within the country has been focused on this issue in the recent past. In fact,

corruption and corrupt practices continue in one form or the other, only to raise their

head. The administration and bureaucratic System of Pakistan is rooted in the

administration system of British India. Pakistan had adapted the structure from the Indian

Civil Service (ICS). The arrangement was designed, mainly, to preserve order and collect

Page 13: Anti corruption in afghanistan

13

taxes (Chowdhury 1972: 12). District officers were the key stone of the administration.

They collected revenue, ran the police and were the head magistrates of their districts.

Later it changes to a centralized system.” It was important to the British that the

executive and judiciary should not be separated: unrepresentative rulers need to block

challenges to their authority” (Duncan 1989).

It is useful to note that corruption was mentioned as one of the ailments afflicting

territories constituting Pakistan by the founder of the country, (i.e. Pakistan inherited

corruption since its foundation), Mohammad Ali Jinnah, in his first address to the

Constituent Assembly on 11 August 1947. He said: “One of the biggest curses from

which India is suffering—I do not say that other countries are free from it, but, I think our

condition is much worse—is bribery and corruption. That really is a poison. We must put

that down with an iron hand and I hope that you will take adequate measures as soon as it

is possible for this Assembly to do so” (Jinnah 1947).

State employees across different institutions of the state engage in various forms of

corrupt practices. These range from basic bribery and extortion of individuals and

businesses to various forms of domestic and international payment on procurement of

materials and services. In general, one can observe and distinguish state-led corruption by

civil bureaucrats, the armed forces and politicians.

Pakistan has shaped notably on the list of corrupt countries. In 1998, the World Bank

estimated corruption in Pakistan close to 10% of GDP (Khan et al., 2004). The country is

being fast dumped by its manpower because of being victims of corruption and left with

no prospects of progression

Pakistan’s ranking on Transparency International’s Corruption Perception Index (CPI)

has constantly been among the lowest:

Page 14: Anti corruption in afghanistan

14

Year (2005-2011) Number of Countries Pakistan’s Rank Pakistan’s Score

(Out of 10)

2005 158 144 2.1

2006 163 142 2.2

2007 179 138 2.4

2008 180 134 2.5

2009 180 139 2.4

2010 178 143 2.3

2011 182 134 2.5

Source: Transparency International

0

20

40

60

80

100

120

140

160

180

200

2004 2006 2008 2010 2012

Number of Countries

Pakistan’s Rank

Pakistan’s Score (Out of10)

A large amount of the bribery carried out by the state, is executed through the civil

bureaucracy. Ranging from petty bribes to the policeman or building authority clerk to

major payment on procurement, civil bureaucrats are the ‘deal executors? They are in the

circle for the simple reason that they carry out the certification and are most familiar with

rules and regulations, as well as the gap and lacunae that exist. However, apart from the

petty bribes and extortion, for the most part the civil administration is not the sole

applicant of big-ticket corruption. Over the years, the civil bureaucracy in Pakistan has

lost its thump and political power to the executive and legislature, whether military or

civilian (Samad 2008).

Page 15: Anti corruption in afghanistan

15

Compare to anti-corruption policies in Afghanistan, the National Accountability Bureau

Ordinance 1999 (NAB) is the most comprehensive piece of legislation to date in Pakistan

to combat corruption. It gives NAB unique and unprecedented powers. The preamble sets

the tone for what NAB was proclaimed to achieve by aiming for “effective measures for

the detection, investigation, speedy disposal of cases of corruption, corrupt practices,

misuse or abuse of power” (NAB 1999: 1).

The director of NAB is appointed by the President of Pakistan, making it a political

appointment. After an amendment in 2001 in the NAB Ordinance, further security of

term was granted to the chairperson by equating his/her terms of appointment with that of

a Supreme Court judge, who can only be removed by the Supreme Judicial Council, a

constitutional body. But in Afghanistan the director of HOO is appointed by the

president. After an amendment in the NAB Ordinance in 2002, NAB has multiple tasks

and also responsible for enhancing awareness about corruption and for its prevention. It

has prepared a National Anti-Corruption Strategy (NACS). The awareness campaign has

found allies in the educational sector and the media such as poster competitions for

students and public television debate on corruption (Hafiez, 2005).

Contrary to Afghanistan, the government of Pakistan has launched the most significant

institutional reforms which are the decentralization and separation of powers through the

local government ordinance, 2001. This ordinance encourages and gives special role to

the civil society, community representatives to participate in development programs.

Other initiatives include civil service reforms, judicial reforms and separation of

accounting functions from the auditor-general’s office etc. During a mission to Pakistan

in April 2002, Transparency International praised the government for these measures but

also pointed to a range of areas where further reforms were needed such as freedom of

information legislation, overhauling the public procurement system and bringing the

military and judiciary under NAB (Ham et al.2007). A conspicuous gap is insufficient

implementation of the existing reforms in this area though the police force is one of the

most corrupt institutions of the country (Samad 2008: 97).

Page 16: Anti corruption in afghanistan

16

Conclusion

A distinct and single anticorruption institution cannot function as an omnipotent and

supreme institution. In order to combat and eradicate corruption it is necessary to reform

all governmental institutions and make them capable of effectively implementing their

mandate and developing coordination and inter linkages among entities. Among

underlying theoretical models, monitoring and incentives programmes are typically based

on the principal–agent model. In this model the „principal‟, who are population at large,

wants to achieve some goals and the “agent”, typically a civil servant to implement this

goal. It is often difficult for the principal to know if the agent is achieving the principal’s

goal or following his or her own agenda, given that the end goal can be difficult to

observe. Monitoring and incentives model increases the probability of agent’s

punishment, who is engaging in corrupt activities. Therefore, monitoring is not effective

without incentives agendas. The anti-corruption strategies in Afghanistan and Pakistan

should include Monitoring and incentives programs to increase the efficiency of policies.

Structurally, NAB follows the Hong Kong model i.e. it is allocated functions of

investigation, prosecution, prevention and awareness. The success of this model depends

upon a number of conditions including: support from government; independence of

anticorruption entities from government; components of a national anti-corruption

strategy; levels of corruption that allow the agency to manage them; governance activities

with different incentives to reduce corruption; and appropriate legal frameworks to

follow cases through the courts.

Internally, the agency should be financially independent and have sufficient resources

and appropriate staffing; clear strategic and operational objectives; operational

independence and freedom from political interference; high levels of integrity in its

leaders and competency among staff; public understanding and confidence in the agency

(Doig et al., 2006). However, as can be seen from the above discussion, many of these

conditions do not yet exist in Afghanistan and Pakistan’s institutions.

Page 17: Anti corruption in afghanistan

17

Effectiveness of HOO and NAB would require high political commitment, accountability

of these entities to an elected body such as the parliament and overall governance reforms

to create an enabling environment.

Challenges and Recommendations

• Firstly, given these countries’ (Afghanistan and Pakistan) economic problems and

political fragility, it is unlikely to expect reforms to eradicate corruption in a few

months. Reforms should concentrate on role of information and foreign

constraints- a free press, broad auditing, democratic controls, the courts and

external strain from international institutions.

• Secondly, there should be adequate legal support for the ACA to investigate

corruption. To investigate corruption and carry out effective enforcement a

government needs strong power and political will by passing effective

legislations.

• Thirdly, the ACA should be independent in implementing of its enforcement work

without political obstructions and interference.

• Afghanistan and Pakistan need to adopt a zero tolerance policy on corruption. If

there is a mutual standard in the society, where small corruption is tolerated in

private sector, then it is unfeasible for the society to eradicate corruption and

become clean.

• Fighting corruption is a challenging task; therefore, you do need very

professional, intelligent and knowledgeable staffs. Thus anti-corruption agents

must be very professional.

Page 18: Anti corruption in afghanistan

18

References

Batalla, E.C. (2001). De-institutionalizing Corruption in the Philippines: Identifying

Strategic Requirements for Reinventing Institutions. In A.C. Pedro Jr. (Ed.), Combating

Corruption in East Asia (pp. 41-78). Manila: Yuchengco Center for East Asia, De La

Salle University

Chowdhury, M. 1988. Pakistan: Its Politics and Bureaucracy, Associated Publishing

House,New Delhi

Doig, A., Watt, D. & Williams, R. 2006. Hands-On or Hands-Off: Anti-Corruption

Agencies in Action, Donor Expectations and a Good Enough Reality, Public

Administration and Development, Vol. 26(2), 163-172.

Duncan, E.1989. Breaking the Curfew: A Political Journey Through Pakistan. Michael

Joseph, London.

Evans, Peter, and James Rausch (1999), ‘Bureaucracy and Growth: A Cross-National

Analysis of the Effects of “Weberian” State Structures on Economic Growth’, American

Sociological Review 64 (5): 748–65.

Geddes, Barbara (1994), Politician’s Dilemma: Building State Capacity in Latin

America, University of California Press, Berkeley CA.

Goodpaster, Gary (1999), ‘The Rule of Law, Economic Development and Indonesia’, in

Timothy Lindsey (ed.), Indonesia: Law and Society, The Federation Press, Sydney: 21–

32.

Hafiez, M. 2005.Turning Pakistan into a True Blue Chip, The Blue Chip, Vol.2(14),

17-24.

Ham, M. V. Omari, S. & Wiehen, M. H. 2002. Pakistan’s Anti-Corruption Programme:

Page 19: Anti corruption in afghanistan

19

Heilbrunn, J.R. (2006). Anti-Corruption Commissions. In R. Stapenhurst, N. Johnston

and R. Pelizzo (Eds.), The Role of Parliament in Curbing Corruption (pp. 135-148).

Washington, D.C.: The World Bank.

Islamic Republic of Afghanistan,(2010), High Office of Oversight and Anti-Corruption

(HOO). Anti-Corruption Strategic Plan 2011-2013. Kabul: Islamic Republic of

Afghanistan, High Office of Oversight and Anti-Corruption (HOO),. 59pp.

http://www.pksoi.org/document_repository/Lessons/HOO_Anti-

Corruption_Strategic_Plan_2011-2013-LMS-732.pdf

Johnston, Michael (1998), ‘What Can Be Done about Entrenched Corruption?’, in B.

Pleskovic and J. Stiglitz (eds), Annual World Bank Conference on Development

Economics Economics 1997, World Bank, Washington DC: 69–90.

Khan, M. Kakakhel, N. & Dubnick, M. 2004. Prosecuting Corruption: The Case of

Pakistan. Working Paper for the Ethics Forum held by the American Society for Public

Administration, Portland, 26-27March, Available on line from

http://unpan1.un.org/intradoc/groups/public/documents/APCITY/UNPAN01911

3.pdf (accessed 14 March 2012).

Low A. Lucinda (2006), The United Nations Convention Against corruption: The

Globalization of anti-corruption standards, London, England

McLeod, Ross (2000), ‘Soeharto’s Indonesia: A Better Class of Corruption’, Agenda 7

(2): 99–112.

Observations and Recommendations. Transparency International, May, Available online

From unpan1.un.org/intradoc/groups/public/documents/APCITY/UNPAN019877.pdf

(accessed 13, Feb, 2012).

Page 20: Anti corruption in afghanistan

20

Powell, Walter, and Paul DiMaggio (eds) (1991), The New Institutionalism in

Organisational Analysis, University of Chicago Press, Chicago IL.

Quah, J.S.T. (2003). Curbing Corruption in Asia: A Comparative Study of Six

Countries. Singapore: Eastern Universities Press.

Rose-Ackerman, Susan (1999), Corruption and Government: Causes, Consequences, and

Reform, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge (UK).

Bardhan, Pranab (1997), ‘Corruption and Development: A Review of the Issues’, Journal

of Economic Literature 35 (3): 1,320–46

Sidel, John (1999), Capital, Coercion and Crime: Bossism in the Philippines, Stanford

University Press, Stanford CA.

Silberman, Bernard (1993), Cages of Reason: The Rise of the Rational State in France,

Japan, the United States and Great Britain, University of Chicago Press, Chicago IL

Solnick, Steven (1998), Stealing the State: Control and Collapse in Soviet Institutions,

Harvard University Press, Cambridge MA.

Transparency International (2011) www.transparency.org

www.transparency.org/.../20299/282101/file/TI Pakistan_national_corruption _percepti

on_survey_2006.pdf

UNDP, 2008. Institutional arrangements for Combating Corruption in Afghanistan:

Analysis and recommendations - Preliminary report. Kabul: UNDP. p. 6.

U.S. Agency of International Development, 2009: Assessment of Corruption in

Afghanistan. Washington, DC: U.S. Agency of International Development.

http://pdf.usaid.gov/pdf_docs/PNADO248.pdf

Weber, Max (1978), Economy and Society, University of California Press, Berkeley CA.

Page 21: Anti corruption in afghanistan

21

World Bank, 2009: Fighting Corruption in Afghanistan: Summaries of vulnerabilities to

corruption Assessments. Washington DC: World Bank.

.