Abpot .. White Collar.··Crime - National Criminal Justice ... This is Ci substantially revised...

47
.:;;::. -....':. I' " F >l\" •• This microfiche' fr.om ,documents received for .' in" the . data base. Since NCJR$ cannot exercise hysical condition the frame quality will vary. The resolution chart on this frame may be used to evaluate the document quality. w Iii IJ£ .8 - 1- , ---' --,.,'. MICROCOPY .RESOLUTION TEST CHART,,· ,_ ' ,-,' NATIONAL BUREAU OF '" oZ'." t. . - '\'1 .,.. - .. ''0' -_< ... - .. I' I' c:s ' .. Microfilming procedures 'used to create this fiche comply with the standards set forth in 41CFR Points of view 01 opinions stated in this:pocument are those ofthe do not represent the official position or policies of pepartment of Justice. , ......... 1\ , ' - ),:':. --1, \ \ "j. f""-" . ,- .. -' ""',:" k : I .6/30/81 r1 . ,I .J...... .. ,"·=·'c·- oo ".: Nationill Institute of Justi¢¢, c ; , ... g Abpot .. T White Collar.··Crime: j\ - Matters of Conceptualization· .... ?.andRese4ICh t.';'" i . I. . " '.' , ... "'.".' ':;-" ,-,. .... ,_ ... c, . C'.·' <,; , ... \;w.. , If you have issues viewing or accessing this file contact us at NCJRS.gov.

Transcript of Abpot .. White Collar.··Crime - National Criminal Justice ... This is Ci substantially revised...

Page 1: Abpot .. White Collar.··Crime - National Criminal Justice ... This is Ci substantially revised version of the "~ckgrourrl Paper on White Collar Crime" (Shapiro 1976) which was prepared

.:;;::.

-....':.

I' " F

>l\" ••

This microfiche' fr.om ,documents received for .' ~nclusion in" the . data base. Since NCJR$ cannot exercise

\:,~ontroloyer t~e hysical condition orth~ docum~ntssubrQitted, the individu~l frame quality will vary. The resolution chart on this frame may be used to evaluate the document quality.

w Iii IJ£

.8 -

",~I f2'S<~~:§«I~~ • 1->~

'~';

,

>-~-'. ---' --,.,'. MICROCOPY .RESOLUTION TEST CHART,,· ,_ '

,-,' NATIONAL BUREAU OF STANDARDS-1963~A ~-'J ""~ '" oZ'." t. . - ,,~-. ~~'~1

'\'1 .\~::-:::-~ ~ .,.. - .. ''0' -_< ... -.. ~~"':"..............-

I' I'

c:s ' .. \~,.\:,

Microfilming procedures 'used to create this fiche comply with the standards set forth in 41CFR 101~11.504.

Points of view 01 opinions stated in this:pocument are those ofthe authoif~)i,&,p.d do not represent the official position or policies of tn1i'~U;<§. pepartment of Justice.

, .........

1\ , '

~" -

),:':.

--1, (~" ~

~ ~

\ ~,~f)Aft"'f[MrD \ "j. f""-" . ,- .. :~ -' ""',:" k :

I .6/30/81 r1 . ,I

.J...... .. ,"·=·'c·-oo

".:

U.S.~~Dtor')~

Nationill Institute of Justi¢¢, c

;

, Research'ori"\~iteC(JdlarCriine

~ ... g Abpot ..

T

White Collar.··Crime: j\ -

z· Matters of Conceptualization·

.... ?.andRese4ICh

t.';'" .;:~

~~'-;"'~3=-'~":>;;c ~'=~~!",~""~,,

i . I. . " '.'

, "~'~' ... "'.".' .~ ~

':;-"

,-,. ~_ .... ~~~ ,_ ... ~._\.'-~,. _~_ c,

. C'.·' ;.~ <,; , ii'·~~:"',-::':f.1

c~ ... ~

~4~ \;w..

,

If you have issues viewing or accessing this file contact us at NCJRS.gov.

Page 2: Abpot .. White Collar.··Crime - National Criminal Justice ... This is Ci substantially revised version of the "~ckgrourrl Paper on White Collar Crime" (Shapiro 1976) which was prepared

o

About the National Institute of Justice

.: ';

The Nationall nstitute of Justice is a research, dev~iopment, and evaluation center within the U.S. Department of J uSlice. Established in 1979 by the Justice System" Irh1lfovement ACt, N IJ builds upon the foundation laid by the former National Institute. of Law Enforcement and Criminal Justice, tlie;first major Federal research program on crime and justice. ""::" co

Carrying out the m~ndate assiglled by the Congress, the l'lationallnstitute of Justice:

• Sponsors research and development to improve and strengthen the crimiJ1aljUstice system and related civil justice aspects, with a balanced prograrn.u.f basic and applied research.

• Evaluates the effectiveness of federally-funded justice improvement programs and identifies programs that promise to be successful if continued or repeated..·· i

• Tests and demonstrates new and improved approaches to strengthen the justice system, and recoij1mends '" actions that can be taken by Federal,,$tate, ,and local governments and private organizations and individuals to achieve this goa1.- c,

• Disseminates information from research, demonstrations, evaluations,'and special programs to Federal, State and local governments; and serves as an international Ciearinghouse) of justice information.

• Trains criminal"just,ice practitionerS" in research and evaluation findings; and assists the research community through fellowships and special seminars.

Auth(lrity for administering the Institute and awarding grants, contracts, and cooperative agreements is vested in the N lJ Director, assisted by a 2 I-member Advisory Board. The Board recommends poliCies and priorities and advises.on peer review procedures. . . . '

N IJ is authorized to support res'tarch and experimentation dealing with the full range of criminaljustice issues and related civil justice matters. A portion of its resources goes to support work on these long-range priorities:

• Correlates of crime and determinantsofc!!minal behavior • Violent crime and the violent offender .

". - .,. Community crime preventior. .Career.criminals and' habitual offenders " • Utili7.ation-and.{i!!ployment of police resources

.• Pretrial process: corisiste.n.cy, fairness, and delay reduction • Sentencing" . • RehabiHt3tion • Deterrence . "'~" . • Performance standards and meastires'for criminal justice

" ".::'i:..,"

'~{\~:)

In addition, the In!!titute focuses on priorities identified by the,CongreSJ), ir.lcludingpolice~nlinority relations, problems of victims and witnesses, and alternatives to judicial resolution of disputes,' ,

,Reports of NIJ-sponsored studie~.awreviewed by Institute officials and staff. The views of outsid~ experts knowledgeable in the report's subject'area are also obtained. Publication indicates that the report meets the Ins!itute's standards of quality, but it signifies no endorsement of conclusions or recomme~datlons. ",'

H~rry M. Bratt .. Aicting Director

ooJ·I980-11

-~

- ,,-

,'.

(~~~~~ ~~--~---~-.--~.--., ~ \' .J '

1\

R.esearch on White Collar Crime

Thinking.,Ab'Out ~~\1L:, cue· l1r lute . 0 ar~,. nme:

!\

M,~tters of Cdnceptualization and Reseatth

Susan P. Shapiro

December 1980

u.s. Department of JUstice National Institute of Justice

"

::'1

;";-'

--: '

, ,

Page 3: Abpot .. White Collar.··Crime - National Criminal Justice ... This is Ci substantially revised version of the "~ckgrourrl Paper on White Collar Crime" (Shapiro 1976) which was prepared

;J

National Institute of Justice .. Harry M. }Jratr' Acting Director

This proj.,et was supported by grant numbfJr 78NI·AX-0017 awarded to Yale Law SchoO~ Yale University, by the National Institute of Law Enforceliient and'crimlnal Justice, Law Enforce/Y16'nt Aaalatance Administration, U. S. Department of Justice, under the Omnibus Crime Control and Safe Streets Act of 1~, 81 amended. POints of view or opinions stated In this document are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent the offIcI.- positIOn or polICIes of the U.S. Department of Justice. .

The Law EnforctMnent AssiStanCe Admlnlatr~n reserves the ~lght to reproduce, !publlsh, translate, or otherwise use and to authorize others to publish and use ai' or any part of the copyrighted material contained In ttlls publication.

Copyright C1980 by Susan P. Shapiro

(;

• • .. ~ .. " . . • • • . .. . . . ~ • • • • . .. . • • • • v

PREFAca II • .. . . .. . • • . .. • • • • • • • • • II .. . .. • • • vii

I. COOCEPrlOOS OF "WHI're COLlAR CRIME II .' .. • •

SOcial Status and Social Location Criteria.

· . .. .. .. . • • • •

• • • • • • • • • •

1

2 2 4

SOcial Status. • .. • .. • • •• ~ • • Social Location. • • • .. • • • • .. •

The Role of Organizations in Il~egality . .. • • • • • • • • • • o • • • De. • • •

.. . .. . • • · .. .. . 7

Di~rim,inating Offenses in Organizational Coritex~. • • • • • .. 11 Differentiating Individuals, OrganizatL~ns anQ

'Ibeir SOcial Locations • • • • • • It .. •• ! .. • .. • 11 O1aracteristics of Behavior. • .. .. • • .. • c • • • • .. • 17

DeceptiOn and Concealment. • • • • • • • • •• • • .. 18 Fraoo. • • 5 • ..-;. • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • c 20 Self-dealing and COrruption. • • • • • • • • • • • .. 21 .Regulatoty Offenses. • .... • • • • • • .r. . . . .. 23 Additional Distinctions~~ • .. .. • • • • • • • • • • 24 .-.-

'ltle Issue of Criminali bJ • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • •• • • 26

II. RESEARCH AGENJl1\ 00 mITE ·OOLIAR ILLmALI'fi AND rrs cmrROL. 29

The Nature, Organization, and· SOcial Iocatioo of White Collar Illegality. • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • ~ • • • • • • '" 29

The FOllll and SOcial Otganizatial of White Collar Illegali ty • • • • • • • • • • • • " • .. • • 0 • • • • 29

'!he Social Location of White Collar Illegality • II • • • 31

The Normative Dimension of White COllar Illegalityl • • • • • • 35 Attitooes and Values COncerning White O'.)llar Cri1ne •••• 35 Legal Development •••••• ~ • • • • • • • • • • •• 36 Norms and SOcial Policy. • • • .. • • • • • • • • • • •• 39

The Enforcement-Qf oNotttS Proscribing White cOllar Illegality. • 40 '11le Developnent of Enforcemenf.: Organizations .. • • • • • 41 Enforcement Strategy • • • • Ii " • • • .. • • • • .. • • • 42 Enforcement Policy • • .' • • II • • • • • • • • • • • •• 47 Enforcement 11\pact • • • • • • • • .. • • • • • • • • • • 47 The COst of Enforcement. • • • • • • • • • • • • • • •• 4B

iii

}

1 , d )

Page 4: Abpot .. White Collar.··Crime - National Criminal Justice ... This is Ci substantially revised version of the "~ckgrourrl Paper on White Collar Crime" (Shapiro 1976) which was prepared

- - -, .---. ~--.-'-\-- ~-~---~~~

r.Ihe Disposi tiQl'l and Sanctioning of White COllar Illegality. • • • The Nature of Case Disposition • • • • • • e • • • • • •

Prosecutorial Success. • • • • • • '. • • • • • • ! • • •

The' Nature of Sanctions. • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • Deterrence •• • • • • • • .. . . . . . .' . • • • • • • •

III. CONCLUSION. • • • . . . • • • • ~. . • • • • • • • • • • • 10 • •

49 51 53 54 55

58

BIBLIOGRAPHY ."........... II- e.,' • • • .. • • • • • ,!. • ',,' 61

(.,

iv

~~-,---------- ...

ABSTRACT

This paper was . prepared to assistneWcoroors to think conceptually and theoretically about white collar {%ime. The paper has two parts. The first cri tically ,'. reviews the oonceptlJal history of White oollar crime and proposes distinctions that might alleviate sate of tlie oonfusion that has plagued the usage of the term. The mtion tbatorganizations play distinctive roles in

. the social organization of illegality is developed and offered as a COIlma1 denaninator that captures many of the conceptions of white collar cr~

, filling the literature. However, . distinctions ~ on behavioral criteria are ultimately recxmnended, and three generic behavioral types - fraoo, self-dealing/corruption, and regulatory offenses are described. '!he second part ()f the paper suggests a series of researchq-destions and theoretical issues concerned with the nature and social control of white collar crime. They include cOnsideration of the nature, organization; and social location of white collar illegalitYi the nor:mative dimension of white ~llar illegali~: the enforcement of norms proscribing white collar illegality: and the disposition and sanctioning of white collar illegality. '!he paper provides an extensive 'bibliography.

.,

v

Page 5: Abpot .. White Collar.··Crime - National Criminal Justice ... This is Ci substantially revised version of the "~ckgrourrl Paper on White Collar Crime" (Shapiro 1976) which was prepared

."

.- -~- ~ -- -,-------~~---~

PREFACE

This is Ci substantially revised version of the "~ckgrourrl Paper on White Collar Crime" (Shapiro 1976) which was prepared about four years ago ~ for a multidisciplinary audience of researchers and facul~ involved in ~e Yale program in white oollar illegality research. Its P.ll::pose was to ass~st newconers to the area to think oonceptually and theoret~cally about wh~te collar crime ..

" During the intervening years, I have benefited from partic~pating in the groWth of the research program and lea:ned f~n ~e exper~ences. and insights of the researchers and faculty assoclated Wlth It. I have prof 1 ted as well f~ oontacts with dUtside researchers and officials that a program of this magnitooe' generates, and especially from the ~nnumerable lessons derived from designing, securing access, and conductlng research at a federal regulatory agency in oonnection with the research program. These insights and perspectives are reflected in this revised paper as are new conceptual, theoretical, or empirical developnents that anteceded the

~ original version.

This paper has t\«) parts: The first part explores the oonceptual history of white collar crime and proposes distinctions that might alleviate sare of the oonfusion that has plagued the usage of the term. The second part suggests a series of research questions and theoretiical issues concerned with the nature and social control of white oollar crime.

The paPer has benefited f~ comments and suggestions made by participants in the II Facul ty Seminar on White C?llar Crime ," at th7 Yale Law School in Februa~ 1976, and those .of Laura Shlll Schrager. _ Speclal thanks go to William Elliott, Diana Polise Garra, Jack Katz, Kenneth Mann, Albert J. Reiss, Jr., and Stanton Wheeler, for th~ir. oooments and for the stimulating intellectual environment they have ppovlded.

vii

-\ .- .-··.·~_',.""'-<.,"""' .... =-==.tQ,~~l-~'-.,.c"'~';.'':}·-::;,-~~·:::!'?::.7;:-:::;:.-:.::;·~~;;.:--~!:::', ".-::.':;:!"'::-" ~< ::;::;'<~":;'~::.; ... ':~..t<.:::;':>-">"., :,~r.~-""-:'~:.'-' '""~;: "" \

More than thirty-five years after the introduction of the expression "whi te collar crime" into the' criminological vernacular, the Deputy Attorney General of th.e United States in an address to professional criminologists rerr.arked on the diff,icul ty of defining the fhrase and Q'l the absence of any consistent or useful characterizations of such events (Tyler 1975, w. 1-2). This observation is, neither unique nor disputable. An examination of the various definitions, of "white oollar crime" and their actual usage in the literature yields fundamental inconsistencies and incompatibilities. It is unclear whether the term characterizes acts or actors, types of offenses or types of offenders; or, whether it refers to the social location of deviant behavior,. the social role or social status of the actor, t.'1e m::rlus operandi of the behavior,' or the social relationship of victim and offender. 'l11ere

c are frequent disputes over whether the phenomenon is necessarily "white collar, " and even mre serious disagreement over whether the behavior is criminal.. In this respect, the label is clearly a misoomer.

These fundamental confusions result f:rom the fact that "white ,. oollar crime" has always been a catch-all category for social theorists, policy analysts, and law enforcement officials. It has referred to that group of offenders (wealthy, respectable persons,' corporations, etc.) for wOOm traditional explanations of criminal behavior are not awropriate or to that group of offenses to which the criminal justice system responds differently -- if at all. 'llie categor:y - white oollar crime - generally has been used to demonstrate the inexxtpleteness of our kn::Mledge, the inadequacy of our theory, .or the injustice of our social oontrol responses. Indeed it is this programnatic function thctt has served as the glue to unite many disparate norms, persons, and social structures.. That the variance within the class of white. oollar crime often has been greater than that between categories of traditional crime and particular instances of white oollar crime has been ignored. The relevance of the oonstruct was its residual status and the polemical and ideological purposes Which its inherent contrast with traditional crime could serve. That this residual construct was multidimensional and its elements neither defined oor enlJl'lerated was oot treated as a problem. Indeed, Edwin Sutherland~ the father of the white collar crime concept, aanitted in his definitiOn of the· term that "this definition is arbitraty and not ver:y precise. It is oot necessa:r:y that it be precise, for the hypotheSis is that white oollar crime is identical in its general characteristics with other crime rather than different fI:Qn it" (Sutherland 1941, p. 1120).

White collar crime is not a lega,l catego~ inoorporating specific offenses. Rather, it is a social construct. The placelOOnt of its conceptual bourrlaries often reflects the social bouooaries of its users. Whether a social scientist, lawyer, law enforcement official, member of a regulatory agency, muckraker, business person, consllrier, or criminal, the fotmS of offense mst salient to one's experience vary. Even aIIOlg social scientists, it is mst likely that criminologists, organizational theorists, social psychologists, stratification theorists, political scientists, or econanists would differ in the criteria they oonsider central. A least

\

1

Page 6: Abpot .. White Collar.··Crime - National Criminal Justice ... This is Ci substantially revised version of the "~ckgrourrl Paper on White Collar Crime" (Shapiro 1976) which was prepared

'.

--",- -- ---,..--------~--~-' -- ,~-

OCllIIDn denominator that would capture this diversity of perspective would clearly lack depth and rooaning. <,

The appro~riate respon~~ to this situa~ion is a~oiding ~ue,atte~tion to the derivation of "such least COI'IIOOn dencxn~nators.. However, l.t ~s ne~ther the, abandonment of generalization in favor of cateritng to the parochial interests of users of the white collar crime ooncept. '!be developnent of theory or informed policy is dependent upon generalization and conparative irquiry. However, the real payoff in this area is ~ IOOve ,aw~y fran questions of definition and closer to concern for d~fferentlatlon ~nd analY$is. '1be significant question is rot whether two events are wh~te collar crlines, but instead whether they possess common elements that render insights useful in thinking about the other. For example, to the social psychologist: ~s information about, the lOOtivations of bank ~ller embezzlers illwninate research into the JtQtivations of oorporateoff~cers who embezzle or bank officers who are engaged in self-dealing or price-fixers? To the criminal investigator or prosecutor: Are ,d'!-ta, al::x;»ut the inves,t-igation and sanctioning of regulatory offenses by admlnlstratlve .~gencies useful in designing programs directed at oon artists, swindlers, or tax evadets?

The following discussion consiqers the definition and differentiation of white collar crimes. It summarii;es the major themes in the literature, presenting not only their strengths and weaknesses, but exte~ing and occcasi,nally redirecting them and reorganizing the thematic terra~n. '!be result of this exercise is rot a correct and definitive all-purpose ooncept of white collar crime. Rather, the intent is to help the reader corre to appreciate the distinctive elements of white collar crimes and to understand the limitations inherent in the selection of a particular definition.

Soc,ial Status and Social location Criteria

A legacy of alroost forty years of literature on white 0011ar, crime leaves us with essentially a single oonceptual theme and variations based on characteristics of the violator and his or her social location. This theme was expressed by Edwin Sutherlard as:

Social Status

& ... a crime oormri.tted by a person of respectability and high social status in the course of his occupation (1949a, p.9).

The social status distinction was critical to Sutherland, in that he created the concept as a challenge to popular crnninological theories of his day which attributed criminal lOOtivation to the assorted pathologies of poverty. By highlighting criminal activities oomnitted by the rore affluent, he was able to denonstrate the weakness of' those tlleories and ~'O argue J1Dre strongly for his own theory of differential associatioll. Although through the years, criminologists have abandoned theories based on poverty as principal explanations of criminal behavior, many have failed to abandon the link of social class characteristics to white collar crime. Twenty years after Sutherland, for exanple, an article in the International Enqyclopedia of the SOcial Sciences defined white collar crime as

2

\

"

"lawbreaking among the middle and upper (or 'white collar') socioeconomic classes" (Clinard 1968, ,p. 483).

There are· a nl.l11ber of Obvious problems in developing a category of deviant behaviyr on the basis of the social class characteristics of its perpetrators, sare of which im10lve matters of legal policy and equal ju~tice. '!be JOOst significant problems fr:om the perspective of social science theory, however, concern the ability of this criterion to meaningfully discriminate between disparate events at the same time that it discrnninates too ruch. .

Fran a theoretical perspective, the irnpoJ;'tance of social class, or other offender characteristics, for that matter, is rot that it defines a partiCUlar category of illegal behavior I but rather that it affects the nature and oont~l of that behavior. one ndght postulate that social class distinctions reflect differences in the opportunity for crnninal behavior as well as differences in the likelibood or severity of puni$tJnent. '!be-se ideas may be tested only where class is vari.able-,· where 1:X>tential differences can be contrasted between high ana low, socioeconomic groups. Where Sooial class is definitionally restricted, these propositiOl~C bec:.'ale assertions !.ather than testable theoretical stateroonts.

ThllS is not a bizzare or unreasonable criticism. In a related area, for e~am~llei' interest has centered on iJrq;x:>rtant· social class differences in the manifestation, labeling, and treatment of xoontal illness (see especially Hollingshe~ and Redlich 1958). Yet these works did not define emotional disturbances among the upper socioeconanic class as a particular form of mental illness - "Park Avenue mantal illnes-s.," for exanple. By allowing social class to vary across a populatiorr~of the mentally ill, researchers were able to stooy the impact or- social class on dimensions of roontal illness and its treabnent~c'>fnaddition, they were able to explore the interaction of cla~ffiar.a 'other independent variables Q'l these cases.

The social class standard, then, excludes too nuch~ at the sane time, it differentiates too little. It accooplishes little o-in the way of discriminating or isolating behavior. -!n:---t:heo'fy,--' if not in practice, affluent Wividuals are_capable of the same range of illegal activity as their llDre impoVerisHed counterparts - fmu l1llrder or rape, to illegal drug use, robbeIy', tax evasion, ellbezzlement, etc. Instead it separates forms of illegality that are virtually identical, as the exanples suggest, or that are structurally similar. J))es one want to definitionally discriminate, for example, between nedicaid fraoo by doctors and that engaged in.l::!i patients~ between the business executive who does not disclose perks, in his tax return am the waitress who fails to disclose tips Q'l her return? I:bes me take a single illegal activity reflecting the oon~iraqy of assorted individuals and label the activities of the wealthier participants white collar crime am those of the less weal thy traditional crime? If high status and lCM status persons OOll11\it the same crimes or: oonspire together in the ccmnission of a crime, what discrimination is achieved by the sooial status stamal:d? If it is the correlation of social status with other factors that are in tum oorrelated with categories of crime, then it. is Q'l

these latter factors that definition should center.

1 See especially Newman (1958) and Quinney {lS(4) for more elaborate critiques of social status criteria in Sutherland's work.

3

;.

~"

" '1

Page 7: Abpot .. White Collar.··Crime - National Criminal Justice ... This is Ci substantially revised version of the "~ckgrourrl Paper on White Collar Crime" (Shapiro 1976) which was prepared

•••• - •• '.' ., • 0-.> :._,":.

..

.~-- -,-------~-~-.~ - -

SOCial Location

~he' correlation between so.:::ial class and crirne is powerful jEor polamcalpurp::>ses 1 it is without merit for theoretical Plqx>5es Perhaps ih response to SOiOO of these criticisms, Sutherland awended t.l),e i:nra~ '''in t~ cour:se of his occupation" to his definition of white, collar crill1le, stlpulatlng n<:)t only the nature of the offender, but aiso the social location of the offending behavior. The social location criterion has been P<'!?ular, emplOYe<'3~ by many social sfientists, including those " who have reJected the sOC:lal class standard~ It stipulates that one' s offense occur i~ the occupational,. setting or when the offender is performing an occupatlonal role. .

, It is, unclear ,~fnat the users of this definition believe they have ~alned by lts ~dop,tlon. Presumably by including ally behavior that occurs 1n ,th~ occupatlo~cil setting, the defini tion na~s the range of criminal act1':"lty mst llkely to be encountered (excluding, for exanple, wife beatlng, bank robbe~, mass lll1~er). Perhap:;, because the setting suggests the arena of ec<?nc;>mlC tr~sactlons and exchange relationships 1 the users f~l t:I:ey have llJlllt~ thelr concept to economic or property crimes or ,the v1olatlon of regulatlons that apply to economic or business activity. Note, however: ' that those who employ the definition say nothing about the norma,tlve content of violations or characteristics of the. offense - they specify only social location.

Perhaps those who accept the social location standard are capitalizing on the f~c~ that focus on occupational settings permits scrutiny of unique ofPOrtHnlt~es and mea!ls. ?f. criminal, activity afforded by the roles, rela~:tonshlps, responslbliltles, and resources available in occupational ~ettlngs. ~e,street offers limited opportunities for potential sources of lncorre and llInted strategies to secute this inc::are. A business setting ~~v:r, affords diverse potential resclurces, an exteooed period of time ~ llll<?ltly secure them, and a variety Of technologies by which they can be obtalned. Hence, by focusing on business, ooe is enphasizing the unique oR?Qrtunities for criminal activity and the extent to which these o.H;X>rtunities affect the form of illeg~:llity that results. Unfortunately these specu~ations or other acoounts of the abstract benefits that accr~ fran center~ng analysis j.n, bus~ness settings. are rever expz:essed by its use~s. , 'lh1S urrloubtedly 1S hlghly desirable to many of them who can capl~llze ~ an intui~ive feeling of the criterion without having to speclfy wbat lS;.~!'f]Jlydi~tinctiv@'abc".lt, white ~J,~~crimes. ; .

Despite the belief J:hat distinctions based on social I;;~t:ion'ai(f;;ttDi;-e::,--- ", __ useful . th~ those refl~~~i~ SOCial. class, the social lOcation s~~ard . --., presents.; lts own ambl\)ll1tles. Fl.rst, what constitu~\~ a bona i' fide occupational location? Are positions in organi.zations tl\Ilat deale in the provision of illicit goods and services - prostitution, na~~cotics,;fences fc:>r the sale of stolen goods, distri~tors ~f pirated cOBies of ;/rootion plctures and ph0rt<?9:a~ records, o~ml1zed crl.Ille nembers ~';occllP9'fiooal? l>1any of these actlvltles are full tlrne, ongoing, Strulctured mechani,sns for providing a livelihood, in accordance with traditional definitions of occupation (see, for exanple, Form 1963, p .. 245).. Are they occ~tional

;

2 See, for example, Clinard ( 1952), Newman (1958), and Reckless ,(1973) •

4

where theeonduct of business is only partially illicit - the legitimate physician or pharmacist \.,ho also distributes narcotics or restricted drggs, or the fence, many of who~e goods were acquired legally (Klockars 1974)?3

Even when bona fide commodities of business are legal, confusion about the nature of a bona fide occupational, setting may rema.in. Business organizations. too. can serve as important resources for facilitating or covering uP' illegal activities. A major strategy in many confidencl~ games or other fraooulent schemes is the creation of a, corporation with a prestigious address, letted~ad, etc. which purports to provide SClIre

desirable service. Where only the rrost gullible victims would give rooney to a stranger on the street, many more sophisticated victims (including F'ortune 500 corporations) will seoo money to unkrx:Mn organizations. Hence, the organizational setting may simply provide a disguise to mask the true identity and intentiops of the individual offend~r. Do we consider these facades of occupational locations as ident~cal to more genuine settings?

Organizations are eaployed not only to facilitate illegality but to cover it up as well. Perhaps the clearest, but by ro rreansonly exanple, is the utilization of legitJmate businesses by organized, crime as fronts for illic,it transactions or as channelS for the lauderi~g of furrls. Are the cr~s of the mobster who manages a dry cleaning establishment as a front to be oonsidered identical with thOl3e of the llOt'e typical proprietor , and 'are both settings to be considered stages for the a:>nmissi<m of white collar crimes?

withOut ~ functio!)f,ll delineation of. what copstitute,s an occupational setting, the resulting defini tiOt'l of whi te ooll~:' crmte(.::becoroos extremely

.,. ~ '. '",

,.'

3 Sutherlana attempted to avoid tqis dilemma with his oonstraint that such persons be respectable. Presumably the embezzler.: is l1'Ore respecta1Jle than the but:glar, the food adulterer more respectable than the marijuana deale!-", etc. Sutherland does rot define the oonditions ·fOr respectability nor does . he suggest whether one be respectable before or after one' s illegal activity has been detected. Some would argue that respectability is a status oonferred on an individual by social definition and not easily stipulated in the .abstract. looeed, Ol''!e of the fascinating aspects of white collar crllninality is the different ability of offenders to retain respectability in the face of their behavior. HeM is it that a man convicted of illegal business praetlces is subsequently elected president of ti)e New York Clamber of Corrmarce (Sutherland 1948, p. 96)? HcJ..; is it th~t one politician charged with corruption is ruined politically, while the political advanceiOOnt (1:.f anqther is not ~ed (Farney 1978)? Ole man is ??,rhaps flDre respectable (or l1'Ore adept at managing his respect.­ability) than the other, but are they not roth white collar criminals'? Generally, in the the area of \l1bi te oollar crime, both respectability and legitnnacy are not objective c~racteristics of ~rsons or org~~izations~ rather they are a manipUlated status employed as a strategic device to consummate illegality. The utilization of such criteria for definitional purposes is thus quite problematic.

5

,

Page 8: Abpot .. White Collar.··Crime - National Criminal Justice ... This is Ci substantially revised version of the "~ckgrourrl Paper on White Collar Crime" (Shapiro 1976) which was prepared

,~,

broad', and incl~d'es many ,traditional street crimes, organized crimes, and victimless crimese ThU:; criterion may exclude crimes of passion or one-time illegal activities~ but it dOes little to distirt9uish ongoing forms of activity di.rected at generating illicit revenue-'S.

;,

"_" At th~ same time that ,this criterion iHgludes too much, it also_ excludes too much, specifiea:11y identical o£f~!1ses COIlI11.itted outside traditional occupational settings. On the one h~nd, there are illegal transactions that bind parties inside and outside of occl.;?ational roles. Is the ITOtorist whO pays a bribe to a traffi<;: po1i<;:eman. or meter maid a traditional criminal and the bribe recipient *,white collar criminal? on the other hand, there are activities that occur in business settings which ~lso occur outside them. Is the individual who p.lts a torch to 'his horoo in order to collect insurance benefits comni ttil19 a crime different from the arsonist ordered to baH out a foun:lering business org~ization? .. ,J:k:)es Q')e include fraooby the enp10yee in declarations for workman's c:onpensation, but exc1uoe that by the person seeking unenployment c~nsation or welfare? Does one inc1ude,ftatrl in the filing' ofoorporate income taxes, but exclude that involv~. irl-the og71ing of personal income taxes? '. Does one exclude a host of illegal activities wrpetratedby consumers, clients; beneficiaries, citizens, or' debtors because the~ parties are behaving outside" of 'Occupational settings where their activities have direct <punterpaftS in ·businesses? In short, is it the occupation per se that defines whi tecollar crllt'les, or is it. that ~~ ,,9Ccupation affords opportunities for illicitly ."~uring ecOl~1L.rP~~JU~~~;t:: saoo.,. of ,which may occur in oth~r sectors of social life?' " .

,. , Even if a solution to the bourrlaries of ,occupational settings were.

:fouoo, ,pmDigui ties about the scope of ~~t:.~y:~ties relElvailt~:',1':Ocwhtt€;"U)li~'! -::.:;"':' /~.jerifue"'-~uld still ar1seQ'Because tiHs defi.nition specifies social'location

rather than the norms breached, many<,traditiona1 forms of offense 't.Ould be included. Indeed, SUtherland consid(~red nuroercomnitted by a manufacturer: in the course of strike->breaking activities to be an instance of white. collar crime (1941, p.'112). where adtlltery is consider.ed a crime, extra-marital relationshi~ ~tween businesSmen and their secretaries would also be included in this definition of white oollar cr~e.

:,:, '

A wi~ range of offen~s can occur, ih occupational locations. In the si.J~ple case, one finds unanblcipqted oo~i(fcoffenses occurring in these locations because they ~vide the ptessures and opportunities for Vilt::t~ization or consensual crimes that are fouoo elsewhere in social life

,-- assaults" adultery, robbery, extortion, etc. Offenses of this nature can be rather easily disregarded in .;~efininq<'white oollar crime. However the diversity of offenses bas nore significant inplica,tions. On the me hand, one finds enployeesrealizing personal enrictJnent, at the expense of their employers. Such cases are illustrated bf embezzlement, pilferage, computer swindles, 'and even the expropriation of government furrls by po1iticans to carpensa~ special friends or family ,through salaIl' pa~nts for nonexistent liOrk. On the other ',harrl, one finds the enp1oyeewho utilizes hi$;-,--Qr;oo.~' position for personal enric~nt of a kind that does Jl:)t cost orbarm the enploying organization. '!his form of offense, or self-dealing, is illustrated by the corporate insider who p.lrchases or sells securities 00"

the basis of inside infot'1l\;1tion; the bureaucrat who accepts bribes fran seekers of licenses 'for' expeditious processing of awlications~ or the

6

- '.~.

.~ >'." ,

t;'estauranteur. who accepts gratuities from liquor conpanies forstoddng its brand. In the first example, the e-rployee expropriated sane of a fixed set of corporate resources whose benefit to the offender generated a comnensurate loss to the organizatiol1. In the second exampl~, resources, like information, power, oRJOrtunities" extra gratuities, are rot fixed in quantj. ty • These resources, generated"I::>Y organizational pasi tion ,may benefit the .. employee without any specifi-e:,or comnensurate loss" to the organization or to other parties. . In the language of game theory, the forrrer resources, fixed in quantity, are labeled: "zer~st.ml;" resources of the latter kind are l~beled "variable sulIf~" . '"

~,

..• ~,

Another kind of offense is derived from occupational role behavior WithOlltsare inawropriate or: illicit benefit accruing to personsi.'1 t.~ese positions -- fixing .prices, paying bribes, or falsifying t'ep::>rts,. for example. Finally, offenses can be characterized as providing enrichment to both, individu~l and organization. ExampJ.es of this latter f*lericxoonqp are somewhat nore obscure, _ but can include employees who are directed to fraoou1ently tout or maniPulate the stock of their conpany., enhancing' rot, only the economic status of the organization but their personal stock holdings as well. Employees who accept kickbacks or 7 other incentives for participating in activities required by the organization (for exanple, padding expense accounts J:o generate m:>nies for slush fUn:ls as well as for personal profit) are. a seeotld"exarrple.- =~"-'

Ambiguities inherent in utilizing soci.;l1cl,9F~tion as a defirl:itional criterion derive from two souxes: ('Irc'from-one's conception of what constitutes an awropriate social location, and (2) iron) me's oonception of

,2,,:."'",;'::·;C'-'C:::' what activities that occur in this location are awropriate for further

" . .:;.

'.' scrutiny. The latter ambiguity derives in part from the fact that, up to this point, conceptions of white collar crimes n?ve, been entirely individualistic, yet many of the Cornnon exa.'llples of white oollat""'cr-4.~c~~., inherently organizational. It is this very relationship of persons and--' organizations, in th~ oorrmission of illegalities, implicit, though not articu1C!ted by users" of the social location criterion, that provides the major insight about white collar crime derived from this Eerspective.

ThE¥ Role of OrganL::ations in Illegality

. Excessive co~ceF for individual. behavior in traditi~nal defin~ti0r:ts of \I,hl.te collar crlIlle has resulted 1n a neglect for 1tS organ1zatlonal dimension. As previous discussion has suggested, the organization is implicit in traditional definitions, but it enters through the back door-­through correlation to social location criteria. The DOle of ocganizations in illegality must be made explicit. Organizations 9enera1::ec new occasions for illegality, many of which are different ftom tt-aQitiona:). crimL~l

~c, 9R?Qrtunities. Fran -this c~tive, white "'{'Ollar crime ,pertains to th~ >

e~1?~~i~atiorlofthese owortunities, ~the_ ~c~~lt:-e 01: which is exp\ored in the foll~~\D9 parag.raph~.. -'<",,-

~-'1 ' ......

---.;..;'~;;.~~,,~~' -'~-~ ---' ~

4 Sare rece~f'~\;prk makes expli!;it ~ference tbthe role of o~~rzatioris:;' in illegality"(see, for examPle,Sqhr9.ger and Short 1978, Ermann and Lundman 1978b). These perspectives are examined~later in this paper.

. --

7

Page 9: Abpot .. White Collar.··Crime - National Criminal Justice ... This is Ci substantially revised version of the "~ckgrourrl Paper on White Collar Crime" (Shapiro 1976) which was prepared

.:::.. -.,. .. ~<:,:..> "

:. '. :'~

.::.r'

; " • j t $

First, a'ld most obviously, like th,eir individual oounterparts, organi­zations "serve as victims of crime. 5 l3ecause of their valuable reSources and ~eir relatively pel'1'lY:able boundaries, organizations provide easy and proiltable targets oftheft.8ecause many organizations are housed in public or semi-public places, ready access to outsiders is afforded. facili­tating shoplifting-type behavior. Access to organiZational resources rrust ~ afforded to, its various insiders - employees, agents, managers, d lrectors, consul,tants ,', -- "thu:; permi tting o~rtuni ties for thefts that involve embezzlement, pilferag~'/ or IlOre .indirectforrns, of theft such as ex .... pen~. account padding" or personal" u~e of organizational property'. ~por­tunl~les fo~ theft va~ across organlzatlons because of differences in p~ tectlng thel.r ~undarl.es, ~~e nature'of the resources available (conslJ1ler ~oods or. cash may be llOre vulnerable ,to, theft than sophisticated equipnent, lnformatlon, or services), the social OL"9anization of the work force and the amount of discretion over resources';vested in organizational ~les. None~eless, although the opportunities may, be g~ater, the thefts more profl~b~e! and the offenders of different bat;kgrounds when organizations are V'lctlJ1l1Zed, these illegalities do rot differ':in kind from those directed at ind~viduals, households, andotqer small grouPS~-f oollectivities.

second~ organizations increase opportunities for'~llne not 9n~y because of the expanded pcx>l of resources-c~o::mmoditigs avail~~rbut because of the ~co~of economic. transactions they ,ge~er~t~~~~~1\~e dev~!or;ment of

",c-:o~ganlzatlons as ecOnomlC actors has parallelec;:t.:.t.lie evolutlon from an econo­mlC system based on face-to-face transac'tions to a svstem in which the interaction bet~een buyer and sellei' Cly:'e mediated, by. agents, middlemen, attorneys, credlt compa.'1i~s, the mass media, applications, etc. '!his ex­pandeq scope of transactions has resulted in predominantly disembodied ~ransactions and social nebprks that intervene between participants. '!he lmpe:-sooal nat~r~ of tral1sactibns facilitates abuse. ,It ~rmits highly mis­leadlng advertlslng and promotional materials that characterize a oonsumer good, investment, charity, or other OOmnodity; to "buyers" who may be unable to 's...ae ~e "good ll or test the product. It also ~rmits misrepresentations by partl.es that ~1eek the services or benefits of an organization -- awli"': cants for governm=nt benefits, for insurance claims, for admission into

',graduate or professional'· schools, for bank loans. '!he possibilities of abuse are highly variable in these examples. '!hey are all characterized h~e!~r, hy si~\}.~~i5!!-~ _in which information RUst flow between the partie~ be'fore the, transaction car1",~~,~leted. Because of the physical, social,

. a~d temporal distance between part.~~$~ distortions of information Tl)aV be llkely anyway, but intentional distortioos--",;'3re facilitated.'Ibe chances for abu~e, the~, are inversel~~ related to the ~~tunities to test this infor­matlo~, whl.ch vary accordlngto~_~e nature of tfie"OOT!1l\CXUty, the nature of the dlstance,' and whether representat.l<:ns pertain to>-~,f~9L"ete or oontinuing events. ' "'- ".'

~::::.:

j .Third, organizations are rot sinply vast repositories of resources and settln~s forec~nomic ;transactions.Many organizations are highly dynamic eco~lc .ac.to.rs. '!hey,. create new comnodities and new opport;unities and the~r act~vltles have economic ~act. ~anizations may disseminate scarce

5 Indeed cthe ArnericanMana.gem;nt Association oonsiders "white collar cr~" as non-violent crimes against business (Sheridan 1975, p. 41). 'IblS concept awarently has sane SUppo'rt fron former u.s. Attorney , General Griffin Bell' (Bell 1978). '

8

resources: licenses, taxicab medallions, admission to professional schools, con,tracts for the purchase of goods, and bank loans. Furthel.TOC)re, they may restructure opportunities for others. Legislatures or administrative agencies, for exa.'1lple, through the passage of tax legislation, zoning provisions, tariffs and duties, may permit or destroy businesses subject to their actions. The decision of a large corporation to relocate its I;>usiness or enter a new line of business has an impact on other parties highly

·depenoent upon its activities.

This capacity of organizations to create or alter opportunities faci1itate~ other forms of abuse. Parties may seek to capitalize on ofPOrtuni ties created by organizational behavior. Where offenders are organizational insiders, such abuse is labeled self-dealing or oonflict of interest. Self-dealing is illustrated by bankers who extend generou~ loans or permit exhorbitant account overdrafts be themselves and associates or who uti~iztt' the bank IS oorrespondentacC()unts in other banks to secure personal loans; managers of large oorporations Who arrange organizational purchases and sales to oth~r oompanies in which they have a financial interest; the allocation of pension fund investments to risky Underworld or Las Vegas establishments in which pension fund trustees or their associates have a financial interest; or "the practice of "scalping" in which investment advisors ~commend that their clients purchase stock which they also hold, thus expecting their clients' purchases to awreciate the value of their 0Nn stock.

Abuses by persons outside of these organizations is labeled bribery or co~ruption. <Altsiders utilize positive or negative incentives to induce

"insiders to· direct allocations" or oH?Qrtunities to them. Bribes anel k~ckbacks are regularly paid to. goverruoont bu~aucrats of all kinds for "ficenses, permits, entitlements, cqntracts, and the like. '!he scandal in the u General Services Administration (GSA) is but one dramatic example. IhvestigatQ:'s discovered that large n~rs of GSA employees at all levels were receiving bribes and kickbacks in order to obtain contracts, to collect on worl( never perfQ~ and on merchandise ordered but never received (Hyatt 1978, "List"1S/78) :--.:.:':t;J3.!.lt such lOOnies also are paid to persons in private organizations ..:,;; ',to'~;-:~oan officers, ~school admisssion officers, to supermarket managers tp. stock and attractively shelve a particular product, to restauranteurs to stock a certain brand of beer, to purchasing agents, etc.

Abuse,s of organizational opport:unities differ from those discussed previously':'-", a quantifiable COI'IInCXiity was expropriated; a definable loss was generated; harm was rore apparent; victims \tlere nore easily specifiable in the abuses discussed earlier. '!he latter abuses, however, pertain rot to unauthorized expropriations of resources, but rather to the reasons for acting on fully authorized transactions or making self-serving decisions. It becomes difficult to specify harm or loss to the organization where the transactions were necessary, illicit or not-- instances,!or example where stooents had to be admitted, contracts made, goods purchased, licenses extended, and legislation passed. '!he difficulty of specifying 'harm, however, does rot ameliorate the presence of abuse. Parties explQit ~their relationships to organizations for personal gain. Because they are~Qle to secure enrictment without generating specifiable loss to the organization, they are p~ably better able to conceal their activities. '!he association

9

,

-(-

--, !

Page 10: Abpot .. White Collar.··Crime - National Criminal Justice ... This is Ci substantially revised version of the "~ckgrourrl Paper on White Collar Crime" (Shapiro 1976) which was prepared

between white collar crime and positions of power derives f~ this enhanced ability of offenders to exploit the dynamic features of an organization as they move up its hierarchy.

Fourth, the examples discussed so,far pertain to the abuse of oormal practices of organizations for personal or organizational enrichment. H~~ ever, as I19ted earlier, organizations may exist solely to facilitate or ,.cover-up illagal activities. Organizations provide pat·ties an entree to ~rticipate in transactions unavailable to individuals. '!hey can be created and dissolved at wil1~ their nature, sj.ze, and credentials easily manipulated. One example is the bankruptcy scam, in which an organization is created along with a credit rating. Merchandise, and supplies are purchased on credit and subsequently converted into cash. The business then claim.c; bankruptcy and the "operators" escape with the assets (DeFranco 1973) • Con games routinely are facilitated by organizations that do rot exist, or that perform a ron-existent service. Organizations, then, provide a legitimacy, a channel for transactions that otherwise ~uld rot occur. Organizations also p~vide the means of covering-up illegalities by circulating, laurrlering, and concealing furrls; masking personal identities; and diffusing responsibility for or knowledge of illegalities. -

Fifth, a final means by which organizations create or;portunities for illegality occurs at a different level than the previous examples~ Organizations are subject to specialized social norms, the violation of which constitutes illegality. The previous examples suggested opportunities for abuse given existing norms. 'Ibis section is concerned with the expansion of no~ and their content as they apply to organizations. Norms apply to the relationships between organizations -- those that p~tect cOHq?etition, that prohibit price-fixing, bid rigging, allocation of marketej" patent and copyright infringement, kickback and referral schemes between practitioners, etc. They concern the products of business activity -' their safety, morality, and necessary testing. 'Ibey pertain to the course of

d:msiness activities - safety conditions and benefits to employees: en~irorunental impact: equal oH;X>rtunity in recruitment, hi-ring, and prOhlotion of personnel. Because social systems generate special rorms that are idiosyncratic to organizations, organi~ations create oJ.=POrtuni ties for -illegality by generating norms capable of being broken~ ,.

In Sllllllllary, organizations create ofPOrtuni ties for illegal i ty (1) by serving as wealthy and t:elatively accessible victims; (2) by expanding the scope of transactional systems and generating impersonal transactions and their related forms or abuse; (3) by creating and allocating resources and oJ;POrtuni ties ,th~ exploi tation, of ~~.ich-is--desirable~ w""-orgariizatioociil insiders and outsidet"§3; ___ .(.4}--i:J!r-providing a strategic device to facilitate a~~ .... up-illegarities; and (5) by conditioning the developnent of new normative prescriptions capable of breach. Offenses may reflect the victimization of the organization by the individual, the exploitation of organizational opportunities'for individual enrichment, theoollaboration of organization and individual in illegality, or the breach of norms pertaining to organizational behavior by organizations and persons in organizational roles. In any case, organizations multiply the opportunities for violation, the strategies of offense, and the chances of cover-up. It is this new stage for the drama of violative activity that j,s iIIJplicit in social

·,location, and it is the drama itself that is the substance of white oollar l., • •

crlJlle.

10

Discriminating Offenses in organiz~tional Contexts

Differentiating Individuals, Organizations, and their SOcial locations

Perhaps it makes sense to choose as a prelimina~ criterion the stipulation that white collar illegalities occur in sane organizational context, _Cil.1;:hough this criterion is extremely general. It includes business

-aile1' .- riin.;,bUsiness settings. Violations that pertain to goverrunent, non-p~fitorganizations, associations, educational institutions, religious groups, and the like, would be included in this definition. FurtherrrDre, the stipulation does not require that the violation be made qy an organization or occur in an organizational role - only that· organizations be invol ved in the violative acti vi ty. '!bus, the case of the insurance company that defrauds consumers ~ p~ising non-existent benefits reflects white collar illegality. So too does the case of the policy holder' who defrauds the insurance corrpany by suanitting false claims for benefit. Organizations may be neither victim t~r violator, but simply the Imdiun for illegality ~ other parties. '!bis case may be illustrated by self-dealing, the utilization of org('mizational position to create or direct benefits tt, insiders at no direct oost to the organization. For exanple, in insidH\ trading, a corpOrate insider utilizes non-public information aboutoorporate prospects and plans derived fran his or her };:OSition to guide personal stock market investments. '!be victim in this case is the stockholder who traded with the insider without knowledge of this inside information.

Perhaps the only events oomoonly thought of as white oollar crimes that would be excluded ~ this standard are abuses that occur in face-to-face interactions between individuals -- ve~ simple con games, "consumer" type frau:ls in the sale of personal p~perty or illicit goods or services •. '!be cases included are enot'lOOUS, harlever, and further discrimination is essential. '!be JOOst oomnon theme in the literature teflects a· ooncern for differentiating the illegal activities of individuals and those of organizations, and the developnent of a strategy for separating these actors where illegality is embedded in organizational contexts. Generally, thea,e strategies consider either ~e beneficia~. of illegality ("cui boron) or· organizational goals. -

Enploying a "cui bono" perspective, users6 seek to determine the ultUnate beneficia~ of illegal activity, and generally divide these activities into categories of benefit, to the individual with concanitant harm to the organization (for exanple, embezzlement), and benefit to the organization irtespective of individual benefit(for-e~le, price-fixing). Clinard and Quinney (1973, p. 188) label the former "occupational crime" and the latter "corporate crime." Many of these users limit their analyses to corporate crime. '!bese distinctions do not specify whether differentiations are to be based on intended or actual beneficiaries. ' 'Ihis concern is not a frivolous onei the possibility of "unintended consequences of PUIPOSive social action" (Merton, 1936) BUst be considered. In any event, this criterion requires either a deep "psychological" p~file of law violators if intention is salient or an extended follow-up of violations if outcc::tre is salient, both rather cumbersome activities for definitional purposes.

6 See, for exanple, Hartung (1950), Bloch and Geis (1962), Clinard;' and Quinney (1973), Meier (l975).

11

\, ,

\

Page 11: Abpot .. White Collar.··Crime - National Criminal Justice ... This is Ci substantially revised version of the "~ckgrourrl Paper on White Collar Crime" (Shapiro 1976) which was prepared

'!he "cui bono" mtion is essentially an individualistic one~ it siIl1?ly sorts out individual behaviors according to their beneficiaries.· As Schrager and Short .ooted in their critique of white oollar crime theories, these theories "view the individual as a criminal agent, whether actions are undertaken on behalf of, outside of, or against organizations. Yet it is often tmpossiele to determine individual responsibility for illegal actions coomitted in accordance with the',operative goals of organizations" (1978, p. 408) @ '!he distinctiOn based on organizational goals, though related J:Q the concern for beneficiaries, examines the Organizational context in which illegal activity is located. '!he perspective shifts from a scrutinyo of individuals and oonsiders whether illegality has organizational sanction.

Schrager and Short define "organizational crimes" as "illegal acts of omission or comnission of an individual or group of individuals in a legit~te formal organization in accordance with the operative goals of the organization, which have a serious tilysical or economic impact on eaploYE*!s, consumers, or the general plblic" (1978, pp. 411-12). For p.lrposes of this discussion, the clause pertaining to impact can be ignored. '!he central canponents are the location of illegal behavior in a "legitimate formal organization" and behavior in accordance with "operative organizational goals. II .. An operational definition of legitimacy is extremely problematic, a matter discussed earlier. Nonetheless, this standard presumably would exclude illegalities comnitted in the context of a con game, where organizational facades are created to facilitate cr~s, or where organized crime or other illicit Qrganizations are involved. Also, the criterion concerned with operative goals presumably would exclude self-dealing activities of individuals which do not benefit the organization.

In a widely read IOOI'lOgrafh on white collar crime, Herbert Edelhertz (1970) specified four categories of offense: (1) "personal crimes" enacted by individuals on an ad hoc basis for personal gain in a mn-business context (i.e. tax fraud) ~ (2) "abuses of trust" enacted by persons in the course of their occupations in violation of their duty of loyal ty and fidelity to employer or client (i.e. embezzlement); (3) "business crimes" incidental to and in furtherance of business operations, but not their central p.lq:ose (i.e. anti trust) i and ( 4) "con games" or white oollar crimes which are the central activity of business (i.e. ponzi schemes) (1970, pp. 19-20). Figure 1 provides a more detailed list of exawples of these categories. '!be implicit distinctions uooerlying this typology follow directly from the elements._--O:r'the Schrager and Short definition,,7 concern for organ'lzational goals,·~on the one hand, and organizational legitimacy, Q'l

the other. 'IbeY.cBCfisider whether behavior is individual or organizational and whether oroot it occurs in a legitimate business setting.

; ,John Meyer (1972) enployed similar distinctions in specifying types of "occupational offenses." His categories, reminiscent of those proposed by Edelhertz, include "structural," "situational," and "ancillary". offenses, corresponding more or less ~: "bul;)iness crimes," "con games," ani a

7 Of course, the Edelhertz typology preceeded'the Schrager and Short definition by eight years. This observation pertains to similarity, not developmental sequence.

12

"

'.,

FIGURE 1

Categories of white .. collar crimes (Excluding organized crime)

A. Crimes by persons ol'erating on an individual I ad hoc basis

1. Purchase. on credit with no intention 10 pay. or purc:hues by mail in the name of mother.

2. Individual income tax violatioDl. 3. Credit card frauch. 4. Bankruptcy &auda. S. Tide 1I home improvement loan frauds. 6. Frauds with respect to social security, unemployment insurance, or welfare. 7. Unorganized or occasional frauds on insurance companies (theft, casualty,

health, etc.). 8, ViolatioDl of Federal Rt:.5erve EegYI~tioDlby pledging Itock for further pur­

chua, ftoutiDg margin requiremenu. 9. Unorganized "lonely hearts" appeal by mail.

B. Crimes in the course of their o'$Wpations by those operating inside business, Government, or other establishmentsl in Violation of their duty of loyalty and fidelity to employer or client

1. Commercia·) bribery and kickbacks, i.e., by and to buyen, insurance adjusters, contracting oftieen, quality inspecton, government inspectors and auditors, etc.

2. Bank .violatioDl by bank officers, employees, and directors. S. EmbezZlement or self-dealing by business or union officers and employeea. ... Securities fraud by insiders trading to their advantage by the use of special

knowledge, or causing their firms to take positions in the market to benefit themselve3. .

5. Employee petty larceny and expense account frauds. 6. Frauds by computer, causing unauthorized payoutl. 7. "Sweetheart contracts" entered into by union officen. 8. Embezzlement or self-dealing by attorney" tnute~ and fiduciariea. 9. Fraud againat the Government.

(4) Padding of paYTOlIs. (6) ConfliCti 01 interest. (I) Faile travel, expense, or per diem c:IaimL

C. Crimes incidental 10 and in furtherance 0/ business opera­tions~ but not the central purpose 0/ the business

1. Tax violatioDl. 2. Antitnllt violations. 3. Commercial bribery of another'. employee, oBicer or fiduciary (including union

08icera). 4. Food and drug viOlatioDl. 5. False weights and measures by retailers. 6. ViolatioDl of Truth·in.Lending Act by mi.representation of credit terms and ~~ .

7. Submiaion or publication of false financial .tatemenu to obtain credit. 8. Ule of fictitious or over-valued collateral. 9. Check-kiting to obtain operating capital on sbort tenn financing.

10. Securities Act violation., i.e. sale of non-registered securities, to obtain operat­iDs capital, {abe PRIXY ltalcme.nU. manipl,llatibQ or market to IUpport corporate credit 01" acceu to capital markets, etc:.

SOurce: Edelhertz (1970, pp. 73-75).

13

,

Page 12: Abpot .. White Collar.··Crime - National Criminal Justice ... This is Ci substantially revised version of the "~ckgrourrl Paper on White Collar Crime" (Shapiro 1976) which was prepared

-~-~-~----

-------'~.~ -

--~ -- -r-- --

11. Collusion between physicians and phannacilt. to caUIe the wriw.. of wmeces· ..., prescriptions.

12. Dispensing by phannacists in violation of law, excluding narcotica traffic. 13. Immigratian fraud in support of employment age~cyoperatioRl to provide

domestica. 14. Huusing code violations by landlord •. IS. Deceptive advertising. 16. Fraud against the Government:

(.) Faile claims. (6) Faile .tatements~

( I ) to induce contracts (2) AID fraud. (3) Housing frauds (4) SBA frauds, .uch as SBlCbootstrapping, selfdealing, cross-dealing,

etc., or obtaining direct loans by Ule of false financial ltatements. (e) Moving contracts in urban renewal.

1'1. Labor vinlationa (Davis.Bacon Act). 18. Commercial espiona,e.

D. White-collar crime as a business~ or as the central activity I. Medical or health' frauds. 2. Advance fee swindles. 3. Phony contests. 4. Bankruptcy fraud, including IChemes devised all llalvage operation after insol·

vency of otherwise legitimate businesses. S. Securities fraud·.and commodities fraud. 6. Chain referral IChemes. 7. Home improvement IChemes. 8. Debt consolidation IChemes. 9. Mortgage ailking.

10. Merchandise swindles: (.) Gun and coin swindles (II) General merchandise (e) Buying or pyramid clubl.

11. Land frauds. 12. DiJec:tory advertising schemes. 13. Charity andrelisioul frauds. 14. Penonal improvement schemes:

(a) DiplODla Y.illi (II) cOrrerpondence Schools (e) ModelinJ Schook,

15. Fraudulent appJ..it&tioD (crjP" aneIIor ale of credit cards, airline tickets, etc. 16. Intm'ance fraud. ..

(.) Phony accident rings. (6) Lootiq of t'.OCDpaniea by purdwe of over-va,luecl Ulets, phony manap.

men' contracts, lC1f-deallq with apnts, inter-company transfen, etc. (e) Frauds by qents writing false policiet to obtain advance commissionl. <d} lauance of annuities or paidup life wur.anc:e, with no consideration, 10

,hat they can be used as collateral for loana. (.) Sales by misrepre.entatioDl to military penonnel or thOle otherwile

uninsurable. ' 17. Vanity and lOng publilhin, schemet. 18. PoDli scheme.. 19. Fabe lCCurhy fraud., i.e. BiUy Sol Estes or De Aqelis type ICheJDeI. 20. Pun:hue of bankl, or control theJCQf, with deliberate intention to loot them. 21. Fraudulent C4tablilhinl and operation of haDb or aviDp and loan aaociatioRl. 22. Fraud apinst the Government

(lI) Orpnized income tax refund swindles, IQIDeUmea operated by income tax "counlelon." <") AID frauds. i.e. where totaly worthlea soods w'ppeci.

(e) F.H.A. frauda. (i) Obtaiaiq I'W'Ulteel of motplet on multiple family hoUling far in

excea of value of property with foraeeable iDevitable foreclOlUl'e. (2) Home improvement frauds.

23. Executive placement aDd employment qeney frauclll. 24. Coupon redemption lrauck. 25. Money on:ler IWindIeL

14

combination of "abuses of.· trust" and "personal crimes," respectively ( 1972, pp. 41-45). Meyer further differentiates structural offenses (i.e • "business crimes") on the basis of the hierarchical p::>sition of the offender in the organization, distinguishing executors, functionaries, and managers. 8

Although th~ terminology differs sooewbat between the v.orks cited above, the .underlying distinctions are very similar. They are reflected in the four-fold table below. As Table 1 indicates, these works vary in the· fineness of detail with which offenses are differentiated and in the subset of terms on which their attention focuses. All four, however, share the

BUSINESS COOTEXT

OON-BUSINESS COOTEXT

INDIVIOOAL OFFENSE

Table 1

II abuses of trus t" (HE) "occupational crime" (C&Q)

~ZATIOOAL OFFENSE

"business crimes" (HE) "organizational crimes" (S&S) "structural offenses" (JM) "corporate crime" (C&Q)

I- "ancillary offenses" (JM) -+--------------i

"personal crimes" (HE)

HE: Edelhertz (1970) JM: Meyer (1972)

"con games" (HE) "situational offenses" (JM)

S&S: Schrager and Sl}ort (1978) C&Q: Clinard and Quinney (1973)

8 When enacted by those low in the organizational hierarchy, usually in order to reduce the actor's inp,lt to the organization while maintaining his or her level of oorrpensation, tb.ese offenses are "executor offenses." They are ex~lified by the use of tl1e "tap" in an aircraft plant (Bensman and Gerver 1963). "Functionary offenses" are enacted by bureaucrats at the level of middle management, who, through ccx>rdinative responsibili­ties, have recourse to deviant activities that are functional to the organization. "Managerial offenses" are perpetrated by those atop the organizational hierarchy, whose purview spans· the interorganizational environment, and whose deviance can pertain both to endogenous and exogenous organizational systemg. The techniques of occupational crime involve c:orrpliant cooperation for the executor, coo~dination for the functionaty, and policymaking for the manager.

15

.~

, \

r ,

Page 13: Abpot .. White Collar.··Crime - National Criminal Justice ... This is Ci substantially revised version of the "~ckgrourrl Paper on White Collar Crime" (Shapiro 1976) which was prepared

\,\ \

·~--~---- --- ---~ ----- - -- - - -,

same distinguishing criteria, and therefore the consequences of the a~i~uities of these criteria. Earlier discussion considered the operational dlfflcu~ty as well as the p~lem of differentiating business from non-buslness contexts. Mditiohal p~lems with this typology concern its o:,er~ll ,di~criminator.:y ~er, on the one hand, and the difficulty of d~stwgulshlng the organlZatlonal goa)~s that lie at the heart of the dlfferences between individual and organizational '-:' offenses on the other hand.

At an intuitive level, the organizational goals criterion seems be be a useful one. However, what does it mean for behavior be be in accordance with operative organizational goals? Ina slightly different context, E~nn and Lundman (l978b) specified the conditions for organizational devlance. For deviant behavior to be attributed to the orqanizations in wh~ch it occu~s rather than to individual members, (1) the -activity rust "flnd support In the rorms of a given level or division of the organization" (p. , 57); (2,) the ac~i ~i ty must "be koown to and sup{X)rted by the dominant adm~nl~tra~lve coalltlon of the organization" (p. 57); and (3) "the soc1allzatlon of new members must include inculcation of norms and rationalizations supportive of such an action" (p. 58). In order to dete:mine wheth~r illic~t behavior is organizational, then, one mqst possess con~ld~rab~e lnformatlon about organizational rorms, orgarii:zational soclallzatlon, and the extent of krnvledge about that behavior across the organizational leadership hierarchy.

, B~t this is the very problem. '!he boundaries of organizational norms are lncredlbly unclear. Al though blatant, sustained embezzlement of substantial corporate funds may be clearly proscribed, the status of related offenses is considerably less clear~ The recent clamour over whether the charges leveled ~t fOrIIer u.s. Budget Dlrector Bert Lance related to the use of his position In several Georgia banks (including suggestions of over-draft privileges, use of the ~rporate plane for J?eI:sonal trips, creation of accounts at various banks ,W1t:b bank fuoos to enhance his personal ability to torrON' money, etc.) are wlthln the realm of "normal banking practice," is illustrative of the extent ~ which organizations are unclear about prohibitions related to self-deallng t the consequences of which may be harmful to these organizations (Horvitz 1977, IO.-1e 197,7, Mi~ler 1979a). It has been argued, for example, that some employers lntentlonally uooerpay their personnel because of expectations that ~ey will be compensated by pilferage and theft. ~resumably, then, pllferage is tolE!rated; it is its excesses that are lilegal.

. The co:rer-~p ,of il~egality is an, inherent qualitl' of the illegality 1 tself, makwg ~t mposslble to asc.:ertaln the extent of the knoWledge of and ~upport, for law-breaking within an organization. When persons engage in L~lega,llt~ ~res~bly for ~e benefit of the organization, the ability to flnd J~stlflcatlons for thelr behavior in same occupational cxx:1e is even less llkely. By the very nature of cover-up and the desire to spread responsi~ility for illegality, a rather corrplex network of delegation and obfuscatlon, or as Jack Katz (1979a) has suggested, "concerted ignorance II is 7onstru7ted to make ambiguous individual and corporate involvement in lilegallty~ ~ W?nders how it i~ possible operationally to discern whether such behavlor 1S In accordance Wlth organizational goals when no evidence exists that such behavior has been required.

16

One kind of criticism leveled at the typology, then, pertains to pro­blems of operationalization. A second criticism, reminiscent of that ap­plied to the use of social location as a definitional ODl1pOrtent, pertai,m;;:,to its discriminatory po.-ler. Examination here of problems of discrimination will concentrate on Edelhertz's work since it is the most explicit and the richest of the studies considered. One problem pertains to the extreme variation within each of his categories. Edelhertz's list of examples pre­sented in Figure 1 p~vides same evidence of this mix. Business crimes in­clude, for example, such disparate cases as tax and antitrust violations, commercial bribery, consumer fraud, fraud against the government or finan­cial institutions, and securities, housing cx:xje,and f<X>d and drug viola­tions. This problem can be remedied by adding additional standards to the criteria.

More troubling is the fact that the categories sometimes differentiate identical behavior. For example, both individuals and organiZations engage in tax violations or in misrepresentations in the application for credit and in,surance or the qualification for benefits and services, and presumably for the same reasons. Yet these activities are l~ated along the diagonals of Table 1: "personal crimes" versus "business crimes." Distinctions between "business crimes" and "con games" may be nore imagined than real. Except for the fact that the former have achievt:~d sane actual or contrived institu­tional legitimacy, many' offenses occu't"t'ing in roth contexts are identical. Differences may be a matter of degree in the extent of IIfalsi ty" of mis­representation~, but are not necessarily a matter of kind.

Similar.ly, the behavior of individuais may rot differ in kind when they move f~ non-business to business contexts. Individuals are involved in a variety of social networks and relationships outside of their occupation which p~vide similar opportunities for abuse. Individuals who serve as trustees, for example, have many of the same opportunities for embezzlement as those who serve as employees. Individuals toth in and out of business often assert their eligibility for particular benefits, and do 9V by misrep­resenting their status. '!be employee pads his or her e>fpense account or falsifies the ntmbers of hours worked1 the individual lies on his or her tax return, application for welfare, food stamps, or insurance COI'I'q?ensation. If one compares same of the other pairs of cells in Table 1, similar overlaps could be noted.

Characteristics of Behavior

Consideration of the social context of illegality -- whether individual or organizational, business or ron-business - provides iIrportant insights about the structure and opportunities for law-breaking. However, because this criterion refers to the setting of illegality rather than the nature of violative behavior, it serves as a rather confusing distinction. ~ was noted, it includes a range of disparate activities yet elccludes sane that are virtually identical to same of those listed. That is so because social context and violative behavior are correlated -- certain behaviors are mere­or less likely in certain settings than in others -- but there is no abso­lute association of behavior and context. Since, presumably, white oollar crime is a category of behavior, definitions that refer to social context at best can be app~xtmations. In retrospect, it seems patently obvious that defini tions of a behavior should oonsider elements or dimensions of 1::.'1is behavior. . SUch attenpts are ODRplicated by the absence of a rormative or legal definition ,of white collar crime and the difficulty of deriving a

17

---

Page 14: Abpot .. White Collar.··Crime - National Criminal Justice ... This is Ci substantially revised version of the "~ckgrourrl Paper on White Collar Crime" (Shapiro 1976) which was prepared

'J - - ---------~

,',

least comnon denominator for so many disparate events.

, Qec~tion and concealment. Conceptibnsof white collar crime concernerl ~lth char~ct;rist~cs of ~e ,il~egal activities themselves are rarely f~d 1n the lltezoature. A slgnlflcant exception is the definition of whitE.\ collar crime Proposed by Herbert Edelhertz:9 '

• • • an illegal act or series of illegal acts ~umitted by oonphysical aeans and by ooncealment and guile, to obtain money or property, to avoid pa:yment or loss of money or property, or to cbtain business or personal advantage. (1970, p. 3)10

What is c,ritical about this idea is that it pe!"tains to the natur.e of illegal, activi~ies. and. t:?eir methods of operation. '!he category of ~ite collar ll1egal1ty 1S ll1Tl1ted by characteristics of the aeans by which they are executed: nonphysical methods, concealment, and guile.

Edelhertz further refines his discussion h¥ suggesting that white collar crimes have tine following elements:

(a)

(b) (c) (d)

(e)

Intent to commit a wrongful act or to achieve a purpose inconsis­tent with law or public policy. Disguise of purpose or intent. Reliance by perpetrator on ignorance or carelessness of victim. Acquiescence by victlin in what he believes to be the true nature and content of the transaction. Concealment of crime by -(1) Preventing the victim from realizing that he has

been victimized, or (2) Relying on the fact that only a small percentage

of victins will react ,to what has happened, am making pr<Ovisions for restitution to or other handling of the disgruntled victim, or

(3) Creation of a deceptive facade to disguise the true nature of what has occurred (1970, p.12).

The "co~cea~nt and guile" criteria are reflected in two of these ele- __ _ ments: (b) d1sgu1se of purpose and (e) ooncealment of the violation. Dis­guise of purpose "pertains to the character of the Offender I s conduct or activity in implementing h.~,s plan" (1977, p.22). Concealment of the viola­tion, on the other ha:nd~ occurs after the corrmission of a crime, to

~.

,/ I

/' /

9 The di~tin~tions attributed to Edelh.e~fz in the previous ssction reflec­ted . C~l ~erla he ProIX?sed, to diffe~rentiate the ];heraoona captured by his defln1tlon. '!hese cr1ter1a are i'lQt- themselves elements of his definition.

10 Two related defini tions aJ)("kede that proposed by Edelhertz. Ogren (1973, p. 59) considers wh~~~ collar crime as "a broad range of oon-vio­lent offenses and offende~J' where cheating, dishonesty, ,or corruption are the ~ntralelements." '!he working definition of the U.S. Deparbnent of J~tl~ incl~es ". • • ,c~asses of ron-viOlent illegal activities which pr1nc1pal~y lnv?lve, tradltlonal notions of deceipt, deception, conceal­ment, man1pulatlon, breach of trust, subterfuge or illegal circl.lnVentionfl (Civiletti, 1978, pp. 1-2).

18

" ,

i'

!

f I,

r _

"-',,/

--- II

.: .....

. " •• :-;:~:: •• .J' ·~~,:'C·~""'_';::'!~·.,,;:-:\::_"·_!:.z:-;::..,-, ;; l' .!."r .. ,.JC .,:

.- :.,' .";.

.7'" •. ~/ .-

ooverup either its recognition as Wr<Ongful activity or the identity of the perpetrators, whether tenporarily or permanently (1977, p. 24-26~. Disguise, then, relates to the inplemenb:tion or cona~tion o~ a c;ime, lt is "part of the manner and aeans by Wh1Ch the fraoo 1S OOfllnltted (1977, p.26). Concealment pertairi~ to activity separate fran and generally subsequent to that central to inplementati?n. Edelher~ ro~s ~at often disguise and ooncE~alment overlap, partlcularly where v1olatlons are continuing, since e:ontinued irilplementation requil'C'es maintenance, of the facade of respectability, but he is careful to treat t.~ese, event:s as distinct. He furthe:c ootes that the importance, degi.."'ee of attent10n to, al1d SOFPistication of dil3guise versus ooncealment vary by crime.

Herein lies th~ problem" Although it may be the case that ooncea~nt is, a rather COI1I'IlOrl or in fad: universal element of white oollar crl11le according to Edelhertz (1977, p. 24), disguise is rot nearly as COfII1\OI1l', Where the structure (:>f illegal activity involves direct transactions between offenders and victi~ as in cases of fraud, disguise is a critical element to secure the participation of the victim. However t there are a large nlJ'l\ber of crimes that require 00 direct interactions with vict~. ,~ese crimes may include bri~ry, corruption, kickback sc:hemes, pr~ce-f~xlng, bid-riggin~l, and the like. For these offenses, the l.IlIplementat.10n ~s, rot disguised. '!here if; a general candor about, the na~ure of pr1ce-~lx1~g, kickbacks,or uribe agreements between collud1ng part1es. Indeed, d1.sgul.se of the fUrp,')S'"~, of trcmsaction wouldoprobably result, in failu;r:e i:? oons~:e it. '!he cormu.ssion of many regulatory offenses 1S mt d1sgul,sed. e~th:1.-' particularly when vit:>lation reflects evasion rather:. than scm affumatlve action - failure to file reports, to register, to meet safety or envirol'llOOntal standards-, etc. For illegal transactic?os of these .. kinds, decepti«(,n is neceEisary in the cover-up, oot m the stages of inpleroorltation.

In a Ioc>re intE!rroodiate category, one finds offenses reflected in,. ' embezzl~nt or self-dealing in which the offender's position in ,an' organization provides access to oomoodi~ies wi~~t inter~ction .Wi~:;9ther parties. An embezzlement does have ~ d1r~t V1Ctl;l1l' ~e o-cganz1.:~,~Ion, but if it can be conmitted without any dl.rect 1Oteract1on w1th ot:h,e:c· enployees, disguise may be umecessary. '!he need for disguise ,is:~,yaria.ble in this context. It depends on the organizational positi~,of' the offender, the degree of his or her interdependence with other ~~l., and "the nature of the oonroodity "expropriated'i' or "errployed" fo~;par~~l use. , lior per~s at the top of organizational hierarchies, pl~cing one's ~~ 1.n the t~ll ~y suffice as a strategy of inplenentatioJl .... At l~r POSltlon~, ~ d1~U1se may be recessary. For eXaq;>le, ra~t than slmply expropr1~tlng m:x'l1es, a clerical employee of the U.s. J3epartment of Transportatlon had checks intended for the Atlanta subtaTay system issued to himself (~inson 1;977). Bank loan officers may create fictitious individuals to whan bank fuoos are purportedly directed as, a l1'eans of expropriating t:.l1eSe fuoos. In order: to inplE!!lent these offenses, then, disguise was necessary. ~re ~e desl.red catiOOdity is oot a spc--cified and control1ec:.3 quantl.ty, d1SgU1S~ mar be unnecessary. Self~ealing may pertain to the abuse .of. org~lZatl.~l information fO);" personal profit, for exanple. ~n ~ 1OS1der .J?vests 10 prope~ty en the basis of krotIledge of future organ1zat1.<;>nal, e~s~on, he or she pUrcr.ases this property at the price requested. D1sg~lse lS 1rr:elevant sinoehe or she is engaging in a ~sumably legal transactlon.

19

,

Page 15: Abpot .. White Collar.··Crime - National Criminal Justice ... This is Ci substantially revised version of the "~ckgrourrl Paper on White Collar Crime" (Shapiro 1976) which was prepared

4 ; a a

::;. _. In other words, for SOIre forms of offense, d isguise,,'!IaY be a necessary conditi,on'9~ implementing a crime~ for olbers, it may be unnecessary; and for still others, the necessity of disguise may vary by characteristics of .~ '" the offender an~ theroumodity involved. Hence~ if analysis pertains"tl11y' to implementation behavior, ,only a subset of the 9ffenses captured by Edelhertz's definition would be 'subject to inclusion. Sat,_that causes us to examin.e. a critical assumption of 'his'-at'.grnnent that "ooncealinent; of the crime itsel~~ f~ the victif~~ well as from j{a$t~~forcement agencie's~·,is always an obJectlve of the whlt~col1ar offender as we:1l~"as an element of the crime itself" .[Edelhertz'l s enphasis1 (1977, p. 24). Ci~arly ~re this assLmlPtion not val1d, the offenses that lacked disguise in, inplementation might be excluded from his definition of white oollar crime. .

~:~. <.{-.,~:.~;\,~.;J'?>~;~::' ~ ' ...... ~

The ubiquity of cover-up>-;i)f'-~*,l-l~ality is an enpirical question, however. Clearly the degree (if rot the'''1ia~~sity) of rover-up activity is variable. Where the offense is ongoing or where-~the likelihood of detection ~s h~gh, there may be oonsiderable attention given'::J;o oover-up.. One might lmaglne, hCMever, that tax offenders in a 1 percent auqit category would be less likely to cover up their violations than those::~Tl" a 91 percent category, if aooit probabilities were known. looeed, given'9:rm-1:.j.nf~equency of social control responses to illegality, cover-up simply may b9·-a~.';wstJ.y. and unnecessary extravagance. '!be likelihood of detecting violation and/or '""><.-,.,,

irrposing sanctions on detected violations, even without any ooncealment, may be too low • Schrager and Short describe, for example, the case of a construction COIt'pany whichfailoo to shore a trench, in violatiol'l of the law, resul ting in the death of an errployee. In this case, prior to the ' accident, Occupational Safety and Health Administration (OOHA) inspectors 11 not only observed the trench; they allowed work to oontinue without the refl10val of· .the hazard" (1978, p. 409). For a variety of regulatory violations, eSp@cially, concealment may be absent, either because of the unlikelihood of enfQJ;:'cement or because of -the naivete of offenders who are unaware that their behavior oon$titutes a violation. . .. ,

As one explores more fully the ambigui tks inherent in the Edelhertz defini tion while at the same time awraising the forms of behavior he suggests it inc~udes, essentially' three types of violation can be <:bserved: fraud, self-deti:l~T a ... ~d °mgul~tOl:yof£eri~s ,::' neceptton: isinherenn-Lq ctbe, frau:] category~ it is rot a' necessary' ~ent of self-dealing or regulatory violations. All three types of violation have the potential for concealment or oover-up - cover-up activities are inpxtant (Xxrponents of the offenses, but not distinguishing features. As ideal types, these offense categories are separate and distinct. In actual practice, illegal behavior may include oornbinations of all three kinds of violation.

Fraud. 'Ibe category of fraoo is perhaps the clearest. It involves the use of deception, the misrepresentation of status!,_experiences, <X>JrIilCXjities, or future events for the purpose of divert:ing economic assets fran the receivers of misrepresented infonnation to lts sources.. '!he exanples are

:> diverse, including oon games, benefits fraoo (eligibility for welfare, food stamps, insurance), oonsl.Jlter"" fraoo, misleading advertising, sedurities fram, misrepresentat;i.ons of qualifications and credentials for enployment or educational aanission, fraoo in scientific research, misrepresenil:ations in re};Orting to 'regulatory agencies (tax returns, "corporate data to the Securitie,s and Exchange Ccmnission [SEC] ,'drug test results to the FooCI and

"

20

l'if

Drug Administration [FDA] )', misrepresen~tions in aw1ications for bank l?Ms or credit, expense account padding, and the like~ ;:BOth offenders and v~ctims can be individ~als or organizations, bUSinesses, gov~rnmental units; or consumers. EFaud may be enacted by organizational, insiders, as in expense account padding; by those desirous of becoming insiders, as 'in ,,f~c:iooulent resumes ahd aWlications for employment or educational admission; or-by-=tho~~ outside of organizationaL conte~ts, as in oonsumer fraud.

'.~ Misrepresentat-io.f~s~ ~y pertain" to the past, present or future.. They may ''',~eflect transactlons'<°bas~.d on entitlercent to benefits because of status or

@St"",experiepce, ba~ on ~cekpectat!.ons of future events cin an inves'tment contextf"-."gr based on more cont:e@:fatY'c.--ex.q~nges of goods and services., They may pe"-'~lemented tbl:'Ough oral or wri tten"nel11'lS; or through the use of phYSical equipneht,,_,- props, 'actors, Ot' oost\J1\eS. Centraltb these o:ffenses is the fact that wiflwut,the dec:eption;-'~'the~lUpj,~ transaction pr'€a!....tmably wou.l.d rot be OOnSUI111f1ated. -'~,,-'.._- --, ~- .

-;e' ~.. "'';~~",,, '~<" -. -I '~. "0":;

=",,, , Self-dealing and corluPtion .. """ile<..bat~orY~f self-dealing is sanewh;t broader. It reflects the ORJOrtuni ties affordectjn organizational 'i~si tions to expropriate reS9Urces. In a "SOCiety in whicI1mQst assets are in the physical };Osse,§sion ,of or readily available to its o..mers,~-tney can only be expropriated by forGe or deception.' Where custoqyof propertY is diverted tonon-own~rs (agents -, enployees , fiduciaries, physical or technOlogical storage) in our organizational society,' and where organizations have the capacity to increase assets (i.e. they are 00 longer finite or "zero-sum"),

-;<:-s-~WQ~iation is po,ssible without either force or deception. '!he central distin9Ui~~jng_ feature of these offenses is the location of Offenders in., fiduciary posiltioos::.:;::(,~I!~erpreted broadly)ll vis ~ vis organizat~ons or rel~tionsllips, and tI1Ef"~e~~1.9itetion of these positions for Personal enrI.chnent. 'Ibe: prototypical exafif>1es.'""Q;,,9ffenses ,in this category arEt errbezzlernent, PlIferage, and errployee thef8';c>,;;:~lleypertain to the expropriation of corcmodities that are specifiable aita~£nte~:b:.JIJ, quantity, whose gain to the fiduciary oonstitutes a loss to other parties.<~::'>',~;:;::::::.-".

':; " ............

However, the exploitatiorl:i:Qf fi:9uciary or insider J;X>Sition~ may cpertain to other than finite conmodities. -':;:»It may involve the bprrowing of organizational property forpersanqJ. use ( i .e ~ use of the oorPorate plane for private vacations, utilization '·'o~ corporate enpl~~s for maintenance worK. on ,one's hale, or the unauthdrj.zed use of a"client's stock as

.. c:ollateral on personal loans). 'C It may i"~'lVolve the exploitation of corporate ot:POrtunit4~,~-te._,!hebenefit of . insiders 'Without oost to the organization­preferential trea1:ineftt'{ir'k~temJ..p.SJ,~~:J.5.??Q!::;,j.n J;Unishing deviance, . in admissions to educatiQ~l institutiOiiSr; 'direcn:ihgc~organizat~9nCll expenditures or allocations 'to ,corporations in which . insiders have- ari'-"":'>:::-, inerest (investment 01; union pension funis-' 'in establishments in which

If In legal terminology , "fiduciaryll has very specific coili1otatioris. Here it is used rrore broadly to refer to the need for trust and delegation of responsibility in the creation of insider positions in organizations and relationships. Entrusted roles"-"-4phere ,in various locations ;in- organizational hierarchies - fz:an watcnnenan..d guards to _ secretaries, managers ,corporate' off icers and directors. Al.b'1ough the~-'

. fiduciary position is described as an individual role, there is nOthing to preclude the classification of groups and organizations as fidu­ciaries - i.e. boards of directors, law or accounting fimB, etc.

21

,,;-

Page 16: Abpot .. White Collar.··Crime - National Criminal Justice ... This is Ci substantially revised version of the "~ckgrourrl Paper on White Collar Crime" (Shapiro 1976) which was prepared

trustees hold an interest, selling lanG! or supplies O:tmed by insilikiltrs"to their organization), ',' directing organizational ,{:blicymaking to sU};PJrt interests of insiders' (creating favorablezoning~for properties th~y ~;td), and exploiting info~tion for perSonal\advC!!llU!9'e (i.e. insi~r trading in the stock market). '"

The previous eXanPle~,,pertain to self-dealing or oonflicts of interest. Where insiders direct asset.$ and ofPC)rtuni ties of this sort to outsiders because of incentives they .. are offered, the_ac!:~~.rities.,,~~~_~!~l~~~.~,> "corruption. II typically, th~? label has been' -ut'i'llzed ---to' aR;>ly to fiduciaries vested with p,lblie, trust - political official:;, police officers, etc. - but corruption QCcurs in situations of private trust as well. 'n1e acti vi ties of insiders a1~e 00 different here than in the case of self-dealing" -- they 'still steal, bprrow, and manipulate organizational oR?Qrtunities:: and allocations. 11hedifference ~s that in the case. of corruption, the econanic incentives to insiders derive, not fran the value of the 'organizational opportUnities and ,resources, but rather fran the payments of outsiders for directing' organizational reS9Urces to them. Payments may take the form of direct; RDnetary bribes, canpaign 6ontributions, kickbacks, gifts, alcohol, &:'xual favors, entertainment and vacations, promises of enpl9YJ!lent for inlsiders, or their associates, investment q:p>rtunities in outside enterpri.ses, invitations to participate in the illicit activities, or the pranise of business to other "enterprises in which the insider holds ,an ihterest.

~.:~ The, occasions for corrupting insiders and the fonll of corruption may

vary. Outsiders may corrupt insiders for fixed "zero-sum" organizational resources (as in sate sophisticated theft arrangement), but JOOSt seek "varial;>l~sun" resources - organizational opportunities, information, and the like~~":)Irducements nay be paid to insiders to speed up, give priority to, or ~n sane other way facilitate a legitimate transactiori that would be carpleted eventually without the bribe. , Inducements of this kind are labeled "speed" or "g:mase" money or "tra~ction" bribes (Reisman 1979). In oontrast, "variance" bribes (Reisman 1979) request insideEs to adjust the performance Qf their JQbs in favor of the interests of ,,,outsiders. Pef~ce may pertain bo the allocation of commodities (referring ,broadly to the dispensation or aQqUisition of goods, services, or erititleman€Sl~ tp the c,:ea~ion of new ~tunities (changing legislation, 'creation o~" government <p1.'OgI'aRLS J , 07: to the obstruction 'of social control ( fixing , tickets, buying judges, t.anpering with juries, buying off police, etc.). In the latter case, briber.y may be preventive - social control personnel may be regularly provided with gratuities to forestall any future sanctions -or reacti ve ~ indu~nts are Pf:OVided to fix a particular ca$e. In all corruPtion-cOntexts, bribetY may>be-pe~nt or episcxUc. '!be "outright

>pu~base bribe" (Reisnan 1979) "buysw the"-insi~F" and aligns his or her loyalties' with outsiders rather than insidersfortb~_ ,first and all subsequent transactions. other variance bribes may' inv61ve"Cl'-'~singl~.~ c,

transaction.

cOrruption acti vi ties nultiply the offender pool fran the single per­son, gIOUp, or organization engaging in self-dealing to the oollusion of two or nore such entities, and generally expand the social locations fran which offerders operate.. '!be activities of outsiders who participate in oorrup­tionaredUfferent ftan those of insiders, but they constitute law violations and are subject to prosecution as ~ll.

22

.'~., -.

-Ii - .. '

'!here fore , a:lthough they share comnon elements, self-dealing and oor-,C",C ruption are rather differen.t events. Furthermore, it is likely that

insiders who participate in self-dealing are different from those engaged in corruption with regard to fIOtivation and organizational position. On'1e might expect substantial differences, forexanple, in the rootivations of the embezzler and corrupt legislator for engaging in illegality. One might also expt."Ct that the orgfll').~i.ttionalc1?Ositlons of participants in the t\«) kinds of offense~",w:>ulddrff~r I> 0 Insiders part~icipatin.g in cqrruption roos!: likely

":,.<.o"'<o.,-..::,,,"WOf,tia Occupy "bouooary spcuming" or "output" roles, which link' organiiation , and'o,c.envlrOQment (ThatpsQ'n, .1962). '!hey roost likely have allocative,

discret.ionary, or policymakingroles. On the average, they may occupy sarewhatlower positions in organizational hierarchies than their counterparts who engage ~J~.,self-dealing. In any event, it is recessary to

,'distinguish between insl:ders engaged in self-dealing and those involved in corruption. But the fact that they are both instances of the roore genera;!" phenamen~i of~sider self-dealing should not be ignored.

Regulatory offem.les. Otber offenses that frequently\i:~ar in ~e white collar crime literature are rather different from those oofIsigered m the categories of fre/LId and self-dealing. '!he fact of exploitation:'~jther thz:c>ugh deCeption, insider position, or the p.lrchase of insider positib.1.?~ irmerent in fraud, self-dealing, and corruption, respectively, is not appli~>.:, cable to these offe.nses. 'Ihese teoo to be ·regulatory offenses-:;. the ,vio-, ",::~ , lation of administ7:ative regulations, J:.ypically by evasioh,ifiatpertain to the conduct of business, the uSe of public facilities, or the obligations of citizenship .. " Such rules pertain tp the payment of taxes; lic~nsing and registration of' organizations, professionals, equipnent," securities issuances, and the responsibilities of registrants~ the cOnditions of enployment (concerning hours, wages, safety, and discrimination) ~ the relatiofishp between organizations and their environment with regard to pollution, ra.diation, etc.; the relationship between organizations themselves with regard to antitrust, bid-rigging, ~~ferral SC~~Si and the like.

Regulatory offenses do not invol~e'~ropriation. '!hey may increase the econanic resources of the violator since the cost of oontinuing regular conduct is typically lower by virtue of the evasion of regulatory require­ments. But the norms fran which these activi1:i~s deviate are rather different fran those discharged by misrepresentations ,_and, self-dealing. Absent their comnon quality of pertai!)ing to ~enanena othe,r than expropriation, ha-lever, these nonns and the behaviors to which theY-eawly 'are dive:rse and bear no necessary relationship to each' other. "

These offenses share a <::X:ll11OOn label by default, oot by theoretical ~ -'.; sign. For those who seek to examine offenscsof this kind-, greater dis­crimination between kinds of violative behavior :is necessary. 'Ibis paper does, not provide those cri teJ;"ia. l2 Qneo pOir,lt DUst be errphasized,

~ ... ,_. ___ :;, ... :~_-_-{;t._ - .o·::,:::-_~;c-:"_'· --~

12 One attempt that' might be useful differentiates fOI'Il5 of organiza ... tional deviance (many of' which would oonstitute regulatory violation~\ in our usage) in terms of the social categories of its victinS~, ('Epnann and Lurdnan 1978b). Victim categories inclUde organizational \': (If''<participants, (2) owners, (3) its p.Iblic-in-oontact, and (4) the ~:\ publ ic-:at-,Jarge. '!be corresponding 0 types .,ofdevic31i\;.~· are-~(l.)!,J;g-Etakdown c, \ -. ~

l~~

23

--,

Page 17: Abpot .. White Collar.··Crime - National Criminal Justice ... This is Ci substantially revised version of the "~ckgrourrl Paper on White Collar Crime" (Shapiro 1976) which was prepared

"

.-----------......,...-..,.--.------..pa---------------------------~~~~~~--~--~,.

J._ ..... _~~:;::, '~ ... --..-

however. Although they are not speci(ied, these criteria pertain to norms, not to the source of the laws or location of the corresponding enforcement responsibility.. This categoty is not cotenninous with Internal Revenue Service (IRS), Envirorunental protection Agency (EPA), <EllA, ~'~, SEC, e~c. violations. For t.'1e prescriptions of regulatory ~:1es prov~de ofPOrtuni ties for fraoo and self-dealin~ as ~ll.. one can file a fra~ulent incClllE tax return and generate conslderable lncane. one Ccyl flle a fraudulent registration statenent with the SEC which can re~u~~. in the ~ successful distribution of stocks }jy_,._~irtue of_ .the credlblllty-c th~ ~ registration generated'~ Liceh~t~6r reglst.ratiOl? with regulatory agencies can provide the badge of legl tllllaCY tha~ coi!t..r~butes to th7 success of otherwise unclledible or disreputable organlzatlons~ ,'!hey provlde resources for con g~~; they allC7tl the creation of fiduciary relationships which can be utilized for embezzlenent. Furthermore, they generate.new systemc:; of public and private social control ~~ inspection which provide new opportunities for oorruption~

, For these reasons, one' firXIs that illegal scheInes based on fraoo ~~'1d s~lf-dealing also involve separate ~.l.l~tory violatio~s. ~t ~ rust differentiate these offenses ---=t:.lJe '"1~1 tImate co~ratlon wl'llC~ falls to register with the SEC and the considerably less legltImate one whlCh emplO¥s a highly misleading prospectus to market its securities; the factory that fails to abide by '~EPA standards i~ .~,~ its emissions and the factory that fraudulently claims carpliance with EPA standards and crldi1::ionally.files for tax breaks··'for the installation of nonexistent antipollutlon deVlces. '!he former examples reflect regulatory violations exclusively, the latter couple regulatory violations with fraud.

Additional Distinctions. '!he categories suggested here begin to highlight some of the distinctive featut~s of "white colla:" crime offe~ses based upon normative criteria and characteristics of the lilegal behav7or. However, these three categories - fraoo, self-dealing/corruptlon, regulatory offenses - are extrerely large, encanpassing very disparate forms of behavior. '!he'additional criteria selected to discrllninate events in these categories should reflect the theoretical or policy interests of the user. To make these selections in the abstract would generate a typology of little value to the user who'~ld find some categories nuch too refined and others far too inclusive. '!his section, therefore, suggests classes of standard':; that Hlay be useful for some typological efforts. '!ht::se

. classes consider ·the nature of the offender, the oomnodity subject to abuse, the offending behavior, and victUnization.

A variety of distinctions pertaining to the nature of the offender may. be important to the user. '!hey consider the number of of~end,er:s, whether they are individuals, organizations I or both. Where ,11'1<h vlduals . are involved, their social or organizational role - custod~a~, managerlal,

. allocative, policymaking, fiduciary, socia! control, beneflclaty' - may be

of internal due process;" (2) "Loss of financial viability," (3) nbetrayal of wlnerable actors," and (4). "erosion of external con~rol, or socially disfunctional output," respectlvely (p. 61) • FollC7tllng from this rather general and absract typology, one might further specify the kinds of behaviors that pertain to the different categories.

24

distinguished as well as their bureaucratic or hierarchical position if their association with organizations is relevant to the illegality. Where offenders are organizations, distinctions about the type of organization -­whether government, business, service, non-profit, mutual benefit, etc. -­may be useful. For roth individuals and organizations, sane of the standard sociological variables may be useful distinguishin,g features -­social class, age, sex, race, education, and recidivism for the formeq and age, size, organizational structure, financial condition, market characteristics, recidivism, etc. for the latter.

Perha~ more valuable than information about the social type of offending organization is some sense for the organizational context in which violation occurs, that aspect of organizational behavior subject to abuse. By focusing en the organizational function involved with resource acquisition, for example, one could construct a category that would include the scandal in the C~neral Services Administration as well as the bribes and kickbacks paid to restauranteurs by liquor companies. Oentering on entitlement demands on organizations might generate a category that includes welfare, tax, insurance, and expense account fraud. Instead of concentrating on the type of organization itself, then, one might consider the kinds of transactions engaged in ~ various types of organzations.

A related concern suggests differences. based upon the cOmnodity transacted for: Is it money, material goods, se:t;Vices, ronds or securities, interest or dividends, information, assurances of future property or services, or government authorization or licensing? Is the commodity nzero-slllil~ .Qr "variable-sunn? l))es it reflect a past, present, or future event?

Distinctions based u.pon the nat~re of the offense consider the methods of deception or technology used in the violation - do they involve forgery, accounttng-irJ:e9ulari ti.es, conputer manipulations, social perfonnances, or mass Iredlaadtjert-t'Si~ Are~p~Sei"l~tions ~"emipUedll_<:>r '~gJs~iedn~ do they include face-to-face~\;;t...*(I!!llnication between victlln and offender? How many offenders are involved andhcw~aJ:'~ they organized in the execution of illegality? Are offenses discrete in tlnle1",-one-shot violative episooes, or cOntinuing over time? Do offenses include actlv~~ies~lated to concealment and cover-up?' ....... _'-..._.

Finally, does the offense involve specifiable victims? How many are there; hC7tl are t:bey distributed over physical space? Did victims knOw~ch other prior to vict~ization? Was there a prior ~elationship between victL~ and offender? What is their present relationsh:Lp - is the offender a stranger? fiduciary? empl~ee? beneficia~1r?13 Are victims aware that they have been vict~ized? '

13 Offenses by organizations have been separatedi6>"~rms of the social categories of their victims, whether organizationar:';;~r,~icipants, owners, its public-in-contact, or the public-at-large (Ermanil':iIJ1drnrdman, 1978b, p. 61). ~

25

--~

,

..

Page 18: Abpot .. White Collar.··Crime - National Criminal Justice ... This is Ci substantially revised version of the "~ckgrourrl Paper on White Collar Crime" (Shapiro 1976) which was prepared

1

-':

...

The Issue of Crllni~lity 'f".,;

pc

A final theme in the conceptual histor:y of white oollar crime ooncems the oontinuing cont~versy over the criminal status of white collar offenses. It has been disputed because:

• the detection and p~secution of white collar offenders are rarely centered within traditional criminal justice agencies, bUt rrore c.xmnonly are dealt with in administrative agencies (Caldwell 1958, Tawan 1947, Newman 1958, Kadish 1963, Kwan 1971, Clinard and Quinney 1973, Mannheim 1965);

• of the infrequent imposition of criminal sanctions (Ne\'Mlan 1958, Kadish 1963, Clinard and Quinney 1973h

• of the inability top~ve intent or the irrelevance of intent (Newman 1958, Kwan 1971, Clinard and Quinney 1973);

• of the absence of p.Jblic ItDral outrage or judgement of the acts as rrorally reprehensible (Burgess 1950,. Ne~ 1958, Kadish 1963); .

• white collar offenders neither think of themselves nor are caunonly thought of as criminals (Newman 1958, Burgess 1950, Mannhelln 1963);

• of the incongruity of society's respectable nernbers being its criminals (VoId 1958);

• white collar crimes tend to be crimes created by legislative bodies (mala p~hibita), rather than natural crimes (mala in se) (Ne\omIan 1958, Gibbons 1973, Bloch and Geis 1962, Kwan 1971, Geis and Edelhertz 1973); an:]

• white collar offenses involve acts which have been outlawed "overnight," and are indeed not easily distinguishable f~ acceptable business practice (Burgess 1950, Kadish 1963, Ball and Friedman 1965).

The cont~versy has centered around conflicting definitions and intet:pretations of the rreaning of the tenn "crime," and an occasional attempt, as Aubert observed, "to interpI:et the question of whether white collar crimes are crimes or not as a research problem and give an affitma­tive answer as if it were a significant result of his stlx:ties" (1952, p. 264). .

SUtherland was insistent in his assertion that white collar crime was ill'Jeed crime. For him, it was necessar:y to equate whi~ oollar offenses with oore traditional categori~!S of crime to argue sliccessfully for the in­adequacy of current explanations of crime which relied on the poverty and social pathology of the offender and for the utility of his theor:y of dif­ferential association. For these less polemical purposes, white oollar of­fenses need not be crimes as a definitional assertion. Indeed, such an assertion weights the concept with an assor~nt of unnecessar:y baggage, and 1 imi ts 'b'1a breadth of the subsequent enterprise.

26

.......... >·_'W~ __ "''''._J'-~ ~!><~~~ ....... ~t~!i:t=~~,: .• :;;:':t;~.;~"",~W<'",,,--,,:--,,

-

I' I ~

L t, ~ -I

k.

f; ", r,: .;.~

;.; !:~ ·F " ;'! t·'

;

,

~

; ~

l~ r',

..

... ~ ~'. 8.-, ,

, i ! ..

. " - .:". ? '1", --'. ,,,"," \

~~--~~~----

Assume that the criteria of crime implicit in the objections enumerated above were incorporated b¥ definition so that it were possible to isolate a set of offenses embraced by Sutherland's (or sane other) definition which were "purely ~iminal" -- fraoo, embezzlement, and bribery, perhaps. To do so, ,WOUld def~ne away one of ,the richest and most interesting of the thea­ret1c~l,ques~10ns posed by wtllte oollar offenses. '!he designation of an act as cr~lnal' 1S much rrore than a definitional activity; it is a social and normat1ve enterprise. It highlights the process of social valuation and social stigma, the allocation of legal resources to one oormative breach rather than another, ~ the "political" interplay of social interest groups and power constellat10ns.14 It also reflects, especially in the 'white collar area, the histor:y of the regulator:y process, and the fortuitous and :a~er~diosyncratic deve~opment of administrative agencies charged with ad­Jud1cat1on of a large varlety of offenses. The theoretical richness of the uncertainty of the criminal sanction has been stated quite aptly by Aubert:

For purposes of theoretical analysis, it is of prime importance to develop and apply concepts which preserve and emphasize the ambiguous nature of the white-collar crimes and not to "solve" the problem by classifying them as either "crimes" or "not crimes. " Their oontroversial nature is exactly what makes them so interesting fran a sociological point of view and what gives us a clue to important norm conflicts, clashing group interests, and maybe incipient social change. One main 'benefit to be derived fran the study of white-collar crimes springs f~ the opportunity which the ambivalence in the citizen, in the businessman, and among lawyers, judges and even criminologists offers as a barometer of structural conflicts and change potential in the larger social system of which they and the white-collar crimes are parts (1952, p. 266).

It is the position of this paper that the definitional dispute over the cr~i~l designation of white coH"ar. offenses is trivial and arbitrar:y. ~h1~ 1S ~t to ~uggest that the criticism of Suthe~land is not legitUnate; 1 t 1S smply Inlsplaced and sterile as currently directed. Rather, the cont~versy suggests quite interesting and significant ooncerns for social theo~, social policy, and social philosq:tly, sane of which are discussed later.

I suggest the adoption of the alternative label "white oollar offenses" or "illegalities,,15 - activities which violate the proscriptions or

14 See Ball and Friedman (1965) for ~ excellent discussion of the oon­ditions for "criminalization" in American legal histor:y.

15 This notion is oot without precedent. Edelhertz (1970, p. 3) Sll1\l­l<;lrly emplOY~, ~e tenn "illegal" to av?id the question of "whet:her par­t1cular actlv1tles should be the subJect of criminal prescriptions." Spencer (1975, p. 238) considered white oollar crime to include "para­crimin~l" as well as criminal behavior.

~27

Page 19: Abpot .. White Collar.··Crime - National Criminal Justice ... This is Ci substantially revised version of the "~ckgrourrl Paper on White Collar Crime" (Shapiro 1976) which was prepared

'j

$ a ;:a

fail to observe the prescriptions of law.16 White oollar "crime" categorically reflects that subset. of offenses which carry criminal sanctions and means of enforcement; sPecific "white oollar crimes" reflect those instances of violative behavior within these subsets for which 'criminal enforcement remedies are actually awlied. '!he criminal designation of law, its enactment, H:s sanctions, etc. are oonsidered problematic rather than definitionally fixed in this view. For p.1rposes of research, one might wish to focus only on offenses which carty criminal penalties and are p~secuted ~ traditional criminal justice agencies. But for purposes of ·theoretical,development, the occasional use of the criminal enforcement roodel must be recognized. 'Ibis can be done only where the category of offenses under inquiry include m::>re than the violations for which this TOOdel was imposed.

16 Indeed, one might prefer even llDre . general conceptual oonstraints, stipulating white collar offenses as nOrmative violations and allowing the invocation of the law as a mechanism of social control to remain problematic. .

28

....... ~ .•.. - .. -,.'----, -~----______ .,~~ .... \P"ttf'Mi ..... ::; - .. ~,,~.~.-.-., •.

II. A RESEARCH AGENDA 00 toJlUTE OOLLAR ILLEGALITY AND rrs CCNl'ROL

The COItPlex of social organizations and social relationships encap:;ulated by the phenomenon of white oollar crime is truly a microcosm of the larger social world in which it is embedded. A mnber of rich and fascinating questions can be posed about aspects of this miniature sOcial world, derived from all of the social science and· rormative disciplines. Certainly sate of these questions are ITOre relevant than others, and sane better exploit the distinctive features of white oollar c~il1les as a focus for the refinement and enricl'lllent of one's understanding of the larger soc ial 'l«>rld.

The following discussion suggests same of the questions ~licit in a deviance and social control perspective. It directs attention first to white collar illegality itself, examining the forms and patterns of violations, their social "location," and the social characteristics of offenders. Topics central to a social control perspective, concerning societal values· and the development of norms pertaining to white oollar offenses, the enforcement of these oorrns, and the disposition and sanctioning of illegal behavior, are also explored. For each of these topics, the need for description as well as explanation is oonsidered •.

The Nature, Organization, and Social Location of White COllar Illegality

This general g~up of topics pertains to variability in the social structure and social location of white collar crime. It oonsiders the types and form of white collar illegality and seeks to account for the distribution of variable forrrs across time and space.

The Form and Social Organization of White Collar Ill~ali~ -----

The stooy of crime and deviant behavior has been~ negl igent, particularly in recent years, in its lack of attention to the form and social organization of criminal activit~'. We kIXM a great deal about criminals and aOOut the official response to them, but very little about the activity itself (Wheeler 1976). '!his is generally true of the study of white collar cr~ as well. A number of journalistically-oriented ethnographies of particular white collar crimes or scandals are available (see, for example, Smith 1961, Herling 1962, Miller 1964, Barmash 1972, Kwitny 1973, Dirks and Gross 1974, Hutchison 1974, Farr 1975, McClintick 1977, Shaplen 1978) • '!he concern for prevention of oorpprate victimization from white collar cr~ and for beefing up the detection and prosecution of these crimes has resul ted in the development of descriptive pol icy manuals directed to the structure and tell-tale signs of white collar crime (see, for example, Chamber of COmnerce of the United States 1974, Edelhertz 19?7, National District Attorneys Association 1975). But between the exceSS1ve generality and superficiality of the descriptiva manuals and the fine detail of the ethnograIhies of rotorious crimes is a deep chasm that reeds to be filled. .

" The richness of detail regarding the developnental sequence of the

offense, the characteristics and social organization of offeooers and victims, the Ileans of executing the illegality; the 6:xrpc:nents of associated

29

-., \

" \

Page 20: Abpot .. White Collar.··Crime - National Criminal Justice ... This is Ci substantially revised version of the "~ckgrourrl Paper on White Collar Crime" (Shapiro 1976) which was prepared

• p

cover-up act~vities, t;he ~pact and, ~gnitude of the offense, etc. available from th:se e~nograpllles 1S tantallz1ng. But these characterizations rust be eX~lned W1th the caveat that the ethnographies by and targe reflect no~rlOUs, precedent ~tting offenses - Equity Fundings, salad Oil SW1ndles, General Electr1c price-fixing conspiracies, Iockheed scandals __ rather than more ty;pic~l ~ffen~s. Because of the unusual sample that these examples reflect, lt 1S 1.I11pOsslble to use them either to characterize the offenses they illustrate or for oa~arative analyses between offenses

o

Ther~ is a need for research, then, that generates detailed chara~te~lzations of a variety of different white oollaroffenses. '!hese descr1Ptl<;>oS would reflect a roore representative sample of offenses than character1ze ll'Ost of the studies available at the present time. Furthennore, the research would be comparative ~ design. Data pertaining to the same ~et of variables would be oollected for each offense. It would then be poss1ble to get SOIre sense of the typical characteristics as well as the range, of characteristics for particular kinds of offenses and to contrast dlfferent offenses on the basis of these characteristics. It would be useful to have data b¥ offense pertaining to questions such as:

• what kinds of illegali~ were involved? • when did the offense begin, and where was it located? • what was the duration of the offense? • how many offenders were there? • what are the characteristics am social £X)sition of the

offenders? • are there enumerable victims, and txM many? • what are the characteristics of the victims? • how were v~ct~ recruited? w~ ~ere vict~precipitation? • were the V1ct1mS aware of the1r v1ctnnization? • what were the nethods of the offense? • was there a oover-up, and if so, what did it entail? • what is an estimate of the amount of llOney involved in the

violation or some other indicator of har.m or ,impact? • were there other violations associated with the offense -- i.e.

tax fraud, mail fraoo, regulatory violations, etc.?

This proposal ignores two critical issues. First, a problem evaded in the first part of this paper returns to haunt us: How are white oollar offen~s t? ~ d~fined, and differentiated? Without an answer to this questlon, lt 1S lInpOssible to develop a research design. However' any r:asonabl¥ ~flective arbitraJ:Y decision is adequate, as long as rul~s of d1ffer7nt1at1on are relat~vely precise and oonsistent. Second, given the secret1ve ~ture ofwh1te oollar illegalities, the fact that their occurrence 1S often successfully ooncealed f1Xl1l victims, social control agencies, and hence, researchers~ how does one construct a sample of o~fenses? ,If the population of offenses is inherently unknowable, what b1ases ar7 .1ntroduced ~ pa~ticular sanpling designs? As in the study of street crJ.m.~, for example, 1t may be necessary to utilize samples based on Off7nse~ kncwn to,social control agencies or based on victnnization surveys (~1<?h, 1n the wh1te collar area do not yet exist). Either stategy has slgn1f1cant methodological p~lems which must be addressed if not surmounted. '

30

t

t \ r. 1

.

"

r\

:~

" ,

;

,~

~i "

f" 1"/ r k 1f '" . ~-':

F ! 1

F t t r l. r , \, " ~\

I f. r-r ~ .

f 1(-' )'

f \ " I ~

r' t r· ~ (--. 1 ' I ! t

, f. f ! '. ,

L ~'L

! L·

V k " F

,.

AI though the data collection describe¢! here should be Lltil ized for theoretical questions about the causes and correlates of white collar crime, they are useful as well in the examination of the social organization of white collar offenses. HCM do offenses vary in their extent of harm or impact, as shown in the number of victnns and extent of rronetary harm? I))

offenses vary in duration or in the physical or social distance they encompass? Do they differ in the number of offenders and abettors participating in the viola_t.i,~Il'?, HCM do offender characteristics -- class, age.,- race, educatiqr.?:!_;p..,~f~s~'ional eX,£?erience, r;ocial position, recidivism -- vary by offense?' - t:b offenses differ in characteristics of victim.s - in social class, economic sophistication, prior victimization, in victim­precipitation, and in their awareness of having been victimized? I))

different methods of offense -- mass media advertising, oral representa­tions, professional communications, pros,£?ectuses and formal disclosures -­attract different kinds of victims? What is the relationship between offense and oover-up? Are cover-ups more likely for some violations than others, and do particular kinds of offenses have distinctive cover-up styles and strategies?

HCM about the relationship between offenses? I)) different offenses typically occur simultaneously ~ the same cast of characters because of the requirarents of facilitating a particular schem.e? tb different offenses occur sequentially, either because of the offenses implicit in attempts to cover-up prior violation, because certain kinds of "professional" white collar offenders typically move from one type of offense to another, or because certain violations create new opportunities for abuse (i.e. payment of bribes or the creation of slush fUMs that become eilsy targets for embezzlement)? What kinds of offenses rarely occur together?

The Social Location of White Collar Illegality

Perhaps the most interesting research in this area concerns the social location or pattern of particular kinds of white oollar offense. It questions the location of offenses over tune and physical space, and within particular sets of offenders, vict~, and kinds of transactions. One might examine, for example, when price-fixing conspiracies are roost likely to occur; where they are most likely to occur; in what kinds of industries or organizational envirorurents they are roost likely to be found; and what type of individuals or persons in which occupational roles are roost likely to participate. The same kinds of questions oould be posed for'any number of offenses -- securities fraud, tax fraud, bribery of public officials, etc. 'Some questions might be more interesting than others for particular kinds of offenses. Regional variation may be significant for political corruption, but less so for tax fraud. Rates of price-fixing may vary oonsiderably over time and by industry, but rates of sec uri ties fraud may oot. Personal characteristics may be significant predictors of embezzlement or participation in a confidence swindle, but may be of no consequence in predicting individual participation in price-fixing or in the payment of bribes. These differences derive, of course, from the fact that the causes and correlates of white collar crime vary ~ type of offense3

The theoretical issues implicit in interest in social location are almost entirely unexplored in 'the literature. With regard to chronological questions, there have been a few superficial global attempts at developing a

31

,

'.'

Page 21: Abpot .. White Collar.··Crime - National Criminal Justice ... This is Ci substantially revised version of the "~ckgrourrl Paper on White Collar Crime" (Shapiro 1976) which was prepared

4 •

historical perspective on white collar crime. For example, Edelhertz has suggested that the rrKXIernization of the social and economic environment -the Wl:!akening of marketing safeguards, the developnent of a "faceless trans­actional environment," the J10re frequent economic exchanges between stran­gers, the expansion of business organh.a.tions, the growing reliance on fi­duciaries, the rapid developnent of new technologies, new developnents in marketing, distribution, and investment - has resulted in an increased rate of white collar crime and has fostered new forms of illegality (1970, W. 5-8) •

Former Deputy Attorney General Harold TYler has noted that there is a definite oorrelation between the "state of the econOfilY" and types of white collar crime. He suggests that during recessionary economic periods, highly speculative investment schemes and mortgage oomnitment rackets proliferate (1975, W. 15-16). HOi/ever, more specific research, for example, on cycles of white collar crime, its relationship to econOmic, political, or social change of specific kinds can rot be fouoo~ .

Concern for the physical, geographical or cultural patterns' of white collar crbne is evidenced b¥ a wealth of cross~national and cross­jurisdictional research, particularly with regard to p:>l,itical oorruption (see Heidenhe~r 1970, for example). But the oomparativerichness of this research unfortunately has been umerplayed. Explanations for the spatial distribution of white collar illegalities are incredibly naive -- based on assumptions of the ubiquity of particular events, stereotypes about regional culture or political machinery, or the geographic distribution of commodities subject to abuse (i.e. land frauds in the south or mining frauds in the northwest and southwest). Conparative research is potentially so rich, especially where the effects of political ideology (socialist versus capitalist), political c~ganization, economic development, urbanization, the distribution·· of .industries, the nature of the interorganizational environment (competition and monopoly), or substantive legal and regulatory differences can be systematically examined. Research that is rot only comparative in outcome, but also comparative in theoretical design should be initiated.

The literature that has focused on individual and organizational characteristics in patterns of white collar illegality has invoked "ItOtivational" explanations for white collar criminal behavior almost exclusively.' Where offenders are individuals, social status, mobility, family backgrourrl, rationalization (Levens 1964, Spencer 1965, Bromberg 1965), nonshareable problems (Cressey 1953), business as oH;X>sed to professional orientations (Quinney 1963), differential treatment urrler the law and perceptions of fairness (Ball 1960), differential association and varying exposure to norms, values, and criminal techniques (Sutherland 1949a, Clinard 1952) purportedly are related to participation in various white collar offenses. Very little research has been conducted on the social psychology of victims and their notivations for participating in activities that eventuate in white collar illegality. '!he "motivational" explanations applied to organizations tend to have ~licit concern for the econanic fortune and constraints upon business organizations - the "munificence" or "scarcity" of environments (staw and Szwajakowski 1975), elasticity of demand (Leonard and Weber 1970), shortages or ooncentration of

32

..

supply (Leonard and Weber 1970, Katona 1945), and the dema!lds, and cOsts of compliance with regulatory procedures (New York, Knapp ColllnJ.sSl.on 1973).

Most of these explanations pertain to particular kir:d~ of offe~se (embezzlement, antitrust, bribery) or are based on v,ery llJTIl.ted, rese<;tr<;:h populations (orisoners, notorious persons, corporatlons on ~hlCh c~vll penalties Wl:!r; imposed). '!berefore, t11ey are l,imit;-d and, req\.ure cautlOus interpretation. Fu'Cther \<K)rk cor:lcerned ,wit.l1 ~tlvatlonal 1ssues for_J~rF~s and organizations that participate 1n Wh1 te collar offe~ses must De concerned with designing research based upon more represen~tlve samp1e~ of ofrer.ders and non-offenders and with a concern for oomparatl.ve exp1anatl,ons across offenses.

Despite these difficulties, analyses that utilize irnplicit,rrotivatior:al theories to explain the variety of locations ?f white oollar ,crlJTIe and Whl te collar offenders are relatively oommon. It 1S <;:learly poss1ble, though, to bracket motivational predispositions for analytlcal f\ltJ?Oses: a$~ume they are constant or fixed according to s;ome formula. Glven , the, ract that perhaps all or some proportion of persons and organl.~at1.ons would participate in white collar illegality, they d? S<? at dlffer(tnt , rates because of differences in ofPQrtunity. '!be POSS1.bll1.ty <;>f tax evas1.o~ or tax fram is r,educed in a system in which most SC?urces of mcome are, subJect to withholding procedures. Systems of oo-fa,ul,t msu!-"ance generate dl.fferent probabilities of insurance fraud than tradltl.Onal msurance syst~. 'lbe opportunities for embezzlement, self-dealing, ar:d oo;ruption, ~e dlff:rent for persons who work within organizations 1.n h1.ghly v1.sl.ble~ h:ghly supervised locations than for those who work alone ~n, orga,rll.zatlonal boundaries - contrast, for,. exarrple, bank tellers at tl'le1.r wmdows and police officers walking their ,beats (Sh:rmar: 1976, p. ~9). In short" the structure of organization, 1.nterorgan1.zat1.onal relat1.ons~ ,transact1.o~l systems, and the like facilitate or inhibit the ?pportunltleS ,for wh1.te collar crline. Research concerned with the explorat1.on o~ th~se dl.fferenc:s __ of the impact of organizational design or the o~gan~zat1on, of €C<;>nom1C transactions on rates of violation and on the execut10n and rnan1.festat1.on of illegality -- is needed.

A proposal for researen .in this area unfortunately suffers from the b of a tunnlt'V1U of white collar illegalities that differentiates

a sence :J.r- '-":JJ. f th' t'on Such off~nses on the basis of the structure 0 elr execu 1. • distinctions would be useful, since oH;X>rtuni tie~ for: abuse reflect ~~ organization of behavior subject to abuse. '1111S • ~ln? of r:s~arch ~i':' illustrated with examples of a few structurally dl.stlnct whl.te collar offenses: collusion, bribery, embezzlement, and fraudulent abuse of beneficiary systems.

One may question how characteristics of the organization and the relationship of potential colluders facil~~te their awar~ness of a nutually beneficial arrangement and their opportun1t1.eS to oommun1cate (for example, in price-fixing, bid-rigging, or referral schemes) ~ ~n ~e co~text of antitrust, Hay and Kelley (1974) suggest that CX)Qrdl.l~at1.on. ~s eaS1.er, ~d hence collusion oore likely, where the nl.l1\ber of fUTlS 1S small, the~r co~centration high, and the ptoduct in question hcmJgeneous. 'Ibey ~so indicate that industry structure is related to t,l-te. type of collus~on involved. Where there are a, large nl.l1\be:r of ~t1. tors and where the

33

-.... ~,

,

Page 22: Abpot .. White Collar.··Crime - National Criminal Justice ... This is Ci substantially revised version of the "~ckgrourrl Paper on White Collar Crime" (Shapiro 1976) which was prepared

product differs among transactions, collusion is conducted during regularly scheduled formal meetings ~ where there are ,a .. small number. of firms and a simple product, less fonnal comnunication is possible~ where purchases are non-competitive, job or te·rritorial allocation may be necessar;y or a complementary bidd ing syste.'1l instituted (see also Leonard and weber -1970 i Reckless 1973). <c,;· "~.~_

-.=-i.:~ '-.~;-,_. ",',"

Consideratipn of patterns of bribery pertains to two phenanena: Tir" the nature of the relationships between organizations that enhances the likelihood of inducements from one to the other and predicts the character of these -inducements; and (2) the nature of the organizational structure that facilitates the accep~nce of bribes. How does the organization of a market for the supply of goOds and services facilitate bribe~ arrangements? In the context of government coqtracting, Bose-Ackerman (1975) suggests, for example, that when the government purchases a product sold on the open market, there ar:e fewe.rincentives forb,ribery than when. the government is the sole purchaser. Her analysis also considersthe"effec..t of m::xlopoly or canpetition in the supply of products and product differentiation on tJle 1 ~kelihood of.! bribery. Other questions about oH?Qrtuni ties for bribery might be explored. Does the fonn of bribel payments vary when organizational relationships are potentially on-going (supplying goods to a retailer or routine constant government inspection of producers) and when they are single events (applications to.medical school, selling military equipment to a foreign government)? How do the roles in bribe recipient organizations affect the incidence and form of bribery? \~at is the effect of intraorgani:z:ationa1 IOObility, for example, the constant shifting of individuals in ahd out of organizational positions? What would be the extent and nature of political corruption if the assignment of legislators to ooJigressional conmittees were done randcmly and altered annually?

A consideration of embe?zlement might examine differences in organizations -- whe·ther their corrmodities are relatively liquid. like troney or consumer goods or less liquid like nuclear submarines or machinery -- in the storage of such ~T.mCdities and accounting or inventory procedures for them, in the nature of supervisory systems, in the degree of discretion vest.ed in emplo.lees and in employee mobility and turn-over and their relationship to the rate and na'ture of embezzlement..

The last example pertains to attempts by persons or organizations to fraudulently claim entitlement to various benefits -- bank loans, insurance claims, food stamps, welfare, medicare, scholarships, or expense account reimbursements. Many of these entitlement arrangements vary in the rrethod by which entitlement is deronstrated and in the form of compensation. Are vendors paid (as in medicare) or are beneficiaries reimbursed (as in auto insurance)? Jk) potential recipients sinply disc;:lose their need for benefits, or are third parties required to certify need? Variation in the role of third parties, the demonstration of entitlement, the significance of audits and independent investigation ~ benefactor organizations are considerable, and JOOst likely are related to the rate and form of abuse that result.

.. In short, how does ooe structure an organizaion,- all~ate

organizational pos.ttions, protect organizational resources, structure interorganizational; relations, and create unilateral or bilateral

34

1"·'

:.---:.~. __ 1>._

I,'· ,

____ .~-:o:;---,------ ~--~~--~

.. sf .:~,,;f;; .::~:;<-=':~~' -/....:- ..... -. -'...---.-..

. :.~ .. ,·;.o,,::~-~:.f~;/;"

-" -;.- .~-.~ "

.. , ~,'~:~~.:;~?':.;) .-~' .

trah ... ...lc..S~~ha1·'-.-systems to minimize abuse? What effects do dif~¥r~nt sQlu~lons of structure and design have on the forms that such abuses Will lake? Research that considers variability, then, in the natl!re,. supply, and dea-nand for goods and services, the relatiQQ§~ip between. organizations, the stLucture of organ izat ioi'ls ana·the ttribilj-ty, of persons through organizational roles" tl'le natur: of ~upe~ision, the . struc,tu~ of

. 'transactions, and the llke, and thelr relationshlp to the form and lncide~ce of violations should provide ~rtarit insights regarding the soclal location of white collar crime. .- . ,=_._

!';s,' The Normative Dimension of White Collar Illegality

Research questions concerning the development,and change as well as ~e correlates of attitudes, social values f and SOCial and legal norms wltl) regard to white collar crime are oonsidered in this section. Alth~h some research on the attitudinal dimension can pe found, much of ,thelitera~ure on the emergence of legal norms in the white collar,area u=~in ~u~atlv~e Data collection and analysis for both of these toPiCS are aegGf~~ .1n thlS section. It concludes with a discussion of the policy implicatiOns ~ of r~search on normative issues.

Attitudes and Values Concerning White Collar Cr~

A COJ'llllOn charge is made tha,tlaws prohibiting ~hite collar o~fenses are not in correspondence wi th the JOOres of th~ .tlme, and attributes ~e

. apparent leniency with which white collar crllTllnals are, treated to th:s discrepancy (Burgess 1950, Aubert 1952, Ne\tmal1 1958,' Kad~sh ~963). mus accusation is made by the offenders as ~ll as t;'Y SOCial. sClen~lsts •. Rec;:ent clamor following in the wake of the international bribe~ lnvestl.gations conducted by the SEC '(Miller 1979b, Taubman 1979a, 1979b). and the sc~dal surroun::Ung the banking activities of Bert Lance (.Horvttz 1977.' Mtller 1979a) reflect assertions by rrembers of th: buslness, ~~nlty th~t enforcement policy is rot attuned to "normal~business praCtlCles·

1 rrher; 15

little systematic research, however, that attempts to assess the tmores, ,or the divergent social attitudes concerning ac.ti~ities, of this kind. . Studl.es have explored student reaction to the tel~vlslon qutZ show scandals ~f ~e late 1950s (Lang and, Lang 1961) and public judgements and sanctiOn1.ng preferences about pure food violations (Newnan 1953) .~n the ~ake of Watergate, a flood of survey r~search proj~ts of ~arylng. quallt¥ has eroorged, tawing a variety of attltudes concernl~gJ.JUb11C (x>nfi~ence ~ "~: country's leaders, and preferences about the J:l.lnishment of J:l.lbliC offlcla1i:1 engage( :l illegality (for exarrple, caroll 1974).

A first priority, then, is the d~~~lo~nt. of good ,survey. research which generates descriptive data an publlC attltude~ conc;:erning wh~te collar crime. It is critical .that research separate the dlIl\enSianS of .wlllte colla: cri.Tre that often are confused in attitud?su~~ys - attlttr;les ~u\.. different forms of offense (embezzlement, price-flxl~g, :tock manl~lat1.on, environmental pollution, as well as traditional cr:unesJ~ about d1.ff7rent oatterns of victimization (victimizing naive investqrs, large corporat~onsi faceless consumers)~ about different characteristics of offenders (natlona politicians, civil 'servants, corp:>r?-te of~ice7s, low-lev~l emp~~ees) 1, and about various -saIlctioning alternatives (l1IPrl~nt, flnes, lnJunctl.ons, alternative sentences). It goes without saymg that research should be

35

..

Page 23: Abpot .. White Collar.··Crime - National Criminal Justice ... This is Ci substantially revised version of the "~ckgrourrl Paper on White Collar Crime" (Shapiro 1976) which was prepared

~~--- - . - -~-- - --.

,I

'::"-"

~directed from C?llege soph~res to wide-ranging populations, and should lnclude cross-natlonal and long1tudinal research. .-

These data WOUld~<'valuaOLe for descriptive purposes as well as for the exp~oration of v~ri~ility in attitude by ~ of offense, by personal and soc1al characteL~st1cs" and ov~r time. Clearly public a~titudes va~ by offense. '!ust as there _ 1S a wlde range of attitudes abOut traditional forms of crlllle, the, same ~s true for forms of white collar crime. Itt«>uld be ~seful to cons1der d1fferences in perceptions of the seriousness of partlcular offenses both witbin scxoo broad category of white collar crime and between particular white collar and tradition~l crimes.17

On: might expect considerable diversity iQ attitudes between different populat1ons. What a~eth~ correl~tes of div~rgent attitudes? How do they v~ ~ standa7'd, SOCl.?loglcal var1ables -- ,?ge, socioeconomic stabls, sex, educat1on, ,pol1t1cal ldeology,ethnicity? Do they vary by social position or occupat10n~lrole-- distinguishing, for example businesspersons a~to:neys, aCc6un~~, civil servants, enployees, or 'th~ unenployed?'"' ,;, V1ctlI11S and, non-V1<:tlmS of white collar crime differ in their attitudes tow<:trd , ~rtl~ular ~lnds of offenses? What is the nature of cross-cultural var1ab1l1ty 1n attltudes about various white collar and traditional crimes? How can tl:1ese differences be accounted for? .

Finally ~ research may'· consider normative change. At the individual level,. one mlght.questi?n, social experie~ces as related to attitude change, for exampl~, S?C1al molnl1ty or changes In employment. At the social level, ~he co~tr1butlon. of the mass JOOdia, scandal, rates and patterns of ~llegal1ty, moral ·entr~preneurship, etc. to change t«>uld be considered. How 1S the law, ~lo.red !='> enginee~ oormative change - for exarnple, the effect of ~e crlm:na~l~atlon and r1gorous prosecution of a particular kind of behav10r on 1ndlvldu~l attitudes (Kadish 1963)? In general, then, there is much unexplored ~rr1tory to be examined regarding individual attitudes and ,:,al~e~ about wh1te collar illegality, nonnative differentiation aIOOng 1nd1v1duals and social groups, and normative change.

I;egal Develq;;ment

. O~ primary conc~rn to research on the social control of white collar cr~ 1S, the evolut~on of laws regarding particular forms of offense and stl~at1ng a~rop~'l"ate sa~ction~ for their breach. Polemical debates descr1bed ~arll;r 1n the ~lScusslon of criminality often oontain charges that~ . unllke street crlltles," many white collar offenses are ''mala proh1b1ta" rather th~ "mala in ~," that they11are offenses made by positive laws rather than ~lng wrongs 1n themselves. 'Ib the extent tJ:\.7,\t these charges a7'e true, th~ stuqy of rule-making in the white oollar area should t:e mu~h rlcher ~an 10 that of street crime. 'Ibe developnent of legislation 1n thlS oontext 1S oot necessarily an outg~th of the noral wrong inherent

17 sare h . . resea!c 1n progress, conducted by Marvin ~lfgang, is exploring

th:s questlon. Preliminary findings suggest that particular kinds of wh;~e collar il,legality ~ically are rated as quite serious by social a~lences relat1ve to the1r assessment of the seriousness of ~ "st~t crlITles. " .. 'Y ....

36

I I t I

'-;f

in these activities,· but rather it may reflect social, political, - or economic design. :

An important, although perhaps unwieldy, rasearch agenda in this area is the developnent of a descriptive inventory of white oollar. legislation with concern for the behavior proscribed, the prosecutorial avenue available (whether civil, criminal, or administrative), the penalties attached, and the "scx:ial jurisdiction" or organizational bodies which are responsible for enforcement. '1llis inventory should enconpass a longitudinal scope and reflect jurisdictional differences"':" by region, city, state, and nation. Finally, the inventory must reflect concern not only for the origin and creation of legislation, but for its implementation and pattern of use. It is as relevant sociologically that a law is oot enforced or is enforced with unusual vigor as that it exists. Furthermore, concern for patterns of use may signal oCca9ions in which existing legislation is being.ll_s!=d innovatively, instances in which the creation of new legislation may otherwise be awropriate. 'Ibis may be illustrated Y:tt the imposition of traditional antifraoo and disclosure related securities regulations by the SEC in response to allegations of international bribery and questionable payments prior to passage of the Foreign Corrupt Practices Act. In short, rates and patterns of use and non-use of existing legislation may provide important explanations of the development of new white oollar legislation.

A useful ancillarY agenda item would be the development of an ethnography of rule-making -. a detailed description of the process of formalizing legal proscriptions, with concern- for the initiator of the proposed legislation, the nature of the parties involvec l::x:>th in support of and opposition to the proposal, and the nature of the legislative process. The work of Mayhew (1968) in the context of development of anti-discr~ination legislation in Massachusetts might serve as a model of the kind of inquiry envisioned.

Data of the sort described here can be utilized to address questions about the conditions uooer which and the process by which white collar legislation is adopted. '!he cooparative focus can be longitudinal, cross-sectional, or a combination of the two. Questions about the emergence and develo~ent of legal norms or about differences b¥ social jurisdiction in the natu't:-e, breadth, and severity of these norms can be considered. Research to date has fcx:used explanations primarily 00 grandiose changes in the social and economic fabric of· SOCiety or on elements of political conflict and change.

. Based upon the analysis of Mannheim (1946, W. 86-7), Gilbert Geis (1968, p. -10) has suggesCted that the underlying factors encourag,ing state interference with oc~rce include:

• JOC)vement fl'Ol1l an agricul tural to a oomnercial and industrial society;

• increasing inequality in the distriqution of property, and the' amassing of great wealth by -·the few; ~=' -;c

• the growing need to leave property i!:l. the, handEF"-or~ other persons; . _ . _.

• transtormation =of~ ownership of visible property into intangible powers and rights, such as corporate

37

- ~- -- -

Page 24: Abpot .. White Collar.··Crime - National Criminal Justice ... This is Ci substantially revised version of the "~ckgrourrl Paper on White Collar Crime" (Shapiro 1976) which was prepared

shares, including a system of social security in place of ownership of goods; and

• passage of p~perty from private to corporate ownership.

Elsewhere Geis suggested that the incorporatior! of principles of "let the seller beware" (.ca'leat vender) into statutory law was a function of "population g~th, the developnent of cities, greater life expectancy, and enhanced technolo:w, the last rich in its c potential and awesaoo in its threat" (1968, p. 7). Clearly we need research on IlDre mic~level social and econanic events and their relation to the developnent ofwhite __ coll-ar legislation. what is the contribution of .recessionoi:'i.nflation or characteristics of the marke1;,struct-ure-6f 1ndustries subject to regulation to legi$latiy.edevelopnent':r

_ _-_I' .:::. :;.::~;:J;'"""'''='"- - -

Vilhelm Aubert, in his sttldy of the developnent of white collar legi.slation in Norway, considered the role of changes in Norwegian s<x:ial structure, characterized by the OCIItpetition of two social hierarchies - the ascendant hierarchy catpOSed of the labor JOOvenent and the gove~nt agencies which it controls, and the descendant hierarchy conposed of business g~ps. His analysis suggested that" ••• the definition of new legal crimes of the white-collar braro has served an :important social function by giving the ascendant group a feeling of possessing the economic power corresponding to its political supremacy" (1952, p. 269) 0 HCMever, slo.mess and inefficiency in the enforcement of this legislation, he argued, has served the function of pacifying the businessmen.

Aubert' s observations suggest a ilDre general PheJ1Ollenon that seems catloon in political history - the strategic use of legal IlOI'I'IB against corruption and self-dealing by newly emerging political regimes against their predecessors as a means of solidifying their power base (for ex~le, the cases of Iooira Gandhi in Iooia or Zulfikar Ali Bhutto in Pakistan). In research on corruption in the Sudan, EI Fadil Nayill Hassan (1979) explored the emergence of new anticorruption legislation (as well as rore vigorous prosecutions) in the wake of political change. Of course, it is an enpirical question whether this seeming pattern is a universal one, and if it is not, the coooitions associated with the presence of this pattern are an awropriate subject for research.

The often political and manipulative nature of the creation of white collar crime legislation is illustrated too by l:esearch on the role in this process of the-pool of acbors whose behavior is being limited by such legislation. Research has sham, for exanple, that historically the develqrnent of licensing requirements (and other foI'1'15 of occupational and p~fessional legislatiOn) has been a response to the demands of occupational gIOUps, guilds, and professional associations, which desire to restrict entrance into their profession or protect them from the encroachment of other professional groups (Akers 1968, Clinard and Quinney 1973). Similar at'g\.lOOnts have been offered regarding the regulation of other aspects of

... eoonanic livelihood: and the involverent of corporations in the construction of the antitrust laws has been frequently doclJ'Rented.

Sanford Kadish (1963) has< arguf.~ that the identification of business OR;lOsition to or detennination of ~ite collar regulatory legislation as all-powerful or monolithic is simplistic and empirically inaccurate. Systematic research is needed to examlne the conditions under which

38

political and economic power constellations are instrumental in the creation of white collar legislation, and to examine the kind of norms and the p~visions for enforcement and sanctions to which these g~ups contributed.

Of course, there are other kinds of independent variables related to patterns of legal. developnent that are worthy of e~ploratio~. What,. for example, is the impact of the nature, rate, and soc1al locat1on of dev1ant behavior on sQbsequent legislation? Do waves of violation precede waves of legislation? What patterns and distribution of corruption, ~or example, are most lik~ly to produce legislative refo~? ~s the prest,lge, ,fXMer, ~d hierarchical position of persons and organ1zat1ons engaged 1n cr1me pred1ct the likelihood of such reform? What is the role of scandal on reform, and what patterns of violation are associated with subsequent scandal?18

In addition to the need for a IOOvement to new kinds of independent variables, irl"'the study of legal developnent, there is a need as well to roove f~ the grandiose questions and comparative settings most often the subject of extant research to Itnre rocxiest ones'. Such questions consider differences by jurisdiction and by mrm. Why is it that ~tion A and nation B, ~tat~ or city C and state or city 0 have much roore strlngent laws for ce~ta1~ k1nds of white collar crime - or overall -- than the other? Why 1S 1t that regulatory agency E is much roore invol~ed ,in rule-~king an~ rule ~~~n­tat ion than regulatory agency F? Why 1S l.t that m a partl.cular' Jurl.sdl.c­tion the sanctions attached to crime G are much roore severe than those atta~hed to crline H? Explanations of these differences may pertain to rates of violation, the regional distribution of kinds of econmic enterprise, other econanic differences, differences in organizational prestige, or differences in social and organizational climates, and political ideology.

Many of the questions suggested can be explored empirically onlY,with great difficulty. They require a massive data collection eff~rt and a hlghly sophisticated sense for hist.:lrical and comparative explanat~ons. However, if the scope of the research and the grandeur of the theory remain nrrlest, there is certain possibility for valuable research.

Norms and Social Policy

Research of this kind is essential for more than the a~ademic questions it addresses. Research on normative issues in white collar crime has sig­nificant policy relElvance. Data on public opinion, for example, are valuable for policymakers, both in the definition of appropriate legislati,?n and for the demonstrations of wide-spread p.tblic support needed for the1r actions. But the preferences of the public have ~ct ~ law enforcement as well. '!be p.tblic audiences of white collar crime contr1bute both, to the mobilization and disposition of white collar crime. As conpla1.nants, audiences often are prUnarily responsible for the detectionof~ite,collar illegality bY social control agencies, but where . the publl.c 1S not supportive or not aware of the laws, the likelihood that it will m::lbilize

18 See Shennan (1978) for an analysis of this question in the context of police corruption.

-.:>/~:.-

39

,

Page 25: Abpot .. White Collar.··Crime - National Criminal Justice ... This is Ci substantially revised version of the "~ckgrourrl Paper on White Collar Crime" (Shapiro 1976) which was prepared

--- - ~~ - ----- - _ .. - . ~--.--- -~-

I. "

these agencies is reduced. 19 Similarly, where the p,lhlic oontributes to legal disposition by participation in jury deliberations, the agreement between pJblic and legal values is central to the likelihood of oonviction. The public is critical, then, to the success of law enforcement. Lata on its knowledge of and attitudes toward legal norms therefore are of significance.

The questions addressed in the section on legal developnent reflect matters relevant for social policy as well. It is only after the factors that predict the likelihood of legal innovation, sources of support and oH?Qsition to new legal norms, the severity of sanctions; the social arrangem:nts of enforcement, the extent and vigor of legal implementation, are understood, is it possible to design legislation to oombat particular offenses.

The Enforcement of Norms Proscribing White Collar Illegality

The previous section concerned the developnent of ~rms proscribing white collar illegality_ '!he following section oonsiders the disposition and sanctioning of normative breaches. '!his section pertains to the intervenin~ process by which these norms are inplemented cmd offenses are detected 'ari~i investigated. Both macrolevel phenomena -- the emergence, policy, impact, and cost of enforcement organizations - and microlevel phenarena -- the consequences of the organization of enforcement for particular violations -- are considered.

Enfor~nent responsibility for dealing with white oollar offenses may be vested' in either or both the public or private sector. Public sector enforcement may occur at the local, state, or federal levels, and may 00 lodged in criminal justice agencies and their affiliates (district attorneys, attorneys general, U.S. Attorneys, economic crime units, offices of special prosecutor, the police, FBI, etc.), or in special regulatory agencies (state cOrporation comnissions, SEC, IRS, etc.). When public agencies, whether executive, legislative, regulatory, or pl:Ogram, are themselves the victims of white collar crime - through benefits fraud, corruption, or self-dealing -- they also may be involved in enforcement activity. '!hus, the Department of Health, Education and Welfare had the office of Inspector General which was concerned, for exanple, with fraud in HEW benefits p~rams.

The location of private enforcement efforts are rrore diverse. '!hey include private social control organizations ("Nader's Raiders;' types, media action lines, etc.) ; the victims of white oollar crime (purchasers, investors; insurers, c::x:>npetitors, etc.) who singly or in concert may institute civil actions in resPonse to their victimization; the legal bar, which includes members who soour the economic envirorunent in search of violations in the expectation of collecting legal fees through participa­tion in ensuing litigatioOi and r finally, the parties subject to the rorms themselves who create self-regulatory functions or organizations to monitor and sanction member nonconpliance with the rorms (Better Business Bureaus, Chambers of Gommerce, ~fessional organizations, trade associations, etc.) •

19 See Black (1973, p. 142) issue.

for a more general discussion of this

40

1\·

. 1/'.' s.' f~ . * .

~ \_,

For purposes both of description and explanation of m.:my of the research questions that follow, it ~jould be useful if an inventory of the forms of . enforcenent and an ethnCXJraphy of the range of enforcement activity, similar to the normative inventory described earlier, could be developed. '!he ethnography would oonsider the fo~, of the enforce~nt agency's activity, agency emergence and change, t enforce:ment. poh<?y, enforcement strategies, typical agency work-load, agency relatlonshl.p to lts "oonstituencies" and to other organizations including the court.s, and general agency characteristics such as size, age, or type of ~rsonnel ~

Clearly, the development of all-encompassing descriptions for the whole range of actors in the white collar crime enforcement area would be prohibitive. For example, just in the area of securities .. fraud enforcel~~t, the actors include countless foreign agencies; the SEC, the Cor(lno:ht1es Futures Trading Commission (CFTC), the Department of Labor (enforcement of ERISSA concerning certain pension furrls) , and the U.S. Department of Justice, at the federal level; at the state and local level, securities conmissions, corporations comnissions, economic crime units, attorneys general; at the self-regulatory level, stock and conm<Xlities opt~ons exchanges, the National Association of Securities Dealers, the, Amerlcan

. Institute of certified Public Accountants, Better Business Bureaus, etc; as well as the securities bar, publicly-held corporations, stockholders organizations (i.e. the United Church Board for \'iorld Ministries), and potential stock purchasers, sellers, and holders.

Nonetheless, it would be extremely useful to be able to map out the enforcement terrain for a selected number of white collar offenses and get sane sense for organizational differences and variations in enforcement strategy between different agencies concerned with the same offense, similar agencies concerned with different offenses, and different agencies concerned with different offenses. In the remainder of this section; sane of the analyses to which these data could be subjected are suggested. They include analyses of the developnent of enforcement organizations, the nature of enforcement strategies, the developnent of enforcement policies, enforcement impact, and enforcement· costs •

The Developnent of Enforcement Organizatio~

Questions about the emergence and developnent of enforcement organizations follow directly from the questions about normative develo~nt considered in the previous section: '!he allocation of enforcement fUnctlonS and the stipulations of enforcement strategy are often contained in white collar legislation. legislation, then, is one source of enforcement organizations and one explanation of the qUality of their activity. B~t ~t is but one explanation - legislation is sanetimes not enforced or It 1S over-enforced; organizations over time change in st:ructure, policy, and activity. Enforcement activities ma~ arise without any enal?ling legislation v reflecting informal norms, private grievances, or prlvate business activity.

This section is concerned with the broader issues. ''!he follc'ling questions suggest same of the research inquiries appropriate in this area:

41

Page 26: Abpot .. White Collar.··Crime - National Criminal Justice ... This is Ci substantially revised version of the "~ckgrourrl Paper on White Collar Crime" (Shapiro 1976) which was prepared

--~-'-- --~,--~ • ., '.~ ;a

Under what oonditions is enforcement k(!pt pdvate or turned Oller to public agencies? Where enforcement is vested in the public sector, when is it designated to general purpose criminal jti5tic~ agencies and when are special purpose regulatory agencies created? What acoounts for the expansion and contraction of special purpose agencies further organizational specialization such as the recent creation of the Oommodities Futures Trading Commission or the decision to recombine specialized agencies under a single lJ1lbrella? What are ~;1e patterns of cross-jurisdictional diffusion of particular kinds of enforcement agencies? What acoounts for the enforcement apparatus vested in newly created agencies - the rights, for exaniple, of administrative subpoenas, licensing, disclosure, inspections, sanctioning po.ier, etc.? Under what conditions do self-regulatory agencies emerge? What characteristics of the offense or the typical victim are t-elated to active victim participation in the enforcement of laws involving white collar crime or the role of private attorneys in such enforcement? Under what conditions do other private social control organizations emerge? These ,ri,nd other questions explore the organizational terrain in the enforcement ,area, and the emergence and decline of organizations, their expansion and contraction, patterns of developnent and diffusion 'of organizational forms cross-jurisdictionally, and the conpetition' between organizations in different sectors.

~~m.::nt Strategy

Perhaps the most significant enforcement activity is the development of systems of intelligence for the detection and investigation of white collar offenses. In the study of the detection of cases of alleged illegality by the police, this process has been labeled ''mobilization'' (Reiss and Bordua 1967, Reiss 1971, Black 1973)~ Studies of police mobilization have distinguished the location of the intelligence operation -- whether cases have been detected by the initiative of criminal justice officials (proactive mobilization strategies) or are reported to these officials by outside parties (reactive rnobilization strategies). The fonner are illustrated by on-site patrol, traffic control, and vice work; the latter by citizen and, usually, victim carplaints. Pesearch on police mobilization ha~ discovered extremely high rates of reactive mobilization. 'Ibis, of course, should not be surprising, given the infrequency of criminal behavior, its lack of predictability, the short duration of a victimization, and its location in private settings. Indeed, proactive policing is IlDst productive only for offenses that occur in public places anQ with some degre of Predictability and regularity (i.e. narcotics, traffic, prostitution) (Reiss 1974).

HOIIever, important characteristics of the nature of illegal activity differ in the co'ntexts of street and white collar crbne. It has been observed that in t"l1e latter; many crimes are victimless or the parties are unaware of their victimization. These offenses sanetimes invol ve nul tiple Victims, oontinue over ti.me, and nu~t of ~cessity occur. in J;Ublic places. The offenders rarely act alone, but behave in a social network inhabited by coconspirators, UllWitting facilitators, and middlemen. In white collar cr~ enforcement, then, one finds nultiple locations, sources, and og;x>rtunities for rnobilizing cases, whether n:actively or proactively, and

42

, o

" ,

';1 ,

1' ..

, ~.

L

this gives rise to a multiplicity of techniquess

The follOlling list suggests sane of the IlDre typical strategies of detecting white oollar illegalities used by various enforcement organizations: 20

• canplainants and Info~~: , Instances of potentlal lllegallty are frequently disclosed by outsiders. They include vict~ of the activity, a::mpetitors of those e~ag~ 1n the activity, disgruntled erployees, lOslders of offender organizations, informants, and others.

• Solicitation of Outsiders: This strategy seeks to create another source of conplaints of illegalities, although it <bes ~ formally. 'l'W:> types are employe~. In one, I?r1-vate organizations are created W1th responSl-bility for detectirg illegali~Ya Frequently the agencies maintain legal ~ers7ght Oller th7 ::. activities of these opganlzat10ns. They 1nclu~e private inspectors (i.e. grain inspecto~s), ,pr1-vate alrlitors, or self-regulatory organlzatlons (i.e. stock exchanges). A second type. at~~ts to employ the threat of SClI'OO fotIn of llablllty for illegality to parties who may have knowledge about the illegality, for example, lawyers, accountants, or brokers with regard to stock frauds. Pres\ll\ably this group can be ~loyed to report en the activities to which they are pr1vy.

• Other Social Control Agencies and Processes: , Other social control agencies often learn of lllegal activities under their jurisdiction. This is especially tr~e given the:; "~or~ui~ous, and ra~" fashion in Wh1Ch agency ]ur1sd1ct1on 1S samet~s defined. '!he execution of illegalities, therefo~e, frequently crosses agency jurisdictional bou~arles. CAltside agerll~ies may t.-efer cases formally or mformal­ly. FurtheI11!Mlre, agency observ~tiQl of extE:rn~ social control activities may slgnal potentlal llle­galities salient to agency jur~sdiction~ F~ example, investigation of illegal campalgn oontrlbut70ns ~ the Watergate ~~ial Prosecutor generated the lnve~t1-gation of col:porate slush fuoos by the SEC. Pr1yate stockholder suits mB¥ raise the spectre of aSSoclated illegality, and generate new investigations.

20 See Shapiro (1980) for an exteoooo discussion of detection strategies used by the SEC.

43

"

Page 27: Abpot .. White Collar.··Crime - National Criminal Justice ... This is Ci substantially revised version of the "~ckgrourrl Paper on White Collar Crime" (Shapiro 1976) which was prepared

• Snowballing or Spin-offs: This strategy of case acquisition is closely related to the former. In this example, the social control process which generates new investigations is located wi thin the agency. The execution of a particular investigation turns up evidence either of additional violations enacted in the particular illegal scheme or of independent schemes. Since many white collar ille­galities encompass many transactions and relationships all IOObilized to "pull off" the illegality, investigation of one of these transactions probes the tip of an iceberg, the underlying structrue of which is occasionally discovered. Where white collar vio­lators are rrembers of organized crime, perpetual con men, and the like, the investigation of one of their schemes often supplies evidence of others. Thus, a given investigation sometimes spins off other investigations.

• Inspection and Auditing: This strategy deplqys agency personnel to make inde­pendent inquiries about the activities of their regu­latory constituents. Through legitimate access to the activities of particular entities, agencies can scru­tinize their behavior and ~sumably uncover illegal activity (as well as prevent illegality because of the difficul ty of hiding it from an inspection system). This strategy is exemplified by bank examinations or auditing of tax returns.

• Infiltration/Ooversion: Where agencies lack legitimate access to inspection or where the fonnal and public quality of inspectioo facilitates rover-up, more oovert strategies may be em­ployeq. Although their use is still lOOre typical of the enforcement of street crimes, particularly vice or victDnless crimes, infiltration and covers ion have special applicability for the detection of more collu­sive white collar crimes, such as bribery and corruptioo, or those involving complex frauds perpetrated on unwitting victims.

• Disclosure or Self-Reporting: This strategy relies on the reporting of data by regu­lated parties on their activities, behavior, or finan­cial condition -- some aspect or pattern of which might be indicative of illegality. This is illus­trated by the required filings of publicly listed cor­porations or of stock purchases by corporate insiders to the SEC. Another interesting device is the requirement that parties audit or investigate th~ selves as a condition for settlement of other ille­galities (as in the foreign payments area). Often where the sanctions or the probability of detection of

44

I : " " ' .. . "

I r I

, \

inadequate disclosure is high, data on other illegali­ties can be gathered.

• Surveillance: This ~trategy relies primarily on the output of dis­closure or observable public transactions or events. It studies the patterning and change of various sta­tuses and activities in the hope that unusual activity may be indicative of illegality. This is best illus­trated by market surveillance conducted in the securi­ties area, where complex computer ~rams scour data on stock market behavior, purchases, sales, prices, etc., and signal unusual activity warranting further investigation. Because the marketing of securites is so well documented -- with names of ~ers and

'. sellers, time of transactions, quantities, prices, etc., -- rather ingenious inferential models can be developed and ernplqyed for detection of illegal it Yo Note that surveillance can rely on other material, of which the mass media is an ~rtant example.

The macrolevel issues implicit in a consideration of enforcement strategy -- differences b¥ agency in rates of the utilization of particular intelligence techniques or in the extent of proactivity -- are addressed in the following discussion of enforcement policy. In this section, microlevel issues concerning the relationship of the crllninal event and law enforcement strategy are considered. First, illegal activities, by necessity and desiqn as well as inadvertence, generate information which is differentially susceptible to detection by the various strategies described here. Different ~hite collar illegalities generate different kinds of data. An important research issue concerns the correlation of offense-related characteristics - the actual offense, the rreans of violation, the magnitude of the violation, cnaracteristics of the violator, the relationship of the offender to the enforcement agency, and patterns of victimization -- with detection strategies. Are proactive maans n¥:.\re likely to detect violations by offenders who previously were known to the agency, through recidivism or registration, than violations by novices? [t) sane strategies detect more serious violations than others? Offenses that involve no known victims or unwitting victtms may be ~netrable without proactive methods. Even when victtms are aware of their victimization, the likelihood that a a:xrplaint will be lodged with an enforcement agency may be affected by the nlltlber of victims, the victim's per capita loss, the social organization of victims, prior experiences of victllnization, or general sociological characteristics of victtms.

This last example, which considers the correlates of victlln complaints, suggests sane useful research concerned with the social conditions under which agency outsiders transmi t intelligence to social control agencies. How do offenders construct their schemes to minUrtize victlln complaints? How do they plan their crimes so that participants won't becOIle disaffected or won't "squeal" to law enforcement agencies? What incentive or sanct7.00s can enforcement agencies develop to induce participants in illegality ancillary personnel, facilitators (accountants, attorneys, etc.) or observers - to reveal knowledge of offenses?

45

,

Page 28: Abpot .. White Collar.··Crime - National Criminal Justice ... This is Ci substantially revised version of the "~ckgrourrl Paper on White Collar Crime" (Shapiro 1976) which was prepared

-'--~----~----- -~

D:spite the need for t"esea~ch, it is safe to speculate that the overall output of cases generated by one detection strategy is likely to . be different than that generated by another. Contrast, for example, the different kinds of information available from insiders, victims, inspections, disclosure, and surveillance. Although these differences are interesting, the important issue is their impact on enforcement policy. Case mobilization is a selection or sampling technique, a strategy by which some presumably non-random sample is drawn f~ an unknowable population of offenses. If different mobilization strategies create different samples, it is important to understand the nature of these differences. The associated policy question considers appropriate ways to, manipulate ~d allocate detection strategies to create a sample that 1S representat1 ve of some enforcement objective.

Three other questions about the nature of detection strategy are appropriate. The first moves away from concern for differences in the characteristics of violations detected boward concern for the quality of the intelligence generated. Are some strategies IlOre accurate than, others? One might suspect, for example, that citizens complain about matters which may not constitute a vl,olation, and that more sophisticated complainants and agency personnel engaged in proactive mobilization would be more likely to spot actual law violations. It is charged that corporations often allege violations by their oompetitors that are of questionable accuracy. Are these speculations and charges supported empirically? Do strategies vary in temporal qualities of offenses detected? HCM "stale" are violations by the time they are detected? One might expect that matters generated by surveillance \<,Ould be more likely to be on-going and less likely to be "stale" than matters generated by victim complaints.

A second question relates to deterrence. A more formal consideration of deterrence is contained in the next major section of this paper, which deals with sanctioning. HCMever, there are important deterrence issues implicit in the design of an enforcement system. Where offenders know that their activity has little likelihood of detection, the deterrent value of sanctions imposed for their offense is irrelevant. Presumably, if offenders are rational, they will not be deterred. Indeed, in some enforcement contexts where the likelihood of detection to some extent can be quantified (for example, IRS audit categories) and therefore the calculation of risks made try potential offenders, it is argUable that enforcement plays a IlOre central deterrent role than does sanction. In any event" an interesting research question concerns the awareness of the subjects of enforcement of detection strategies, of their calculations of associated detection probabilities, and generally of the associated deterrent value of particular mobilization strategies.

A related issue concerns secondary deviance, specifically the ~ct of enforcement strategy on the nature of the execution of· illegality. How are offenses covered-up or modified to lessen the likelihood of detection? Some of the comnon strategies involve the use of n::>minees, dlllTllTlY or fictitious persons, misrepresentations in required disclosures, false bcx:Iks and records, double sets of books, laundering of funds, creation of slush funds, computer accounting manipulations, and the bribery (whether blatant or subtle) of potential whistle-blCMers, COl'Iplainants, or enforcement agenqy

46

, . I ,

, .~

personnel. What is the relationship of enforcement strategy to cover-up strategies of these kinds?

Enforcement Poligy

In this discussion the develoflllent of enfor'cement policy - the a~locat~on of ag~nsY resources to particular enforcement strategies and dlscre~lOnaIY dec~slon~ about the targets of enforcement -- is considered. Ex~utlve or le~p,slat1ve mandate to saoo extent may dictate enforcement p?llCY. Agenc1es may be required to conduct inspections or COI1pel dls7losur~, for example. B¥ virtue of the resources allocated to agencies, thelr cholce of enforcenent strategy may be l~ited t~ less costly meth~ls. But gen:rally ~ er:tf?rcement ~encies are free to define enforceroont strateqy ang asslgn prlorlt1es to varlOUS methods. How do agencies differ in their use of various enforcement strategies, and what are the 'l1arious sources available?

Agencies do differ, and a major source of this difference C'Oi'OOS from ~ariabi~ity in the ~nformation generating capacity of the offenses relevant ... 0 particular agencles. Contrast, for example, a consumer fraud unit with the IRS. Because of the differences between consumer fraud and tax fraud the role of canplainants may be rore effective in the former case and th~ role of audits more effective in the latter. Even so differences in enforcenent strategy in agencies of the same kind -- fede;al and state tax commissions, different banking regulatory agencies, federal and state securities commissions - need to be fully explored.

A ,seCOnd po~iey matt~r concerns enforcement targets rather than str~tegles. Agencles, espec1ally where proactive, often make discretionary cholces about where to focus detection. Priority may be given to smaller offenses that generate le'lrge per capita victim losses, or the reverse. M:>re seriC?Us offenses of ~llmangitude (i.e. the enbezzlement of $1,000) may rec~lve g~ater attent10n than offenses of greater magnitude considered less s~rlous, (loe. a conflict-of-interest situation that generated $1,000,000). Dlscretlon may relate to the size of the targets of investigation or to the an'Dlm~ of resources necessaty to investigate them. . Antitrust enforcelOOnt may lnvolve IBM or Kodak, or relatively small corporations in less concen~rated industries. ~curities enforcement may pertain to Lockheed and Gulf all, or to newly emergulg corporations that seek to market their stocks ~ublic~y • Discretion may favor the allocation of resources to offenses lnvolvlng poor or naive victims or highly visible victims (movie stars and other "beautiful people") • Discretion may :r;:ertain to offender characteris.tics - as in the assignment of audit categories by the IRS - or to the soclal role of offenders in an illegality - for example the SEC "access points" theory, in which the professional facilitators ot' offenses (a7countants, attorneys, brokers) rather than the offenders may be the prunaty tal;qets of enforcement. 'lbese catparisons suggest the value of re~arch that attempts to understand the correlates of agency enforceIlEnt polley.

~nforcement Impact

This topic is an extension of the previous one. Enforcement agencies vary tr~ndou~ly in the outcomes of their soCial control activity, and they are so percelved by Congress (Subcaunittee 1976), the public, and presumably

47

,

Page 29: Abpot .. White Collar.··Crime - National Criminal Justice ... This is Ci substantially revised version of the "~ckgrourrl Paper on White Collar Crime" (Shapiro 1976) which was prepared

----~-.--~----------------------~----~----~------------'~~ .. ~~' .. ----~ .... ----.. ~ .. --.. ------------------------------------,-------------------------------------------------

offender populations as well (see, for example, Sullivan 1977). '!he question, of course, is why this is the case. HoW can one account for different enforcement impact? one first must define the term "irrpact," a task not undertak,e,n here. Indicators of impact may include the presence of scandals in the industry being regulated, agency track record in the courts (especially the appellate courts), agency enforcement case load, the magnitude of fines, other awards or penalties, some estimate of deterrence or the extent of compliance with regulations, and the like. Next, one rust seek comPariSon groups for which as many of the extraneous sources of variation as possible can be controlled. 'lbis can be Cbne through a: cross-sectional study of several agencies which, because of jurisdictional. overlaps or duplications, are somewhat comparable in enforcement goals, or' through a longitudinal study of a single 'agency .and changes in iItq?act ClVer time. one may COhtrast the tl1ree federal agencies with jurisdiction ClVer bank regulation, or contrast u.S. Attorneys offices in different districts or particular kinds of regulatory agencies in various states.

An interesting comparison \\Ould contrast the u.S. Securities and Exchange conrnission and the U.S. eonmodities Futures Trading COnmission. Both have Sllni1ar regulatory responsibility and sUnilar enforcement problems, but radically different ratings of the quality of their enforcement program (Subcommittee 1976, SUllivan 1977). Are the relatively positive and negative ratings, respectively, a reflection of the forty-year discrepancy in agency age and the greater "roaturity"," experience, and, perhaps, respectability attained by the SEC, or qo they reflect differences in agency organization, enforcement policy, enforcement strategy, or patterns of illegality that each encounter? What were the perceptions of the enforcement impact of the SEC when it had been in existence for only several years? This agency has attained its greatest aggressiveness in the enforcement area during the last decade. What accounts for this change -charismatic leadership, changes in the econ<:>tl¥ and the nature of the illegal activity it fosters, Watergate, normative change, change in agency structure or personnel, or the accumulation of years of prestige and credibility? Explanations of this kind are difficult, of course, but they are central to policy interests ooncern~~ with the development of effective enforcement of laws pertaining to white collar offenses.

,'the Cost of Enforcement

An important issue in the desi9n of enforcement systems is its o:>st, that incurred b¥ investigation, p~secution, and delivery of sanctions, as well as by the targets of enforCeIrent (to ~lY with investigative subpoenas, hire counsel, defend themselves, etc. ). r AI. though estimates of aggregate costs may be illuminating -- for example, estimates that the Federal government devoted 84,773 man-years to regulation in fiscal 1976 (Subcomnittee 1976 f p. 6) - it w;>u1d be nuch \TOre useful (and ll'Ore difficult) to have estlinates broken down by type of enforcement strategy or type of offense.

21 This leaves aside the matter with goverment regulations. enforcement agencies and allegatiOns of deviance.

of the costs assoc~ated with canpliance Here we consider the costs incurred by enforcement targets associated with;!

48

- "

r ' ) Wl. th regard to enforcement strate f . . , and units of oomputer time are ' gy, or example, hc:M may person-hours prosecuted case? What is th!YP:~~l;¥ de;?ted to surveillance efforts fer systems to the quantit and alia 1~ns l.~ of ~e costs of inspection Clearly p~ctive det~ctionqustr.:~ o~ vl.olatl.ons de~ected. by ~~ese efforts? strategies. But what oosts are ~ eg~es are, IOOre expensl.ve than reactive effort? How many hours~ are devo:~~t~ Wl.tI: th~ subsequen,t investigatory victims relative to the mltlbe f fn,;,estlgatl.ng oomplalnts by alleged How does that figure contrast r W~th comp Cl:1nts ~at result in prosecution? violations detected during inspectiom;;~e mvestlgatory effort allocated to

'Attempts to break down enforcement . siderab.ly Irore difficu1 t RON • ~sts by type of violation is oon-difference in resources' ~llocate~ver, lt ~uld ,be . useful to know the other things being al) by . ~ ~e mvestl.gatlon of offenses {all parties and by cons;rratorial o:;:~z=~ns and by ,i~d~viduals, by single offenders, that generate witting· and

g unw~t' by :eC~d1V1Sts and by novice not involye elements of a oover-up. It \ttU l~n~ v1ctlIns, and that ?<' or do changes l.n· the costs of investigation uas . fr

efU1 t:o have es~unates of reflected in the nl.l1lrur of off d 0 enses mcrease l.n scope, offense, physical spread of viotantl.,eVrs'a nt~~t7 of victims, duration of the e c 1Vl les, etc.

obtai~~~r~~i~a~l~~ithiS kind ~re ~xtremely ai~ficult to ob~i!21cc=andJDCe

t 1 ,tY.aIlsiP;llabllty are guestl.oY\::>hl'-~'B·--·-J:

ra to the desl.on of systemS f"'] ---~ _ .. .......,.L~. Ut 1L seeIIl$ cen-costs of irnplernentin ' 0 en orcement to have some sense for the ber of violations t1erru~~~a; e~orcement strategies relative to the nun­offenses detected the rna ni tud~ e n~ber of prosecutable or prosecuted distinctiveness of offen~s relat~~ ~~usness of these offenses, and the techniques. 000 g~nerated by other enforcement

The Disposition and Sanctioning of White Collar Illegality

The literature concerned with th d' " collar offenses is more extensive e lSPOSltl0~ and sanctioning of white previously discussed. 22 Hc.wever ,:an that relat1ng to JOC)st of the topics on the invocation of the cr'irnina'l sa~c~ncern has, ~n. a~st exclusively tencing, on sentencing difflerentia1s be~n, orbrarl.abl.l1t~ 1n criminal sen­and the deterrent value of 'criminal sanc~n \!l'Ieh ancil wtute oollar crUne, iIlq)Ortant H th I .1 ns. ese ooncerns are not un-

t' f" ?Wever, ey miss IlOSt' of the "action" by foe' 1 lP 0 the lceberg with reg d to th . , ' . ' uSl.ng on y on the

legality •. '!he data presentedarin Tabl e 2 d~frslt1on o.f w~ite collar il­shows a breakdown of dispositional o~t~ ~st~lat~ hlS V1ew. 'Ihe table almost 2000 person d ,', lOVO vlng a random sample of tions by the SEC ~v: ~~9~1~~~10ns_ i,~eS~gated for white oollar viola~" tQble illustrates, onl 85 -off r perl tween 1948 and 1972. AS the plead guilty or were ~nvicted enders, 4 ,~rcent, of ~e original sample, subject to criminal sentencing ~ secur~t~es vlo1atl.ons, and therefore, escaped sentencing becausethe~ were ~~lng 96 perce.nt; o,f t:h~ offenders regulatory agency (9 percent) bece ou not to be 1n vl01at1on by the despi te their violation (45' perc:~~ they were not prosecuted at all n or prosecuted';' only civilly or

22 A, COJIprehensi ve view of issues in the sanctioning of white crl100 can be found in the President's Co7'rn'l1' sSl.on collar (1967) • "ou Task Force Re};X)rt

49

,

Page 30: Abpot .. White Collar.··Crime - National Criminal Justice ... This is Ci substantially revised version of the "~ckgrourrl Paper on White Collar Crime" (Shapiro 1976) which was prepared

-~ ----.---

·~--.-~--~~--~~--~----~~.~,~,~---.-------~~------~~~-----.""""""" .... ~------.-----------------------------------------------------~----~ a<inini~tratively (37 percent), because the Justice Department declined prosecution (2 percent) or did.oot proceed with ,their case (2 percent), or because they were acquitted (l··percent). Although these particular figures are perhaps idiosyncratic to the SEC, they are clearly ~ical of ~erall d isposi 1: iona 1 trends for other agencies. Even for Offenders en(Jaged in clearcut illegal activities which carry criminal penalties, the ljLkelihood

TABLE 2

'IOl'AL OFFENDERS

00 violation violation not prosecuted violation prosecuted civilly or administratively

Total offenders refer-red far criminal prosecution

u.s. Attorney declined prosecution nolle prosequi a<x.Iuitted

Total offenders subject to sentencing

SOurce: Adapted from Shapiro (1980, W. 190, 203)

1934(100%)

-180(9%) -861(45%) -708(37%)

185(10%)

-47(2%) -33(2%) -20(1%)

85(4%)

of invoking the cciminal justice system is rare,' and the eventuality of criminal sentencing is even rarer. A realistic theory of t:he:.disposition of white oollar illegality must consider the other 96 percent of the Offenders. It must seek to uroerstand the conditions that generate ooncriminal outCOlOOS as well as criminal penalties. Questions of deterrence su17:ely rust consider the deterrent value of p,rison sentences (in the ilhlstrat7Lon, only 2 percent of the Offenders were sentenced to prison) or of 'criminal sentences generally, but they also rust oonsider. the deterrent ~alue of. the entire range of prosecutorial outOOJIes. .

" The z:esearch inplications of this orientation. are the subject of this

section. Specifically, variable dispositions, prosecutorial success, sanctioning, and deterz:ence are oonsidered. "'1he topics discussed here relate to the :inq;x>sition o~ legal sanctions for whiteoollar illegalities. Clearly, sanctioning can be am is enacted by. oon-legal social control organizations as well. An ex~ination of this ~ss might be the subject of intez:esting research, but it is oot specifically addressed in this pape!':'. Most of the topics oovered invel ve questions posed at toth the micro- ··ana . macro-levels. The fOt'lOOr ooncern dispositional ·differ:ences across specific offenders and offenses and seek explanations ~ their characteristics and behavior. '!be latter conSider diffez:ences across enforcement agencies,

50

- -"~.- ---_ .. .

legal jurisdictions, and time periods, and seek explanations in agency characteristics, prestige, . and resources, as well as oormati ve characte~istic~ and normative change.

\'

The Nature of Case Disposition

As the data presented in Table 2 suggest, a broad range of outc:::oroos may befall a matter investigated by "enforceJt¥:!nt agencies. '!his range differs by agency and its legal poWers· and options, but these results include' non-prosecution, civil, administrative, or criminal prosecution, and informal undertakings and ancillary remedies. '!he legal dispositional outcomes of private litigation include civil, treble damage, class action, shareholders derivative suits, and the like. Offenders, then, may be spared sanctioning, or may be imprisoned, placed on probation, enjoined, disbarred, divested, fined, sued, have their license or bUsiness operations suspended or revoked, be ordered to make restitution or rescission, investigate themselves, restructure their organization, or surrender themselves to the control of a receiver.

The consequences of lawbreaking can be strikingly different as a result of the IOOde of prosecution employed. At one extreme, business activities may continue as before, though enjoined against future lawbreaking. At the other extreme, these activities may be permanently halted by the revocation of licenses or forms of registration, or by the imprisonment of the business leaders and operators. Alternatively, the structure of business operations may be substantially altered through legally induced changes in organization, leadership, operations, dispensation of furrls and materials, and the like. Although each of these: outccmes may result in the temporary cessation of the illegal activities, t.l:ley are p,l:entially different in their impact on the offenders, the business comnunity and its constituency, on deterrence and recidivism, and in their sc:x::ial oosts. A consideration of the conditions under which one or another prosecutorial method is employed and one kind of sanction or another imposed is by no IlEans a trivial matter. 23 .

In the ca~e illustrated in Table 2, JOOre than half of all offenders wez:e oot formally prosecuted, despi be the invol verrent of JOOst of them in prosecutable offenses. Although this proportion probably varies across agencies, it reflects the J1l)st ccmnon response to violations and, therefore, is worthy of attention. What are the characterisitcs of offenses (their severi ty and :immediacy), offenders, victims, and the investigatory process, that are associated withnon-prosecution? Why are SCfIe participants in an offense prosecuted and others not? What are the typical "rationalizations" or "justifications" given by enforcement agencies for oon-prosecution? IkI ra~s of non-prosecution vary by agency or by jurisdiction across agencies of similar kind? I):) the justifications for oon-prosecution differ across agencies? What accounts for cross-agency differences -- offense and offender-related characteristics or agency-related characteristics? Is

23 For an example of the kind of analysis described here, see Shapiro (1978) •

51

(.i

Page 31: Abpot .. White Collar.··Crime - National Criminal Justice ... This is Ci substantially revised version of the "~ckgrourrl Paper on White Collar Crime" (Shapiro 1976) which was prepared

there a relationship between the maturity of asencies and the legislation they enforce and the proportion of· cases prosecuted?

Of course, a substantial proportion of offenses are'~prosecuted, often with IOOre than one prosecutorial mode employed (for ~~anq:>le, a civil

. injunction might be obtained against individuals and corporations; then . subsequently the individuals may be indicted for these violati:.'prts). Many of the same questions concerning the correlation of offen~related and agency,.. re lated characteristics suggested earlier with respect to non-prosecu~ion are appropriate to variable prosecution. Before analyses of this kind can be undertaken, however, it is critical that offenders be sorted into categories for which the same prosecutorial possibilities are available. For· example, the likelihood of invoking criminal penalties should be examined separately for offenses that carry only criminal penalties, that carry both civil and criminal penalties, that carry roth administrative and criminal penalties, and that carry civil, administrative, and criminal penalties.

In addition to exploring the 6'ffect of offense-related and agency-related characteristics on mode of prosecution, the effect of alternative forms of prosecution on the ~sition of a particular type of prosecution should be explored. I)) forms of prosecution oomplement or substitute for each other? How do offenses with multiple forms of prosecution imposed differ from those with single forms? '!be macrolevel questions pertain to different rates 0f prosecution ~ enforcement agency, controlling for agency differences both in prosecutorial opportunities and in the composition of offenses prosecuted. I)) agencies of similar kind vary in the extent to which they prosecute matters criminally or in the ratio of civil to criminal prosecution? How might such variability be explained? Do these rates vary over time within the,.o!'r:wne agency?

The previous discussion assumed that the determination of prosecutorial mode was located in a single orga.nizational contexte However, few enforcerrent agencies are vested with full prosecutorial authority. Many agencies must go to outside organizations to prosecute their caseS criminally and saootimes··'civilly. Consideration of disposition, therefore, should include the interorganizational process through which cases flow fran ipvestigative agencies to prosecutorial agencies, and the role of the latter

/;/agencies in determining disposition.

Prosecutorial agencies are rarely coopelled to prosecute all cases referred to them. Research on the cases referred from investigative to prosecutorial agencies which are declined promises to be rich. At the microlevel, this provides a second opportunity to evaluate the effect of offense and offender-related characteristics on the likelihood of prosecution. On the macrolevel, the research provides an qportunity to systematically explore cross-agency differences in disp:>sition as they are reflected in agency relat~ ... shtps with a Etingle prosecutorial agency. . Fot'­example, in the context (~~'::~ff*:~~~1:~!J~l>;}J'<ffi:~~"$~in (1971, 1972) has fourrl substantial cross-agencY variability 10 rates of cases declined k:!i U.S.. Attorneys, ranging from 10 percent to 90

;;. ... .: _ .,..~. w_.;:u. u~~. d

" ,

52

j',

"

~i.

r ",

"

percent. 24 What are the characteristics of the agencies, their enforcement and disposi tional processes, or their relationship to prosecuting agencies that account for differences of this magnitude?25

Prosecutorial Success

The transition between prosecution and sanctioning is marked ~ a critical factor -- successful or oon-successful prosecution. Because the rate of successful prosecutions for white collar offenses is so high, it is easy to neglect this 'phenaoonon. But two questions rust be addressed: When are prosecutions lost? HOW are prosecutions won? '!be former question involves the correlates of unsuccessful prosecution of individual cases -­strength of evidence, staleness, nature of the victi¥lization, magnitude of the offense, offender characteristics, etc. - and on the macrolevel, explores differential rates of unsuccessful prosecution b¥ agencies ac~ss jurisdiction, and over time. If macrolevel variation is fouoo, explanat~ons concerned with different levels of prestige or expertise, typical patterns of illegality prosecuted, agency aggressiveness or passivity, the recency of legislation being enforced, and public and judicial attitudes abc)U~ white collar crbne might be addressed. High rates of successful prosecutlon may reflect strong public' attitudes against white collar crime and aggressive enforcement agencies1 however they may instead mirror cautious passive agencies which, prosecute only the most trivial and clear-cut offenses. Explorations of this kind ooncern all prosecutorial modes - - civil, cr~inal, administrative, and private suits.

The latter question involves the way in which prosecutions are successful. Specifically, it asks whether prosecutions are terminated by litigation or b¥ oonsent, gu~lty or nolo oontendere pleas., ,It is, unclear whether the proportion of gull ty and nolo pleas on the crlInlnal slde, and consents and settlements on the civil and administrative side, are as high in the white' collar area as the guil ty plea is in the prosecution of street criIoo. Nonetheless, the proportion is high enough to mari t study. Research is underway concerning cases of white oollar plea bargaining by federal prosecutors (Katz 1979b) and defense attorneys (Mann 1978). HcMever, research must be devoted to the p~ss of bargaining across ~~Secutorial

24 These rang~ from 90 percent for ineligible sales of food stamps referred ~the Department of Agriculture) to 50 percent and 4~·per?ent for draft violations (Selective Service) and gun control vlolatlons (Alcohol, Tobacco, and Firearn~, IRS), respectively, to 10 to I~ per?ent for violations such as mail fraoo (Post Office), food and drug vlolatlons ( FDA), securi ties violations (SEC), incorre tax fraoo (IRS), imnigration violations (Inmigration and Naturalization Service), and highway safety violations (Department of Transportation).

25 Rabin suggests that correlates of the declination of a given referral include "caseload, magnitud~ of the violation, court-perceived criminality of the offense, special characteristics of the defendant, e~dstence of alternative sanctions, adequacy of the case, equality of treatment of regulated parties, and special interest influence" (1972, pp. iii-v).

53

,

Page 32: Abpot .. White Collar.··Crime - National Criminal Justice ... This is Ci substantially revised version of the "~ckgrourrl Paper on White Collar Crime" (Shapiro 1976) which was prepared

__ -_-___ . ~--~ .... ~ ...... ~ .. ~ .................. ~.a .. ~~p ...... ~ .......................................................................................................... a:~ ___ --

t,. ~ ,.,.. .. , '."" «- • ,

IlDdes besides the criminal one, and the correlates of litigation versus consent. What are the characteristics of offenses and offenders who choose to litigate charges? Perhaps more ~rtant than the extent of culpability or severity of the offense in explaining this variation are factors such as the prestige of the offenders and defense counsel, the magnitude of the charges, or the novelty of the charges. On the rnacrolevel, one might ponder cross-agency differences and within-agency differences over time in rates of consent and consider whether the recency of the law, or the prestige and reputed vigorousness of the prosecuting agency are related to this difference.

The Nature of Sanctions

Given successful prosecution, sanctions must be ~sed. White collar crime sanctions vary both in severity and in kind, both within and across mooes of prosecution. Criminal judgments include fines, prison sentences, suspended sentences and probation, as well as "alternative sentences" that now are coming into vogue - requirements that offenders make public addresses about their "evil ways," that corporations make charitable contributions, that individuals engage in conmunity service, etc$ (see Bur,eau of National Affairs 1976, and Renfrew 1977). Sanctions emanating from administrative p~~edings can involve revocation 0f licenses or forms of disbarment, but may also involve lesser penalties including suspensions of business or personnel, nonetary fines, and required ch3.nges in organizational structure or management. On the civil side, tr.e J;ennanent injunction is the typical penal ty, al though imposing other ancillary rezoodies - restitution or rescission, disclosures, inspections and audits, limitations on business practice, receiverships, and the like - may increase the severity of the injunctive sanction~ With regard to private civil suits, one may argue that the size of an award has sane relationship to severity of sanction, although the relationship is I:¥ 00 rreans clear.

SOIOO kinds of penalties are readily qLiantifiable - magnitude of fines, length of imprisonment or license suspension - facilitating comparative research. HOA'ever, many sanctions cannot be quantified. FurtherIIDre, different offenses carry different sanctioning possibilities, both in kind and in extent. Similar offenss carry different sanctions across jurisdictions. 'lberefore, conparati:;,e research on the imposition of sanctions is fraught with difficulties. '!be solutions are oot addressed here, but the problems rust be seriously evaluated before neaninglful research can be conducted.

Ideally, a series of conparisons \\Ould be desirable: sanctioning differences for 'I,'ifferent parties participating in a given offense, for parties engaged .m similar offenses, for parties engaged in different offenses, and for similar offenses oomnitted in different jurisdictlons or in different eras. For exarrple, what were the various fates of the participants in the price-fixing conspiracy in the heavy electric equipment industry~ hCM did these sanctions conpare with those typically levied for price-fixing and to those typically ir..pJsed for bribety or securities ,or tax fraoo~ and hCM did these sanctions differ fran the price-fixing penalties imposed in different federal districts or in the 1920sor 19706 rather than the 1960s?

54

. '!he microl~vel ~estions pertain to the sources of the considerably disparate sanctions ~sed on various offenders. Characteristics of individuals and organizations, the nature of their participation in the offense, matters of recidivism, and the like, are invoked in this analysis. Macrolevel questions involve what appear to be substantial cross­ju:i~ictional .an~ longitooinal disparities in sanctioning, at least crlIRl~al. sanctioning.26 Interesting theoretical questions emerge if sanctloning differences between jurisdictions or over time remain, even after controlling for offense- and offender-related characteristics. ro matters of public opinion or of normative climate account for these differences, or do they reflect instead matters such as the composition and gJ:'ganization of the "jud iciary ," case-load and incidence of particular kinds o~ offense? Questions of fairness and equal justice are also salient if differences are found. Systematic research is needed to measure differences of this kind for administrative and civil as well as for criminal sanctions. What is the source of these differences.'? IX> they remain when one controls for offense and offender-related characteristics? What is the role of the normative composition of various jurisdictions and various eras on sanctioning differences?

Deterrence

The study of the general preventive effects of punishment or deterrence has been an important research area in the field of criminology (Andenaes 1966a, Chambliss 1967, Zimring 1973). Perhaps one of the major findings of this body of research concerns the greater deterrent value of sanctions imposed on behaviors which are "instrl.Jnental," or rationally calculated, rather than "expressive," or emotive, in notivation (Chambliss 1967). In contrast to traditional forms of crime, white collar crimes are thought to be mJre instrumental than expressive. To the extent that it can be asSlDlled that white collar crimes are usually the response to a utilitarian calculus of the probability of economic gain, this form of criminality is particularly appropriate for the study gf deterrence~

In the literature concerned with the deterrent value of various sanctions, one frequently finds the assessment that, as presently structured, the proscribed penalties for white collar crime have little ~eterre,:t valu~. 'Ibis usually is attributed to the low probability of such lilegallty being detected (a problem discussed in the section on

26 For example, a small stooy conducted by the u.S. Attorney's Office of the Southern District of New York (SrNY) contrasted the likelihood of i~ri~onment and the average length of sentence ~sed by offense in its d lstrict and across all federal districts during a six-IOOnth period in 1972 (Bureau of National Affairs 1976). '!he study found, for example, that the likelihood of imprisonment for bribery was 25 percent and 42 percent, or for securities fraud was 67 percent and 22 percent for the SI:NY and all other districts, respectively, or that the average length of pri~on terms for tax violations was 5.9 and 10.45 months, or for perjury 5.2 JOOnths and 28 months, respectively.

55

--. ,

Page 33: Abpot .. White Collar.··Crime - National Criminal Justice ... This is Ci substantially revised version of the "~ckgrourrl Paper on White Collar Crime" (Shapiro 1976) which was prepared

enfo~cement), the small fines or other monetary penalties relative to the prof~t acc7U~ from the, offen~, and the low pt:Obability that persons will recelve cr1111lnal penalties (el.ther because of the inability to oonvince the public of moral culpability or the inability to attribute corporate criminality ,to ,poli~kers) (Kadish 1963, Dershowitz 1961). '!he response to these dlfflcultles has been to suggest that sanctioning systems be restructured -- for eXClIlple, impose fines so that all illegal profits are recovered and all victims coopensated (Dershowitz 1961), or introduce standards that create affirmative duties and responsibilities for corporate policymakers over the behavior of their employees (Dershowitz 1961, Kadish 1963) • Another suggestion proposes that since the stigma of inpris~nt has more impact for so-called white collar persons than for others, these

,persons should be jailed more frequently (Geis and Edelhertz 1973).

Although these proposals seem coopelling, they tend to igrore the vast range of illegal behaviors to be deterred and the multiplicity of potential prosecutorial settings invoked, and they substitute intuition and sinplistic assumptions for research findings. Among the distinctions that must be made and then empirically evaluated include specific deterrence versus general p~v~ntion, t.h:e ,detert;ent effects of various types of prosecution (civil, cruDlnal, admlnlstratlve) as well as the traditional concern for the certainty and severity of sanctions, and the different consequences of sanctioning persons and organizations. For nost of the research questions described here, it is necessary to locate analysis within particular kinds of offenses,and evaluate the consequ~nces of altering the mode and targets of prosecutlon and the nature and del1very of sanctions for the same kind of behavior. TO be unattentive to offense-related differences is tQ confound the research with so much clutter that an already difficult analysis will beoorte formidable. ..

Almost all of the research concerning the deterrence of white collar crime has involved criminal sanctioning. 'Ibis focus is inappropriate for tv«) reasons~ the rarity of the invocation of the criminal Justice system for offenses of this kind (discussed previously) and the problems of attacking organizational offenses with criminal penalties. Research is needed on the deterrent effects of the various CX>TIpOnents of the prosecutorial alternatives available. Given an equal certainty of sanc~ionin~, ,what, are ~e, var~ous inpacts ~ offenders and on the general publ7c o~ 1n]unct10ns1 1~]unct10ns coupled w1th ancillary remedies, such as res~1~ut1on! changes. 1n ~gement, or special investigations; of admin1stratlve penalt1es rang1ng from fines to suspension of business operations to license revocation or disbarment; of criminal fines1 of prison sentences; of "alternative sentences;" of civil lawsuits? What consequences are associated with charging individuals instead of or in addition to organizations? What kinds of sanctions leveled at which positions in organizational hierarchies have greatest deterrent effect?27

27 These latter questions, of course, assune kinds of illegal ac'tivities that involve the oarplicity of organizations and persons in managerial roles - bribe paying, price-fixing, or securities violations. '!he allocation of sanctions is scxtewha.t clearer where offenses are nore easily attributable to individuals - the acceptance of bribes and kickbacks, self-dealing, etc.

56

i >-.

,\' '.,

, . "

A different sort of question relates to the deterrent effect inherent in the conduct of prosecution and delivery of sanctions. What is the iIrpact of private as opposed to public administrative proceedings, of secretive grand juty proceedings versus nore public forllllS, of televised congressional hearings (such as Watergate), or of extensive litigation versus quiet consent agreements? What is the inpact of the publicity of sanctions - a front page New York Times story on William F. Buckley's SEC consent injunction (Miller 1979c) in contrast with the typical injunction which earns an inch or two on one of the back pages of the Times, if at all? Survey research which evaluates the knowledge of various white collar crime audiences about the delivery of sanctions and of their reaction to sanctioning would be valuable.

Stooies of stigma also would be useful. HeM do various sanctions generate stigma and how do they differ? How' do organizations experience stigma? When do the misdeeds of individuals have a stigmatic effect on the organizations for which they work? One way of a::]dressing these questions is to research the consequences of prosecution and sanctioning of white collar offenderse What haH;lened to those convicted, in the G.E. price-fixing case, to ~lrlge Renfrew's price-fixers sentenced to deliver public speeches at the evils of that crime, to the Watergate particpants who did and did rot serve prison sentences, to the nulti-national corporations involved in the international bribet:y scandals and subject to SEC injunctive ptoceedings, and so on? Did individuals face different employment ~spects than others of their same age, experience, and previous :p:>sition? ,Do sanctioned individuals find that non-professional social relationships are strained ~ irrpaired? Do convicted corporations have difficulties with their stockholders? Do they have difficulty finding new capital, making new contracts, ot' generating sales? Is their ooopetitive position in their respective industries inpaired? Do they experien!==e boycotts and other informal social sanctions? What seems remarkable, from riOn---systematic reflection, is the rarity of at least ron-subtle consequences for individuals and organizations of the invocation of sanctions for white collar illegalities. Research is needed to consider the potential stigmatizing effects inherent in the nature and delivery of various sanctions, and of the management of stigma by those who have received sanctions.

Finally, deterrence is not the only relevant oonsideration in the choice of sanctions. '!he severity in financial terms and in terms of deprivation of liberty that may be needed to deter white oollar crime relative to roore traditional crime may be unjustifiable to a public that does not consider these victimizations as serious. Research directed to finding the public's attitude toward different sanctions for various types of white collar crime is needed.

57

Page 34: Abpot .. White Collar.··Crime - National Criminal Justice ... This is Ci substantially revised version of the "~ckgrourrl Paper on White Collar Crime" (Shapiro 1976) which was prepared

--~-- - ~--~--- • ..

III. C'CNCLUSION

The first part of this paper reviewed critically the conceptual 'themes in the litera,tu,re on ~it~ co,llar crime, expanded and integrated them, and P~sed ,a~ltlon~l dlstlnctlons that might be useful in defining and dlfferentlatlng whlte collar offenses. That discussion leaves to ehe reader th~ difficult task,of selecting an appropriate definition of white collar crlJ1le and oonstructlng a ty{x)logy of offenses. The second part of the paper P~sed an ag7nda of research with regard to white collar crime. Like the ~lrst part, ,thls part, too, leaves tasks for the reader. The discussion is Incomp~ete ln two respects:, the research topics are stated so generally and expa':ls~ve1~ that they ~lrtua11y cannot be pursued without further speclflcatlon; and the toPl~S are arrayed as in a smorgasbord -- presumably equally worthy of our appetlte -- without any indication of their relative ~eri~ ?r importance. Again the reader is left to select the fOssib1e uq\UrleS that are: of, g~atest relevance or inmediacy, and then mce selected, of operatlona1Iz1ng the research qU~~tion.

These "omissions," of course, were intentional. It is meaningless to propose a typology of white collar crime stripped from the theoretical research, or f01icymaking enterprise for which it is to be used Similarly' the "con~tituencies"of white collar crime and the sources of ~eir conce~ are so dlverse that research priorities and research design necessarily must be left open. This discussion concludes with saoo reflections on the task of setting prioritie~ and of designing research.

Matters of priority may siA'11ply reflect the social location of the pc;trtiCI.;Ilar "constituent." Economists may be IIDre interested in antitrust vlo1atlons than embezzlement. Preferencesot psychologists most likely are ~he rev~rse. The: State Department presumably 'is IIDre interested in lnte~tl(:)Oal brIbe,t'Y than in crimes against business. Business orgam.zatlons IIDSt llke~y ar.e IIDre ~ncerned with employee theft, pilferage, and embezzlement than Wlth Lnternational bribery. Officials in the Justice Depar~nt may ,be IIDre interested in the use and impact elf the criminal sanctIon than WIth civil or adminis~ra~ive forms of disposition (although a gCX?d, argl..ll'lent COUld, ~ made that lnslghts about the relative impact of 7r~lnc;t1 ,and non-cr,lJIl,lnalrememUes would be invaluable to those with ]UrlSChctl.on over crlJlllnal remedies).

M?:t'e subUe choices are involved in the design of a research program. What ~s ~e trade-off between basic and awlied research, between IIDre aCadf.'~IC Interests and those of policyma.kers? Many of the macrolevel questl'?"s ,de~cr~bed in the pap~r -- about the sources of cross-cultural or cr\)Ss-]urlschctlonal patterns of illegality or enforcement or of their change over time - although ,interesting for theoretical p.lrposes, may be of <:>nly. reoote ~lev~ce to poll~1JlIakers for whan spatial and temporal context lS fIXed and unmedlate.

Another question concerns the trade-off between description and explanation. , ~ina~ily, on~ ~uld rot design a program of research concerned prlmarily w1th descrIptIon. However, it is incredible how little: we ~ abou~ patterns of white collar illegali1;y and enforcement. Even partIclpants In the process arE! frequently unaware of the big picture that

58

, i'

, . i, ,

their discrete activities have created -- the kinds of matters i~~'estigated, parties prosecuted, sanctions inp:>sed, etc. '!he choice is between research that asks who is the violator, in what way are violations occurring, what enforcenv:nt strategies are being utilized to deal with them, and what d isposi tions result from these efforts, and tesearch that asks ~ these people are violating, why these kinds of violations are occurring, what accounts for the use of these enforcenent strategies, and what explains the variability in dispositions and sanctions inposed. These two sets of questions are oot necessarily nutual1y exclusive, but the design of research pertaining to one may be incompatible with the design of research pertaining to the other.

Another choice concerns the short-term or long-term consequences of research. FOr example, the ~lementation of findings involving aspects of enforcement strategy or enforcement targets may have almost immediate ~ct for social control. The consequences of ~lementation of findings pertaining to deterrence, enforcement :inpact, or mrmative change may mt be felt for years. ~related concern pertains mt to the t~ing of the ~ct of research, but rather to the soope and t~ing of the research itself. Many of these questions require oonplex research designs and enoI1OOus conmitments of time and llDley for their execution. '!he imnediacy of policy questions and the limited resources of policymakers and academic researchers may preclude ~ertaking projects of this kind.

Each of these trade-offs must be evaluated with respect to the setting in which the research is oontenplated. S~i1arly, matters of research design, particularly involving the selection of the research site, must derive fran the interests and priorities of those conterrplating the research. The choice of a research setting will reflect substantive interests, concern for generality or specificity,concem for description or explanation, preference for academic or };Oliey concerns, and r:erhaps lTDst of all, matters of access to data.

The research questions p~ in the previous sections only begin to scratch the surface of the enortOOUS pool of potential inquiries about aspects of white collar cr:i.ne that might be oonducted.'1be research agenda is inOCXlPlete, then, in the collection of topics proposed as well as in its omdssion of definition, specification of priorities, and operationalization. Alth~h the tasks incllllbent Ql the reader to fi,11 in these anissions may be substantial, they pale in the face of the tasks associated with executing the research. As ooted earlier, many of the topics suggested will require substantial (X)IIIIli tments of time and resources. Nonetheless I the tasks are not insurnnintable. In recent years a flurry, of research has been urXlertaken, overshadowing in theoretical scope, methodological rigor, and policy relevance the accll1\u1ation of a third of a century's worth of literature on white collar cr:iJr.e. And the work is just beginning.

In characterizing the work on white collar crime CNer the past quarter of a century, Gilbert Geis (1974, W. 284-5) noted that the "white-collar crime researcher might write an article, then a book, and later perhaps a general overview of the theory and substantive content of work an whi te-collar crime. '!hen he JlDV'es along." Unlike the stereotypic CNerview described by Geis, this paper looks to the future rather than the past. It serves not as the bridge of professional respectability that leads (May from

59

,

Page 35: Abpot .. White Collar.··Crime - National Criminal Justice ... This is Ci substantially revised version of the "~ckgrourrl Paper on White Collar Crime" (Shapiro 1976) which was prepared

attention to white oollcu:- crime; rather it hopefully provides sate of .the building block)'l with which others can work and oonstruct a stronger bridge leading ~ard ~rtant systematic work in this area.

60

-~'::--"':;~:.~~~:::'::.."1;:'t~~,..~1=;:.~~~~.>,iI..~_~--=~~~..lIt~~w, ... ",.,.. ~ • __ ~,.- ....... __ ? ;pr~~~~~-~.""",_~"!"''';;:::C;z;;'_·:-':':.·:~~':';:l'~;r::-.e:''~:;!.':"'~:;:t'::.-~,t'':·::::r~':'':''''7"::.-~~-"";';;"'.~ .-' .'

BIBLlOORAPHY*

Akers, Ronald L. 1968 "The ~fessional Association and the Legal Regulation of Practice."

Law and SOciety Review 2: 463-482.

Alatas, Hussein 1968 '!be Sociology of Corruption; '!be Nature, Furx::tion, Causes, and

Prevention of Corruption. SingaIX>re: D. Moore Press.

Allen, Brandt R. 1975 "Embezzler's Guide to the Conputer. H Harvard Business Review 53:

79-89.

Allen, Francis 1959 nCriminal Justice, Legal Values and '!he Rehabilitative Ideal."

Journal of Criminal Law, Criminology and Police Science 50: 226-232.

Alieitjcan Enterprise Institute For Public Policy Research 1977 Criminalization of Payments to Influence Foreign GO'Vennents.

Washington: American Enterprise Institute.

Amick, George, and Barbara Bacon 1976 '!be ~rican way of Graft: A study of Corruption in State and local

Goverrrnent, HCM It HaA?ens, and What Can Be I:bne Alx>ut It. Princeton, N.J.: Center for Analyis of Public Issues.

Andenaes, Johannes 1966a "The General Preventive Effects of Punishment." University of

Pennsylvania Law Review 114: 949-983.

Andenaes, J., N. Christie, and S. Skirbekk 1966b nA StlJd:,.1 in Self-Reported Crime." Scandinavian Studies in

Criminology 1: 86-116.

Aubert, Vilhelm 1952 "Whi te- Collar Crime and Social Structure." Al1erican Journal of

SOciology 58: 263-271.

Axeltod, ld>ert 1970 Conflict of Interest. Cllicago: Markham.

Bacon, Selden D. 1950 "Review of White COllar CriIi;e l:!i Edwin H~ SUtherland. H Anerican

Sociological Review 15: 309-310.

Bailey, F. Lee, and Herny B. lbthblatt 1969 DeferXJing Business and White Collar Crimes: Federal and State.

Rochester, N.Y.: Lawyers Co-Operati vee

* !ok)re extensive bibliograPlies can be foun:i in Tarpkjns (1967), Geis (1968), Geis and Meier (1977), and Ostennann (1977).

61

Page 36: Abpot .. White Collar.··Crime - National Criminal Justice ... This is Ci substantially revised version of the "~ckgrourrl Paper on White Collar Crime" (Shapiro 1976) which was prepared

Ball f Harty V. 1960 "SOCial Structure and Rent-Control Violations." American Journal of

SOCiology 65: 598-604.

Ball, Harty V. , and LawrenceM. Friedman 1965 "The Use of Criminal Sanctions in the Enforcement of Economic

tegislation: A Sociological View." Stanford Law Ieview 17: 197-223.

Balter, Henty G. 1975 "Plea Bargaining and the Tax Fraw Syrrl:rome. Ii Tax Magazine 52:

333-339.

Barmash, Isadore (ed.) 1972 Great Business Disasters: ~~indlers, Bunglers, and Frauds in

American Industty. Chicago: Playboy Press.

Basc~, JamesR. Jr. 1976 . Unusual Foreign Payments: A Survey of the Poli.cies cmd Practicies of

U. S. Corrpanies. New York: Conference Board.

Beckenstein, Alan R., and H. Landis Gabel 1980 "Organizational Compliance Processes and the Efficiency ,of Antitrust

Enforc~nt. " Paper presented at the annual meeting of the Law and Society Association. Madison, Wisconsin: June" 5-8.

Bell, Griffin B. 1978 Memorandum concerning appointment of Directo~_o£ the National

Ecooomic Crime Project (May 16).

Bensnan, ,Joseph, and Israel Gerver 1963 "Crime and PunislTnent in the Factory: '!he Function of Deviancy in

Maintaining the Social System." American Sociological Review 28: 588-598.

Benson, George Charles Sumner 1975 Alooral ArIerica. Stanford, Calif: Hoover Institution Press .•

Bequai, August 1977 COOputer Crime. Lexington, Mass.: D.C. lieath.

Bequai, August 1978 White-Collar Crime: A 20th Centuty Crisis. Lexington, Mass:

Lexington Books.

Berg, Larry L., Harlan Hahn, and John R. Scl'Jllidhauser 1976 Corruption in the American Political ,System. ~rristown, N.J.:

General Learning Press.

Berty, John F. 1977 "Unraveling a Lance Bank's Finances." Washington Post (October 16).

Black, ronald J. 1971 "The So=ial Organization of Arrest." Stanford Law Ieview 23~

1087-1111.

62

1',. ,~~ .... ~ ., '. '~·":'":;::-:<:":;:;·.~::::::.':~::~,;::i:::~'::'<:H":~'-l'\.~:<~::>'·=-_,,,,, k •• """'''''''' ... ·.-=..~-"'''L~'. ,-'~ '0' __ _

Black ,Donald J. 1973 "The ftDbilization of Law." Joumal of Legal Studies 2: 125-149.

Black, Hillel 1962 '!he Watchdogs of Wall Street. New York: r-brrow.

Bloch, Herbert A., and Gilbert Geis 1962 ''White-Collar Crime" in Man, Crime and Society: '!he Forms of Criminal

Behavior. New York: Randan House: 379-404

Bloan, Murray Teigh 1971 Pogues to Riches: '!be Trouble with Wall Street. New York: Putnam.

Blum, Richard Ho 1972 Deceivers and Deceived: Observations 00 Confidence Men and '!heir

Victims, Informants and Their Quarry, Political and Industrial Spies and Ordinaty Citizens. Springfield, Ill.: '!banas.

Blundell, William E. 1976 Swindled. New York: J):M Jones Books.

Bc;>rkin, JoseIi1 1962 '!he Corrup'_ Jooge: An Inquirj into Bribery and Other High Crimes

and Misd~~anors in the Federal COurts. New York: Potter.

Briloff, AbrahOOl J. '. . 1972 Unaccountable Accounting. New York: Harper & Row.

Briloff, Abraham J. 1976 r-bre Debits Than Credits: ~e Burnt Investor's Guide to Financial

Statements. New York: Haq.~r & Rai.

Branberg, Walter 1965 Crime and The Mind. New York: Maanillan.

Bryant, Clifton D. 1974 Deviant Behavior. Olicago: Parrl McNally.

Bureau of National Affairs 1976 "White-COllar Justice." United States Law Week 44 (April 1.3): 1-16.

Bur:gess, Ernest W. 1950 "Comment on Hartung, 'White COllar Offenses in the Wholesale Meat

Industry in Det~it.'" American Journal of Sociology 56: 32-34.

Burton, J.F. Jr. 1966 "An Eoonanic Analysis of Shetman Act Criminal cases" in J .M.

Clabault and J .• F. Burton, Jr. (eds.), Sherman Act looictments 1955-:-l96?= A Legal and Eoonanic Analysis. New York; Federal Legal Publ1catlons.

Butterfield, Fox 1978· "Peking Presses Carcpaign Against Official Corruption and High

Living." New York TUnes (May 7): 22. .

'·63

,

Page 37: Abpot .. White Collar.··Crime - National Criminal Justice ... This is Ci substantially revised version of the "~ckgrourrl Paper on White Collar Crime" (Shapiro 1976) which was prepared

..

Caldwell, Robert G. . 1958 "A Re-Examination of the Concept of White-collar Crime. !I Federal

Probation 22: 30-36. .

Caplin, M:lrtimer . . . 1976 liThe IRS I Racketeers and Will. te COllar Crlltllnals." American Bar

Association Journal 62: 865-866.

Carey, Max:y, and George Sherman . 1976 A COnpendillD of Bunk or HQtl to Spot a Con Arti~t - A Handbook. For

Fraud Investigators, Bankers; and Other Custodlans of the Publlc Trust. Springfield, llle: Thomas.

Carroll Robert M., Steven M. Pine, Cindy J. Cline, and Bruce R. Kleinhaus 1974 ~Judged Seriousness of watergate-Related Crimes." Journal of

Psychology 86: 235-239.

Cartwright, Joe, and Jerry Patterson . 1974 Been Taken Lately? The Conprehensive Consumer 'Fraud Digest.. New

York: Grove Press c

Chamber of COmmerce of the United States 1974 A Handbook on White Collar Crime: Everyone's Ioss. Washington:

Chamber of Comnerce of the Un! ted States. e Olanbl iss, Will iam J. 1967 "Types of Deviance and the Effectiveness of Legal Sanctions."

Wisconsin Law Review: 703=719.

Chambliss, William J. 1978 On The Take: Fran Petty Crooks to Presidents. BlOOOlington:

Indiana University Press.

Civiletti, Benjamin R. 1978 "Statement Before the Subconmittee on Crime, Comnittee on the

Ju:liciaty, House of Representatives, COncerning White Collar Crime." (July 12).

Clark, John P., and Richard Hollinger. 1977 "On the Feasibility of Enpirical Studies of ~ite-Collar Crime" in

Robert F. Meier (ed.), Theot'J in Criminologyf1' COnt:elrp)rary Views. Beverly Hills: Sage.

Clarke, M.J. 1978 "White Collar Crime, Occupational Crime, and Legitimacy."

International Journal of Criminology and Penology 6: 121-136.

Clarke, Thurston, and John ~1. Tigue 1~75 Dirty f.bney: Swiss Banks, the Mafia" f.bney Laundering, and White

COllar Crime. New York: Simon & Schuster.

Clinard, Marshall B. 1946 "Criminological Tt~eories of Violations of Wartime Regulations."

American Sociological Review 11: 258-270.

64

·-:~·~·~:_~2L::,::z:::::.:::..:..~:..:--:.,:!.'ts~~~~~ __ ~~,,.,.~ ___ ._... ..,-.--.... - •• ~~~,.,""'-.,,="""".===~:-..:."!=""~::c""'=tt":::::-= . .,..J'~,=.rr-·; """"~':=::,:r " \

,

Clinard, Marshall B. 1952 The Black Market: A Study of White COllar Crime. New York:

Rinehart.

Cl inard, Marshall B. 1968 "White Collar C:rime" in International Encyclopedia of the Social

Sciences. New York: Free Press: 483-490.

Cl inard, Marshall B. _.>

1979 Illegal Corporate Behavior. Washington: U.S. GoverJ'lJOOnt Printing Office •.

Clinard, Marshall B., and Richard Quinney 1973 "Criminal Behavior Systems: A 'l}1IX>logy." 200 ed. New York: Holt,

Rinehart and Winston: 187-223.

Clinard, Marshall B., and Peter C. Yeager 1978 . "Corporate Crime: Issues in Research." Criminology 16: 255-272.

"ohen, Stanley 1977 The Game They Played. New York: Farrar, Straus & Giroux.

caner, Michael J. 1977 Corporate Fraud. Iondon: McGraw-Hill.

"Conptroller' s Report: 'Unresolved Questions. "' 1977 washington Post (August 19).

Conklin, John E. 1977 Illegal But Not Criminal: Business Crime in AIoorica. Englewoc:x:l

Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall.

COrmier, Frank 1962 wall Street's Shady Side. Washington: Public Affairs Press.

Cressey, J))nald R. 1950 "The Criminal Violation of Financial Trust." Arrerican Sociological

Review 15: 738-743. .

Cressey, Donald R. 1953 . other :People's M:>ney: The Social Psychology of Embezzlement. New

York: Free Press.

Cressey, Donald R. 1961 "Foreward" to Edwin H. Sutherland, White Collar Crime. New York:

Holt, Rinehart & Winston.

Cressey, Donald R. 1965 "'!he Respectable Crimil1?"l.; Why SaTe of Our Best Friends Are

Crooks." Transaction 2: 12-15 •

Cressey, Donald R~ 1976 "Restraint of Trade, Recidivism, and Delinquent Neighborhoods" in

James F. Short, Jr. (ed.), Delinquency, Crime, and Society. Chicago: University of Olicago Press: 209-238.

65

1 1 1

Page 38: Abpot .. White Collar.··Crime - National Criminal Justice ... This is Ci substantially revised version of the "~ckgrourrl Paper on White Collar Crime" (Shapiro 1976) which was prepared

~-~~'- - - -~-- _.

CrC7t\"1ey, George D. 1975 "The Tax Fraoo Investigation. n Joumal of Criminal Defense 1:

155 ff.

Deeson, A.F .L. 1972 Great Swindlers. New York: Drake.

DeFranc.o, Edward J. 1973 ~\natoow of a Scam: A Case Study of a Planned Bankruptcy by Organized

C'rme. Washington: u.S. Goverrunent Printing Office.

~tt, I).A. 1977 "Rl~eaving the Corporate Veil: Management Structure and the COntrol

of Coqx>rate Infonnation." Law and Cont.enporary Problems 41: 182,,-221.

Dershowitz, Alan M. 1961 "Incl:easing Ccmnuni ty Control Oller Corporate Crime: A Problem in the

Law of Sanctions." Yale Law Journal 71; 289-306.

1979 "Devel,opnents in the Law: Corporate Crime: Regulating -Corporate Behavic:)r 'l1u:ough Criminal SanctiOns." Harvard Law Review 92: 1127-1375.

Dinitz, Simon 1977 "Economi(:! Crime" in Simha F. Landau and ~slie Sebba (eds.),

Criminology in Perspective. Lexington, Mass.: Le!Cingten Books.

Dirks, Rayroond L., and Leonard Gross 1~7 4 The Great tfall Street 'Scandal. New York: f.k:Gra"rHill.

Ditton, Jasen 1977 Part-Time Crime: An Ethnography of Fiddling and Pilferage.

london: Macmillan~

Douglas, Jack D., and John M. Johnson. 1977 Official Deviance: Readings in MalfeasaIlce, Misfeasance, and Oth~r

Forms of Corruption. Philadelphia: Lippincott.

Downey, R. M::>rgan ,1974 "Public Citizen Btaff Report: White COllar Crime, January 1973 -

June 1974" (unpublished paper) c

Duchnick, J .L., and Michal9l J. Dohoff . 1978 nA New Outlook en t'lle White COllar Criminal as it Relates to

Deterring White Collar Crime." Criminal Justice Journal 2: 57-76.

Duoovny, Amtam M. 1969 The Billion D:>llar Swindle - Fraoos Against the Elderly. New York:

Fleet Press.

Dum, Donald H. 1975 Ponzi: The Boston Swindler. New York: M:::GraW'"'Hill.

66

~-'.-' t:1

r'~

i.

, i' .;

Edelhertz, Herbert 1970 The Nature, Inpact and Prosecution of White COllar Crime.

Washington: U.S. Government Printing Office •.

Edelhertz, HerbeI'-t,~-Ezra Stotland, Marilyn Walsh,. and Milton weinberg. 1977 The Investigation of White-COllar Crime: A Manual For Law

Enforcement Agencies. Washington: ,U.S. Goverrunent printing Office.

Ehrlich, Isaac 1972 "The Deterrent Effect of Criminal Law Enforcement." Journal of Legal

Stooies 1: 259-276~

Elias, Christopher 1971 Fleecing the Lambs. Chicago: Henry :Regnery.

Elsen, Sheldon H. 1969 "Securities Law Investigations." The Review of Securities :Regulation

2: 873-878.

Emersal, 'lbanas 1. 1950 "Review of White Collar Crime l:!i Edwin H. SUtherland." Yale Law

Journal 59: 581-585.

Ermann, M. David, and Richard J. wmman 1978a Corporate and Governmental Deviance: Problems of Organizational

Behavior in cantenporary Society. New York: Oxford.

Ermann, M. David, and Ri.chard J. Lundman 1918b "Deviant Acts l:!i Cooplex Organizations: Deviance and SQcial Control

at the Organizational Level of Analysis." . Sociological Quarterly 19: 55-67.

Farberrnan, Harvey 1975 IiA Criminogenic Market Structure: The Autaoobile Industry."

Sociological Quarterly 16: 438-457.

Farney, Demis 1978 "Scandals OVer Fraoo, sex and Bribes Fail to Stop Incl.lllbents." Wall

Street Journal (November 9): 2.

Farr, Robert 1975 The Electronic Criminals. New York: M=Graw-Hill.

Farrand, Janes R. 1976 "Ancillary ~ies in SEC Civil Enforcement Suits." Harvard Law

Review 89: 1779-1814.

Ferrara, Ralph G. 1971 "SEC Division of Trading and Markets: Detection, Investigation and

Enforce.ment of selected Practices that Inpair Investor Confidence . in the Capital Markets. nHoward Law Ieview 16: 950-92.

Flemning, Marl is 1976 Under Protective Surveillance. Toronto: M:::Cl~lland & Stewart.

67·

Page 39: Abpot .. White Collar.··Crime - National Criminal Justice ... This is Ci substantially revised version of the "~ckgrourrl Paper on White Collar Crime" (Shapiro 1976) which was prepared

- • •• ;a

Form, William H. 1968 "OCcupations and Careers" in International EncyclOpedia of the Social

Sciences 11. New York: Free Press: 245-254.

Gardiner, John A., and David J. Olson 1974 '!beft of the City: Readings on Corruptioo in Urban America.

Bloomington: Indiana University Press.

Gastwirt, Harold P. 1974 Fraoo, Corruption, and Holiness: '!be Controversy OVer Jewish Dietary

Practice in New York City, 1881-1940. Port Washington, N.Y.: Kennikat.

Geis, Gilbert 1962 "Toward A Delineation of \'Ilite Collar Offenses." Sociological

Inquiry 32: 160-171.

Geis, Gilbert 1967 "The Heavy Electrical ~ipnent Antitrust Cases of 1961" in Marshall

B. Clinard and Richard Quinney (eds.) Criminal Behavior Systems. New York: Holt, Rinehart & Winston: 139-150.

Geis, Gilbert (ed.) 1968 White-Collar Criminal: '!be OffeOOer in Business and the Professions.

New York: Atherton.

Geis, Gilbert 1972 "Criminal Penalties For Corporate Criminals." Criminal Law Bulletin

8: 377-392.

Geis, Gilbert 1973 "Deterring Corporate Crime" in R. Nader and M. Green (edse),

COrporate Power in America. New York: Grossman: 182-197.

Geis, Gilberc: 1974 "Avcx::ational Crime" in Daniel Glaser (ed.), Handbook of Criminology.

New York: Rand ~ally: 273-298.

Geis, Gilbert 1975 "Victimization Patterns in White-Collar Crime" in Israel DraPtin and

Emilio Viarx> (eds.), Vict:iJoology: A New Fcx::us, 5. Lexington, Mass.: Lexington BoOks: 89-105.

Geis, Gilbert, and Herbert Edelhertz 1973 "Criminal Law and COnsllDer Fraoo: A Sociolegal View. II American

Criminal Law Review 11: 989-1010.

Geis, Gilbert and Robert F. Meier 1977 White-COllar Crime: Offenses in Business, Politics, and the

Professions, rev. ed. New York: Free Press.

Geis, Gilbert and Ezra Stotland, eds. 1980 White-Collar Crime: 'llleoty and Research. Beverly Hills, Calif.:

Sage •.

68

Gibbons, Don C. 1973 "Criminality A100ng 'Respectable Citizens'" in Society, Crime and

Criminal Careers, 200 ed. Engle~ Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall: 324-353.

Gibsoo, Larry 5., and Frank A. ZUMO

1978 "Report to the Attorney General of the National Econanic Crime Project." Washington: U.s. Department of Justice (December).

Gilbert, David 1937 Fraoos, Misrepresentations, Confiscations, Mysteries in Life

Insurance. Philadelphia: Marlowe.

Goff, Colin H. and Charles E. Reasons 1978 Corporate Crime in Canada: A Critical Analysis of Anti-canbines

Legislation. Scarborough, Canada: Prentice-Hall.

Goffman, Erving, 1959 '!he Presentation of self in Everyday Life. Garden City, N.Y.:

Ibubleday.

Graham, George A., and Henry Reining, Jr. 1943 Regulator:y Administration. New York: Wiley.\

Gross, Edward 1958 w;)rk and Society. New York: Crowell.

Groves, Harold M.

1970 "An Empirical Study Qf In<xJ1e-'l'ax Conpliance" in E.rwin O. Snigel and H. Laurence a:,ss (eds.), Crimes Against Bureaucracy. New York: Van Nostrand Reinhold: 86-96.

Hadden, Tan 1967 "The Orig~n and Developnent of Conspiracy to Defraoo." American

Journal of Islal History 11: 25-40.

Hall, Jerane 1935 '!heft, L;:,.w and Society. Indianapolis: Bobbs-Merri11.

Hanp!1, G. 1977 "White Collar Crime •. " Australian Law Joumal 51: 629-634.

Hancock, Ralph, and Henry Chafetz 1968 '!he Coopleat Swindler. New York: Macmi11c:m.

Hannay, William M. 1973 "Introduction. II Anerican Criminal Law Ieview 11: 817-819.

Hartung, Frank E. 1950 "White-Collar Offenses in the Wholesale Meat Iooustry in Detroit."

American Journal of Sociology 56: 25-34.

Hartung, Fl'ank E. 1953 "White Collar. Crime: Its Significance for Theory and Practice."

Federal ProbatiQ1 17: 31-36. .

69

\ , \

Page 40: Abpot .. White Collar.··Crime - National Criminal Justice ... This is Ci substantially revised version of the "~ckgrourrl Paper on White Collar Crime" (Shapiro 1976) which was prepared

, .

Hassan, El Fadil Nayil 1979 Bribety and Corruption in the Sudan. J .S.D. dissertation,. Yale

University.

Hay, George A., and Daniel Kelley 1974 "An Empirical Survey of Price Fixing Conspiracies." Joumal of Law

and Economics 17: 13-39.

Heidenheimer, Arnold J. 1970 Political Corruption. New York: Holt, Rinehart & Winston.

Hellerman, Michael 1977 Wall Street Swindler. Garden City, N.Y.: Doubleday.

Hendrickson, Robert 1976 Ripoffs. New York: Viking.

Herling, John 1962 '!be Great Price Conspiracy: '!be Story of '!be Antitrust Violations in

the Electrical Industty. Washington: I«lbert B. Luee.

Hetman, Edward S. 1975 COnflicts of Interest: Calmercial Bank Trust Departments. New York:

Twentieth Oentury Fund.

Hollingshead, August de Belmont, and Fredrick C. le.ilich 1958 SOcial Class and Mental Illness. New York: W:Uey.

Horvi ~, Paul M. . 1977 IlBanks Need More Scrutiny, Not lobre Laws." washington Post (November

6): Cl, C4 ..

Hutchinson, John 1969 I''lbe Ana~ of Corruption in Trade Unions." looustrial Relations 8:

135-150.

Hutchison, Bdbert A. 1974 Vesco. New York: Praeger.

Hyatt, Jaroos C. and David Ignatius 1978 "Fraoo at GSA Stores Is Only the Beginning of Agency's Troubles."

WeIll Street Journal (Sept:eni>er 13): Iff.

Jacd:Jy, Neil Herman, Peter Nehenkis, am Richatd Eells 1977 Bribery and ExtortiQ'l in WOrld Business: A Study of Cotp)rate

Political Payments Abroad. New York: Maani1lan.

Johnson, ~lohl"l M. and Jack D. J))uglas (eds.) 1978 crime at the Top: Deviance in Business and ,t:he Professions.

Philadelphia: LiWinoott.

Josefhson, Matthew 1934 '!he Robber Barons: '!he Great American capitalists, 1861-1901.

New York: Harcourt, Brace.

70

Kadish, Sanford H. 1963 "Sare Observations on the Use of Criminal Sanctions in Enforcing

Economic Regulations. II Uni versi ty of Chicago Law Review 30: 423-449.

Kahn, Ely Jacques Jr. 1973 Fram: '!he United States Postal Inspection Service and sane of the

Fools and Knaves It Has Known. New York: Harper & ReM.

Katona, George 1945 Price COntrol and Business. Bloanington, Ind.: Principia Press.

Katz, Jack 1977 "Cover-Up and Collective Integrity: On .the Natural Antagonisms of

Authority Internal and External to Organizations. II Social Problems 25: 3-17.

Katz, Jack 1979a "Concerted Ignorance: '!he Social Construction of COver-up. II Urban

Life 8: 293-316.

Ka~,~k , 1979b "Legality and Equality: Plea Bargaining in the Prosecution of

White-Collar and COmoon Crimes." Law and Society Review 13: 431-459.

Katzmann, Robert A. 1980 Regulatoty Bureaucracy: ~be Federal Trade OOmmission and Antitrust

Policy. Cambridge, Mass: MIT Press.

Kennedy, Tan, and Charles E. Simon 1978 An Examination of Questionable Payments and Practices. New York:

Praeger.

Kessler, Friedrich 1943 "Contracts of Adhesion -- Sare Thoughb..o; About Freedan of Contract. 1I

COlumbia Law Review 43: 629-642.

Kinch, Sam, Jr., and Ben Procter 1972 Texas Under a Cloud. Austin, '!'ex.: Jenkins •

Klockars, Carl B. 1974 '!be Professional Fence. New York: Free Press.

Klockars, CarIB. 1977 "White Collar Crime" in Edward sagar in and Fred Montanino (eds.)

Deviants: Voluntaty Actors in a Hostile World. Morristown, N.J.: General Learning Press.

Kneier, Andrew 1976 "Serving Two Masters: A CorIIoon Cause Study of COnflicts of Interest

in the Executive Br~h." Washington: cannon Cause.

Kohlneier, Louis ~~. Jr. 1969 '!be Regulators. New York: Harper & Ib'i.

71

Page 41: Abpot .. White Collar.··Crime - National Criminal Justice ... This is Ci substantially revised version of the "~ckgrourrl Paper on White Collar Crime" (Shapiro 1976) which was prepared

• ;a

Kriesberg, Louis 1956 "National Security and a:mduct in the Steel Gray Market." Social

Forces 34: 268-277.

Kriesberg, SUneon M. 1976 "Decisior'.1lIaking Models and the Control of COrporate Crime." Yale

Law Journal 85: 1091-11:29.

Krisberg, Barry 1975 Crime and Privilege: TcMard a New Criminology. Englewood Cliffs,

N.J.: Prentice-Hall.

Kugel, Yeracmie1, and Gladys W. Gruenberg 1977 International Payoffs: IDilenma for Business. Lexington, Mass:

Lexington Books.

Kwan, Quon Y., Ponnusamy Rajesw,aran, Brian P. Parker, and Menachem Amir 1971 "'!be Role of Criminal is tics in White-Collar Crimes." Journal of

Criminal Law, Criminology and Police Science 62: 434-439.

Kwitny, Jonathan 1973 'lhe Fountain Pen Conspiracy. New York: Kropf.

Lane, Robert E. 1953 "Why Businessmen Violate the Law." Journal of Criminal Law,

Criminology and Police Sicience 44: 151-165.

Lane, Robert E. 1954 '!be Regulation of Busineiss: SOcial Conditions of Government Economic

COntrol. New Haven, COnn~.: Yale University Press.

Lang, Gladys Engel, and Kurt Lang 1961 ''Van J))ren as Victim: Student Reaction." Studies in Public

eannunication 3: 50-58.

Leff, Arthur A. 1976 Swindling and Selling: '][he Story of Legal and Illegal Congallles.

New York: Free Press.

Leonard, William N., and Marvin Glenn Weber 1970 "Autanakers and Dealers: A Study of Criminogenic Market Forces."

Law and Society ~view 4: 407-424.

Levens, G.E. 1964 "101 British White-COllar Criminals." New Society 78: 6-8.

Levine, 'It1eodore A., and Edward D. Herlihy . 1977 "SEC Enforcement Actions." Review of Securi tif;~S Regulation 10:

. 95+-955.

Lewis, John B., and Charles C. Bcllbaugh 1896 Stratagems and COnspiracies to Defraud Life Insurance Oompanies

Bal timore: lvt::Clellan. •

72

Liebholz, Stephan W., and Louis D. Wilson 1974 Users' Guide to COnplter Cr:ine - Its CORrnission, Detection, and

Prevention. Radnor, Penn.: Olilton.

Lipnan, Mark 1973 Stealing: How America's Errployees Are Stealing 'lheir COnpanies

Blind. New York: Harper's Magazine Press.

"List of Changes in GSA Procedures Pales as Panel Hears New Tally of 1978 COrruption. II Wall Street Journal (September 20): 19.

Mack, John A. -1975 '!be Crime Iooustry. Lexington, Mass.: Lexington Books.

Maine Law Review 1976 Special Issue on White Collar Crime. Maine Law review 28: 96-116.

Mann, Kenneth 1978 "Defending White Collar Crime: A Pro:posal for Research Q1 the

Profession and Technique of Protecting White Collar Defendants from the Impact of Criminal Sanctions" (unp.tblished paper).

Mann, Kenneth, Stanton Wheeler, and Austin Sarat 1980 »sentencing the White COllar Offender: Choosing Aroong Alternati\7e

Sanctions." American Criminal Law Review (forthcoming).

Mannheim, Hennann 1946 Criminal Justice and SOcial Reconstruction. London: Routledge &

Kegan Paul.

Mannheim, Hennann 1965 "OUr Criminogenic Society III: White COllar and Other 'Non-working­

Class' Crimes" in Conparative Criminology, 2. lOndon: ~utledge & Kegan Paul: 469-498.

Mathews, Arthur F. 1971 "criminal Prosecutions Under the Fedli2iral Securities Laws and llelated

Statutes: 'Ihe Nature and Developnent of SEX:: Crilninal Cases." George Washington Law Review 39: 901-920.

Mathews, Arthur F. 1975 Effective Defense of SEC Investigations: Laying the Foumation for

Successful Disp\~itim of Subsequent Civil, Mninistrati:-le ard criminal ProceedJongs." EnDry Law Joumal 24: 567-638.

Mauer, David W. 1940 '!be Big COn: '!be Story of the COnfidence Man and the Confidence

Galle. Indianapolis:; Bol:t>s-Merrill •

Maxa, ROOy 1977 Dare To Be Great. New York: f.brrow.

Mayhew, Leon H. 1968 Law and Equal Opportunity: A Study of the Massachusetts Commission

Against Discrimination. cambridge, Mass.: Harvam University Press.

73

Page 42: Abpot .. White Collar.··Crime - National Criminal Justice ... This is Ci substantially revised version of the "~ckgrourrl Paper on White Collar Crime" (Shapiro 1976) which was prepared

• a ;

McClintick David 1977 Stealing From the Rich. New York: M. Evans.

MCCloy, John Jay, Nathan W. Pearson, and Beverly Matthews 1975 Report of the Special Review OommittefJ of the Board of Directors of

Gulf 'Oil Corporation (submitted to the U.S. District Court for the District of Columbia).

McCloy, John Jay, Nathan W. Pearson, and Beverley Matthews 1976 The Great Oil Spill: The Insider Report, Gulf Oil's Bribery and

Political Chicanery. New York: Olelsea House.

McIntosh, Mary 1973 "The GrCMth of RackElteering." EcoI1Ol1W and SOciety 2: 35-69.

McKnight, Gerald 1973 Computer Crime. New Yor.k: Walker.

~tcNew, Bennie B., and Charles L. Prather 1962 Fraoo Control for Comnercial Banks. l!Qrlewood, Ill.: Irwin.

~ier, Robert F. 1975 "Corporate Crime as an Organizational Behavior." Pa-per presented at

the annual meeting of American Society of Criminology. canada: October 30 - November 2.

Meier, l\'Obert F. 1976 "~1hite-Co11~ and COrporate Crime: '!be Nadir of Criminological

Understanding" (unpublished paper).

Merton, Robert K. 1936 "The Unanticipated Consequences of Purposive Social Action."

American Sociological Review 1: 894-904.

Meyer, John C. Jr. 1972 "An Action-Orientation Approach to the Study of Occupational Crime."

Australian and New Zealand Journal of Criminology 5: 35-48.

Mileski, Maureen 1971 "Policing Slum Landlords: An Observation Study of Mninsitrative

COntrol." Ph.D. dissertation, Yale University. '

Miller, Jooith 1979a "Bankers Gird For lobre Nasty Questions. lf New York Times (May 27):

E4. '

Miller, Jooith 1979b "OVerseas Echoes, 1:00." New York Times (June 17): ES.

Miller, Jooith 1979c "S.B.C. Olarges William F. Buckley with Violations of Securities

Law." New York 'Times (Februaty 8): Alff.

Miller, Nonnan C. 1965 '!be Great Salad Oil SWindle. New York: Coward, ~Cann.

74

Mintz, Morton, and Jerry S. Cohen 1971 America, Inc. New York: Dial Press.

Mintz, ftbrton, and Jeny S. Cohen 1976 Power, Inc.: Public and Private Rulers and Hc:rtI to Make them

Accountable. New York: VikiB1 Press.

Moffitt, Donald (ed.)

:<1

1976 SWindledl: Classic Business Fraoos of the Seventies. Prl.flceton, N.J.: Dow Jones Books.

z.t:»rris, Albert 1935 "Criminals of the Upperworld." Criminology. New York: I.ongmans,

Green: 152-158.

Morrison, Peter H. 1978 "SEC Criminal References." ~~view of Securities Regulation 11:

991-996.

Nash, Jay PJJbert 1976 Hustlers and Con Men: An Anne<,",dotal History of the Confidence Man

and His G'ane. New York: M. Evans.

National District Attorneys Association, Econanic Crime Project 1975+ Ecoronic Crime Digest. Washington: U.S. Government Printing

Office.

Nettler, Gwynn 1974 "Embezzlement Without Problems." British Journal of criminology 14:

70-77.

New York, (;Q1I1lission to Investigate Allegations of Police Corruption and the City's Anti-COrruption Procedures (Knag> CQmtission)

1973 carmissicn Report. New York: Braziller.

Newman, Donald J. 1953 "Public Attitooes Tcward a Form of White-Collar crime." Social

Problems 4: 228-232.

Newman, Donald J. 1958 "Whi te-COllar Crime." Law and Conterrporary Pl'Oblems 23: 7J5-753.

!

Newman, Donald J. 1961 "Legal Nonrs and Criminological Definitions" in Jose{:h S" ibucek

(ed.), New York: Philosophical Library: 55-89.

Northwestern Uni versi ty School of Law 1975 "Consltner Protection: New HQpe Following Failum of Civil and

Criminal Remedies." Joumal of Criminal Law and Crimimlogy 66: 271-285.

Ogmn, a:t>ert W. 1973 "'!be Ineffectiveness of the Criminal Sanction in Fra-oo and COrruption

cases: Iosin;J the Battle Against Mlite COllar Crime." American Criminal Law Review 11: 959-988.

75

Page 43: Abpot .. White Collar.··Crime - National Criminal Justice ... This is Ci substantially revised version of the "~ckgrourrl Paper on White Collar Crime" (Shapiro 1976) which was prepared

, './1"'<',.

::;"

Ostermann, Peter, Esther L. Williams, Kevin O'Brien, and Susan Shapiro 1977 White Collar Crime: A Selected Bibliography. Washington: National

Insti tute of Law Enforcement and Criminal Justice, Law Enforcement' Assistance Administration, u.s. Depar.tment of Justice.

Ottenberg, Miriam 1962 . The Federal Investigators. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall.

Parker, Ibnn B. 1976 Crime by Computer. New York. Scriber's.

Pashington, B.P. 1975 "On the Control of Crime and Bribery." Journal of Legal Studies 4:

311-326.

Patrick, Kenneth G. 1972 Perpetual Jeopardy: 'Ihe Texas Gulf Sulphur Affiar: A Olronicle of

Achievement and Misadventure. New York: Macmillan.

Pearce, Frank 1976 Crimes of the PaoIerful: Marxism, crh~, and I:eviance. London:

Pluto Press.

Pecar 1 Janez 1975 IIWhi te Collar Cdme and Social Control." International Journal of

Criminology and Penology 3: 183-199.

Pecora, Ferdinand 1939 Wall Street Under Oath. New York: Simon & Schuster.

J?:apinsky, Harold E. 1974 "From White Collar Crime to Sxploitation: Redefinition of a Field."

Journal of criminal Law and Criminology 65: 225-233.

Perez, Jacob 1978 Corporate Crimin. ~ "ty: A Study of the One Thousand Largest

Industrial Corporations in the U.S.A. Ph.D. dissertation, University of Pennsylvania.

Posner, R~,chard A. 1970 itA Statistical Study of Antitrust Enforcement." Journal of Law and

Economics 13: 365-419.

Practising La~i Institute 1971 White Collar crimes: Defense and Prosecution. New York: Practising

Law I~stitute~

, "( President' 5 COmnission 00 Law Enforcement and Administration of Justice t 1967 '''White-Collar Crime" in Task Force Report: Crime and Its Inpact -

j;2:: :::.r.,:L;, . ~2~~~snent. Washington: U.S. GoIr1>rnment Printing Office,

,:' ,:·.\).'·~/:··,~:TL;;'./~:;t,~~e~lil:>'(JS 1riduStl¥ Links Noted AmJng UoS. Iegulatoty Aides" , .' l';";!'Y'·'/'···::'j, .. ( ;>',~~5:. New York TImeS (5eptentler 1): 36 ..

, • c .. , ,\

Quinney, Earl R. 1964 "The stooy of White COllar Crime: Toward a Reorientation in Theroy

and Research." Journal of Criminal Law, Criminology and Police SCience 55: 208-214.

Quinney, Richard 1963 "Occupational Structure and Criminal Behavior: Prescription

Violations b¥ Retail Pharmacists." SOcial Problems 11: 179-185.

Rabin, Robert L. 1971 "Agency criminal Referrals in the Federal System." Stanford Law

Review 24: 1036-1091.

Robert L. Rabin, 1972 "The Exercise of Discretion b¥ the Justice Department in Handling

Referrals for Criminal Prosecution from Federal Agencies and Departments." Preliminary draft of te1X)rt to the Administrative Conference of the United States.

Raw, Charles, Bruce Page and Godfrey Hodgson 1971 "D:> You Sincerely Want to be Rich?": The Full Story of Bernard

Cornfield and lOS. New York: Viking.

Rawls, Wendell, Jr. 1980a "Bert Lance Facing Fraoo Trial Today." New York Times (January 14):

11.

Rawls, Wendell, Jr. 1980b "~ce Cleared on 9 Fram Counts; Jury Deadlocks on 3 Other

Charges." New York Ti.mes (May 1) Al, B12.

Reckless, Walter C. 1973 "White-Collar Crime" in The Crime Problem, 5th. Englewood Cliffs,

N.J. : Prentice-Hall: 315-344.

Reed, John P., and Robin S. Reed 1974 I'Doctor, Lawyer, Indian Chief: Old Rhymes and New on White Collar

Crime." Australicul and New Zealand Journal of Criminology 7: 145-156.

Reichstein, Kenneth J. '1965 "Ambulance Chasing: A case sttrly of Deviation and Control within the

Legal Profession." SOcial Problems 13: 6-17.

Reisman, Michael 1979 Folded I,ies: Bribety, crusades and Refo:t1J1s. New YOI'k: Free Press.

Re iss, Albert J. Jr. 1966 "The Stooy of Deviant Behavior: Where the Action Is. If Ohio Valley

Sociologist 32: 1-12.

Reiss, Albert J., Jr. 1971 The Police and the Public. New Haven, COnn.: Yale University Ptess.

71 ,

Page 44: Abpot .. White Collar.··Crime - National Criminal Justice ... This is Ci substantially revised version of the "~ckgrourrl Paper on White Collar Crime" (Shapiro 1976) which was prepared

Reiss, 1976

Albert J. Jr. .. IISe ttling the Frontiers of a Pioneer in American Criminology: McKayll in James F. Short, Jr. (ed • ), Del inquency, Crime, arrl SOciety. Chicago: University of Chicago Press: 64-88.

Reiss, Albert J. 'Jr.

Henry

1976 "Surveys of Self-Rerx>rted Delicits" in Albert Biderman (ed.), Crime and the Police: A SymposiLnn. New York: Naibur.g.

Reiss, Albert J. Jr. and Albert D. Biderman 1980 nData SoLlrces on White-COllar Law-Breaking." Washington: National

Institute of Justice, u.S. Department of Justice (forthcoming).

Albert J. Jr., and David J. Bordua Reiss, 1967 "Envirorunent and Organization: A Perspective 00 the Police" in The

Police: Six SOciological Essays. David J. Bordua (ed), New York: 25-55.

Renfrew, Charles B. 1975 "Address." ALI-ABA Course of Study on Defense ()f t'Ji1ite COllar

Crime. Los Angeles (September 26).

Renfrew, Charles B. 1977 "Reflections 00 White-COllar Sentencing. The Paper Label Sentences:

An Evaluation and Critiques. II Yale Law Journal B6: 589-644.

"Rep:>rt on the Role of Sanctions in Tax Conpliance." 1968 Washington: u.S. Government Printing Office.

Robins, Gerald D. 1974 "White Collar Crime and Employee Thefto" Crime and Delinquency 20:

251-262.

Robinson, Kenneth 1976 The Great Arrerican Mail Fraud Trial: USA v. Glenn Turner and F. lee

Bailey. Plainview, N.Y.: Nash.

Robinson, Timothy S. 1977 "Two-Month Spending Spree Leads to GS-5' s Arrest. 1\ Washington Post

(August 9): 1,9.

Rose-Ackerrn:m, Susan \~

1975 "The Economics of Corruption." 187-203.

Journal of Public Economics 4: , "

Rose-Ackerman, Susan 1978 Corruption: A Stooy in Political EconOll¥ ~ New York: Academic.

Rose-Ackerman, Susan n.d.. "COrruption and IDbbying as a Problem in Political Ecol'lOll¥"

(unpublished manuscript).

Ross, Edward Alsworth 1907 "The Criminaloid." Atlantic Monthly 99 (January): 44-50.

78

, . '.

Ibwe, James L. Jr. 1977 "Bank Abuses Are Said Not Widespread.: New York Times (October 18):

113ff.

Russell,Harold F. 1977 Foozles and Frauds. ¥tamonte Springs, Fla: Institute of Internal

Aooitors.

Schelling, Thanas C. 1967 "Economic Analysis and Organized Crime" in Task Force Report:

Orgar:ized, Crime, .~tations and COnsultant's Papers. Washington: Pres~dent s Comnlssl.on on Law Enforcement and Administration of Justice: 114-126.

Schrager, Laura Shill, and James F. Short, Jr. 1978 "Toward a SOciology of Organizational Crime."

407-419.

Schur, Edwin M.

Social Problems 25:

1957 "Sociological Analysis of COnfidence Swindling." Journal of Criminal Law, Criminology and Police Science 48: 296-304.

Schwartz, Richard D., and Sonya Orleans 1967 liOn Legal Sanctions." University of Chicago Law Review 34:

274-300.

Scott, James C. 1972 Coltparative Political Corruption. Englewood Cliffs, N.J c:

Prentice-Hall.

"

Seidler, Lee J., Frederick Andrews and Marc J. Epstein 1977 ~e Equity Funding Papers: The Anatorrw of a Fraud. Santa Barbara:

Wlley.

Seymour, Whitney North, Jr. 1972 Fighting White-COllar Crime. New York: Office of the U.S. Attorney

for the Southern District of New York.

Seymour, Whitney North Jr. 1973 "Soc~al and. E~ical Considerations in Assessing White-Collar Crime."

Amer~can Cr:un~nal Law Review 11: 821-834.

Seymour, Wili tney North Jr. 1975 United States Attorney: An Inside View of "Justice" in AIrerica Under

the Nixon Administration. New York: Morrow.

Shapiro, Susan 1976 "A Se.ckgrouoo Paper on White Collar Crime: COnsiderations of

Conoaptualization -and Future Research" (unpublished monograph).

Shapiro, Susan 1978 li'1'he Disposition of White Collar Illegalities: Prosecutorial

Alternatives in the Enforcement of the Securities Laws." Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Sociological Association, San Francisco (Sept:ettler).

~ j

\ ,

Page 45: Abpot .. White Collar.··Crime - National Criminal Justice ... This is Ci substantially revised version of the "~ckgrourrl Paper on White Collar Crime" (Shapiro 1976) which was prepared

Shapiro, Susan 1980 "Detecting Illega::.ities: A. Perspective on the Control of securities

Violations. " Ph.D. dissertation, Yale University.

Shaplen, Robert 1978 "Annals of Crime: '!he Lockheed In(:ident~" New Yorker: 48ff.

Sheridan Peter J. 1978 ''Whi te-Collar Crime Costs Business $ 40 Bill ion a Year." Occupational

Hazards 38 (June): 41-44.

Sherman, Lawrence W. (ed.) 1974 Police Corruption: A. Sociological Perspective. Garden City, N.Y.:

Anchor.

Sherman, Lawrence W. 1976 "Controlling Police Corruption: Scandal and Organizational Reform."

Ph.D. dissert~tion, Yale Universi~.

Sherman, Lawrence \'1. 1978 Scandal and Reform: Controlling Police Corruption. Berkeley:

Universi~ of California Press.

~)hoemaker, Ibnald, and J):)nald R. South 1974 "White-Collar Crime" in Clifton D. Bryant (ed.) Deviant Behavior.

Chicago: Rand McNally: lS9-200 •.

Si.mpc"..,on, Anthony E. 1977 'nle Literature of Police Corruption. New York: John Jay Press.

Smead.. glmer E. 1969 - 'Governmental Praootion and Regulation of Business. New York:

Appleton-Century-Crofts.

Smigel, Erwin 1943 "Public Attitooes TCMard 'Chiseling' with Reference to Unenployment

Conpensation." American Sociological Review IS :59-67 •

Smigel, Etwin 0., and H. Laurence Ross 1970 Crimes Against Bureaucracy" New York; Van Nest.rand Reinhold ..

Smith, Richard) Austin 1961 "The Incredible Electrical Conspiracy." Fortune 63 (April): 132ft:.

Sobel, Lester A .. (ed.) 1977 Corruption 'in Business. New York: Facts on File.

Soble, Ronald L., and Robert E. DallO$ 1975 'nle Inp:>ssible Dream: '!he Equity Fuooing story, '!he Frau;3 of the

Century. New Yot'k: Putnam.

Sokol, David 1970 Stock Market: Scams, SWindles, aM Scouoorels. los Angeles:

Sherbourne Press.

80

Sorenson, a:i.>ert C. 1950 "Review of Sutherland, White COllar Crime." Journal of Criminal Law,

Criminology and Police Science 41: SO-S2.

Special Task Force to the Secretary of Health, Education and Welfare 1973 Work. in America. Prepared under the auspices of the W. E. Upjohn

Instl tute for E!1ployment Research. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.

Spencer, John C. 1965 "White-COllar Crime" in Tadeusz Grygier, Howard Jones, and John C.

Spencer (eds.), Criminology in Transition. Institute for the Study and Treatment of Delinquency. London: Tavistock: 233-266.

Staw, Barry M., and Eugene Szwajkowski 1975 "'!he Scarcity-Munificence COnponent of Organizational Environm~nts

and the COOmission of Illegal Acts." Administrative Science Quarterly 20: 345-354.

Stessin, Lawrence 1979 "Enployees Don't Take Anti-'Iheft r-t>ves Lightly." New York Times

(March 4): F3.

Stinchcanbe, Arthur L. 1963 "Institutions of Privacy in the Determination of Police

Administrative Practice." American Journal of Sociology 69: 150-160.

Stone, Christopher D. 1975 Where the Law Ends: '!be Social Control of Corporate Behavior. New

York: Harper lie Ra.tI.

, Subcannittee on Acininistrative Procedure of the Senate Comnittee on the Jooiciary, 86th Congress, 2nd Session.

1960 ReIX>rt on Regulatory Agencies to the President Elect. Washington: u.S. Q)verrment Printing Office_ '

r~

Subcomnittee on OVersight and Investigations of the Comnittee Q1 Interstate and Foreign eoornerce of the House of Representatives, 94th COngress, 2nd Session.

1976 Federal Regulation and Regulatory Peform. Washington: u.S. Q)vernment Printing Office.

Sullivan, COlleen 1977 liThe E'uture of Futures Regulation" (4 part series). Washington Post

(October 25-28).

Surface, William 1967 Inside Internal Revenue. New York: Coward, ltt:Cann.

SUtherland, Edwin H. 1940 "White-COllar Criminality." American Sociological Review 5: 1-12.

SUtherland, Edwin H. 1941 "Crime and Business." Annals of the Anerican Ac~ of Political

and SOcial Science 112: 1!2-118. .

·S1

Page 46: Abpot .. White Collar.··Crime - National Criminal Justice ... This is Ci substantially revised version of the "~ckgrourrl Paper on White Collar Crime" (Shapiro 1976) which was prepared

~-~--- ~---- -~ - ----- - --~ -~ -.-- --.r- ------~---.--.--- - .. ---_-

Sutherland, Edwin H. 1945 "ls 'White-Collar Crime' Crime?" American SOciological Review 10:

132-139.

Sutherland" .Edwin H. 1949a White Collar Crime. New York: Holt, Rinehart & Winston.

Sutherland, Edwin H. 1949b tiThe White COllar Criminal" in Vernon C. Branham and Sanuel B. Kutash

(eds.) New York: Philosophical Library: 511-515.

Sutherland, Edwin H. 1956 "Crime of Corporations" in ,Albert Cohen, Alfred Lindesmith, and Karl

Schuessler (eels.), The Sutherlcm3 PaPf'rs. Bloanington: looiana University Press: 78-96.

Taft, Ik>nald R., and Ralpb W. England, Jr. 1964 "White-Collar Crime" in Criminology, 4th ed. New York: Macmillan:

199-207.

Tawan, Paul W. 1947 "Who Is the Criminal?" American SOciological Review 12: 96-102.

Tappan, Paul W. 1960 Crime, ~Justice and Correction. New York: McGraw-Hill.

Taubman, Philip 1979a "carter unit Recomnends Weakening of Bribe Law,," New York Times

(June 12): 01, 015.

Taubman, Philip 1979b "Second Look at Bribery Law." New York Times (June 17): ES.

'lhomforde, Fredrich H. Jr. 1975 "Patterns of Disparity in SEC Mministrative Sanctioning Pratice."

Tennessee Law Review 42: 465-525.

ThCJtlforde ,Fredrich H • Jr. 1976 "Controlling Administrative Sanctions. II Michigan Law Ieview 74:

709-758.

Thaupson, James D. 1962 "Organizations and OUtput Transactions." American Journal of

Sociology 68: 309-324.

Tobias, Andrew 1971 '!he Funny fttlney Game. Olicago: Playboy Press.

Tarpkins, lbrothy C. 1967 "White-Collar Crime - A BibliograPlY." Berkeley Institute of

Governmental Stu:Ues, University of California (reprinted in Practicing Law Institute 1971).

Treadway, James C .. Jr. 1975 wSfX: En£OCC! '1lt Tecl'Ilicp!S: Expanding and Emtic FornB of Ancillary

Relief. W ~tm aid Lee tar Review 32: 637-679.

82

~-

,. _'~':' .'.~', 1'" "" <.:-" _~=~'" .. "" __ -" c, .... ~!...1<.<-~...,<, ... "-'_'r~. ,-r_<

Trout, Daivd , 1975 liThe Inspectors." Journal of the Institute of Bankers 96: 302-6.

Tyler, Harold R. Jr. 1965 liThe Defense of the White Collar Accused. "Americcm Criminal Law

Quarterly 3: 124-128.

Tyler, Harold R. Jr. 1975 "Address. II Aroorican Society of Criminology. Torottto, Canada

(October 31).

VaLghan, Diane, and Giovanna Carlo 1975 "The Appliance Repairman - A Study of Victim-Responsiveness and

Fram.1I Journal of Research in CriIre and Delinquency 12: 153-161.

Vicker, Ray 1973 '!hose Swiss f.bney ~n. New York: Scribner's.

VoId, George B. 1958 "White COllar Crime" in Theoretical Criminology. New York: Oxford:

243-261.

Wagner, Walter 1966 '!be C..olden Fleecers. Garden Ci ty ~ NS.: D::>ubleday.

walton, C. (eo>!) 1977 '!he Ethics. of COrporate Conduct. Englewcx:rl Cliffs, ,N.J.:

Prentice-Hall~

Washburn, Watson, and Edmond S. Delong 1932 . High and LcM Financiers. Indianapolis: Babbs-Merrill.

Watkins, Jom C. Jr. . 1977 "White-Collar Crime, Legal Sanctions, and Social Control: 'Idols of

the Theatre' in Operation. 1I CriIre and Delinquency 23: 290-303.

Weaver, Suzanne 1977 Decision to Prosecute: Organization and Public Policy in the

Antitrust Division. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.

Weinstein, Deena 1978 "Pram in Science. II Paper presented at the annual rooeting of the

American SOciological Association, San Fran~isco (September).

Wells v John A., Manuel F. Cohen, and Ralph H. Demnler 1972 IlReport of the Advisor:y Comnittee on Enforcenent Policies and

Practices. II Washington: United States Securities and Exchange Ccmnission.

Wheeler, Stanton 1976 "Trends and Problems in the Socio~ogical St\X1y of Crhne." SOcial

Problems 23: 525-534.

"

Page 47: Abpot .. White Collar.··Crime - National Criminal Justice ... This is Ci substantially revised version of the "~ckgrourrl Paper on White Collar Crime" (Shapiro 1976) which was prepared

---,.--~------- ..... ~- ---- - --~ . - -- ---.- --

Wheeler, Stanton 1979 "Perplexities in the Sentencing of Price Fixers." Ant'.itr~t Law

Journal (forthcoming).

Whitney, Craig R. 1978 IiIn Soviet Union, Bribes Help to Get a Car, Gat an Apartment and Get

Ahe·ad. " New York Times (May 7): 1, 22.

Wilensky, Harold L. 1967 Orgcmizational Intelligence. New York: Basic Books.

Wilensky, Harold L. 1968 "Orgamizations: Organizational Intelligence" in International

Encyclopedia of the Social Sciences, 11. New YGlrk: Free Press: 319-334.

Wilson, H.H. 1951 COngress: Corruption and Corrprcmise. New York: Rinehart.

Wilson, James Q. 1978 '!be Investigators: Managing FBI and Narcotics Agents. N(~ York:

Basic Books. .

Wilson, Stephen V., and A. Hotlard Matz 1977 "Ct>taining Evidence for Fea~ral Ecoranic Crime Prosecutions: An

OVerview and Analysis of In"'estigative Methods." American Criminal Law Review 14: 651-716.

Zald, l'1ayer N. 1978 liOn the SOcial Control of Industries." Social Forces 57: 79-102.

Zimring, Franklin E., and Gordon J. Hawkins 1973 Deterrence: '!he Legal 'lbreat in Crime COntrol. Chicago: University

of Chicago Press.

*u s ~ PRIII'1'UiCl OFFICE. 1981 341-2.13/1815