6. Productionsites.bu.edu/manove/files/2013/05/MicroSlides4ProductionF05x2.pdf · Possibility...

32
EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 251 6. Production Definition 6.1. Production is the transformation of a vector of commodities into a dierent vector of commodities. Production can be organized in either of two environments: In hierarchical environments: within rms In market environments: between rms Important questions without clear answers: Why do rms exist? What determines their boundaries? Economists understand more about the market environment than about the hierarchical environment. EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 252 We use a simple model of production within the rm in order to generate supply curves. Supply curves are analyzed within the market environment. Definition 6.2. A production activity or y is a vector of inputs (negative) and outputs (positive) that describes a transformation of some goods into others. Definition 6.3. A production set Y R n is the set of all activities that are physically possible to implement.

Transcript of 6. Productionsites.bu.edu/manove/files/2013/05/MicroSlides4ProductionF05x2.pdf · Possibility...

Page 1: 6. Productionsites.bu.edu/manove/files/2013/05/MicroSlides4ProductionF05x2.pdf · Possibility Production 0 z1 y EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 258 •

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 251

6. Production

Definition 6.1. Production is the transformation of a vectorof commodities into a different vector of commodities.

• Production can be organized in either of two environments:In hierarchical environments: within firms

In market environments: between firms

Important questions without clear answers:

◦Why do firms exist?◦What determines their boundaries?

• Economists understand more about the market environment thanabout the hierarchical environment.

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 252

•We use a simple model of production within the firm in order to

generate supply curves.

• Supply curves are analyzed within the market environment.

Definition 6.2. A production activity or y is a vector ofinputs (negative) and outputs (positive) that describes a

transformation of some goods into others.

Definition 6.3. A production set Y ⊂ Rn is the set of allactivities that are physically possible to implement.

Page 2: 6. Productionsites.bu.edu/manove/files/2013/05/MicroSlides4ProductionF05x2.pdf · Possibility Production 0 z1 y EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 258 •

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 253

• Suppose the commodities are given by:⎡⎢⎢⎢⎢⎣ice cream

cheese

milk

sugar

⎤⎥⎥⎥⎥⎦ , and suppose y =⎡⎢⎢⎢⎢⎣2

1

−6−8

⎤⎥⎥⎥⎥⎦ ∈ Y.

• Then it is physically possible to convert 6 units of milk and 8 unitsof sugar into 2 units of ice cream and 1 unit of cheese.

• Real production in modern economies is extraordinarilycomplicated.

• Vectors of inputs and outputs would be very large.

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 254

Think about the economics department at BU:

• Inputs:Professors, each one with different skills, training.

Staff, again, each with different skills, training.

Structure (this building) is specialized.

Equipment, not too important.

• Outputs:Undergraduate

Masters’ training

Doctors’ Training

Research of doctoral students

Research of professors

Page 3: 6. Productionsites.bu.edu/manove/files/2013/05/MicroSlides4ProductionF05x2.pdf · Possibility Production 0 z1 y EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 258 •

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 255

• How could you represent in a vector what we do in the economicsdepartment?

• How could you represent all the possible production activities inthe department, including those that have not been used here?

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 256

• The economists’ model is extremely abstract!• The set Y , below, is the production set.• Y does not contain any points in Rn+ except 0 . Why not?

• Think of the an activity vector y ∈ Y as an arrow from the origin

that indicates a decrease in the stocks of inputs and an increase in

the stocks of outputs.

n+

0Yn−

yn+

0Yn−

y

Page 4: 6. Productionsites.bu.edu/manove/files/2013/05/MicroSlides4ProductionF05x2.pdf · Possibility Production 0 z1 y EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 258 •

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 257

• If a vector of initial resources, z0 , is added to each point in theset Y , a production possibility set (PPS)Y + z0 = {y + z0 | y ∈ Y } is obtained.

• In the diagram below, the activity y transforms the initialresources z0 to the the vector of resources z1 .

0z

Yz +0

Sety Possibilit

Production

0

y1z

0z

Yz +0

Sety Possibilit

Production

0

y1z

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 258

• The PPS lies in Rn+.• Contains all the combinations of commodities that can beobtained in the economy.

• z0 corresponds to 0 in the original production set.• z0 is the vector obtained if no production occurs.

Page 5: 6. Productionsites.bu.edu/manove/files/2013/05/MicroSlides4ProductionF05x2.pdf · Possibility Production 0 z1 y EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 258 •

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 259

The following are commonly assumed to be properties of Y :

Assumption 6.1. Continuity in production: Y is closed.

Assumption 6.2. Inactivity is possible, but there are no freeproducts: Y ∩ R+ = {0}.• You can’t get outputs without using inputs.• But you can do nothing, so 0 ∈ Y

0

}{ zy≤

x

z n+

n−

Y )(xP 0

}{ zy≤

x

z n+

n−

Y )(xP

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 260

• For any x ∈ Y , we define the higher-productivity set, P(x), byP(x) = {y | y ∈ Y , y ≥ x}.As compared with x , all the points in P(x) (except for x itself)either

◦ use smaller amounts of some inputs◦ and/or yield greater amounts of some outputs

0

}{ zy≤

x

z n+

n−

Y )(xP 0

}{ zy≤

x

z n+

n−

Y )(xP

Page 6: 6. Productionsites.bu.edu/manove/files/2013/05/MicroSlides4ProductionF05x2.pdf · Possibility Production 0 z1 y EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 258 •

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 261

Assumption 6.3. Limited productivity:

• Given any x ∈ Y , the higher-productivity set P(x) isbounded. [Missing from M-C, but should be there.]

Assumption 6.4. Free disposability:

• If z ∈ Y , and y ≤ z , then y ∈ Y .• It is always possible to waste inputs.• See graph.

Assumption 6.5. Irreversibility:

• if y ∈ Y , then −y /∈ Y .Can’t turn process around, produce inputs from outputs.

Technical assumption: Labor, energy used in production,

cannot be fully recovered.

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 262

Assumption 6.6. Convexity: Y is a convex set.

• Strong assumption.• Rules out economies of scale.• Graph below violates convexity, shows increasing returns.

0Y

n+

n−

0Y

n+

n−

Page 7: 6. Productionsites.bu.edu/manove/files/2013/05/MicroSlides4ProductionF05x2.pdf · Possibility Production 0 z1 y EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 258 •

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 263

Assumption 6.7. Additivity:

• If x , y ∈ Y , then x + y ∈ Y .Strong assumption.

Rules out diseconomies of scale.

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 264

Assumption 6.8. Y is a convex cone: If x , y ∈ Y , then forα,β > 0 , αx + βy ∈ Y .

• Very strong assumption.• Implies additivity.•Mathematically, Y is closed

under linear combinations.

• Implies constant returns to scale.

Y0

Y0

Page 8: 6. Productionsites.bu.edu/manove/files/2013/05/MicroSlides4ProductionF05x2.pdf · Possibility Production 0 z1 y EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 258 •

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 265

• Replication argument:Production sets have additivity property between two different

production activities if they don’t interfere with one another.

Production activities describe possible transformations, not

resource constraints.

If a production activity exits, then it ought to be possible to

replicate (duplicate) it exactly, as many time as desired.

=⇒ If y ∈ Y , then for any integer n,ny ∈ Y .=⇒ Y has additivity.

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 266

Proposition 6.1. If 0 ∈ Y , and Y is convex and has

additivity, then Y is a convex cone.

Proof. We have:

• By convexity, if y ∈ Y , then for α ∈ [0 , 1 ],αy = αy + (1 − α)0 ∈ Y .

• For α > 1 , find integer n ≥ α.

By additivity, ny ∈ YBy convexity α

nny ∈ Y .

=⇒ αy ∈ Y .• If x , y ∈ Y , then for α,β > 0 , αx ,βy ∈ Y .• By additivity: αx + βy ∈ Y .

Page 9: 6. Productionsites.bu.edu/manove/files/2013/05/MicroSlides4ProductionF05x2.pdf · Possibility Production 0 z1 y EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 258 •

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 267

• Suppose Y ⊂ Rn is convex but not a convex cone.• By assuming that there is a “hidden input,” z , we can create Y 0

that is a convex cone.

• Assume that each y ∈ Y , uses also one unit of z .

• For each y ∈ Y , set y 0 ="y

−1

#.

• Define Y 0 =

"y

−1

# ¯¯α ≥ 0 , y ∈ Y

)⊂ Rn+1 .

• Y 0 is a convex cone.

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 268

Definition 6.4. If there is only one output, q , and a numberof inputs, denoted by the vector z , then if Y is a closed set,

has free disposability with 0 ∈ Y , we define a productionfunction f by

f(z) = max

(q

¯¯"q

−z

#∈ Y

)

Page 10: 6. Productionsites.bu.edu/manove/files/2013/05/MicroSlides4ProductionF05x2.pdf · Possibility Production 0 z1 y EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 258 •

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 269

Definition 6.5. A production set Y exhibits increasingreturns to scale if for any y ∈ Y and α > 1 , there is a pointy 0 > ay with y 0 ∈ Y .

• If you increase the scale of production, then it is possible toincrease productivity.

Definition 6.6. A production set Y exhibits decreasingreturns to scale if for any y ∈ Y and α ∈ (0 , 1), there is apoint y 0 > ay with y 0 ∈ Y .

• If you decrease the scale of production, then it is possible toincrease productivity.

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 270

Definition 6.7. A production set Y exhibits nonincreasingreturns to scale if for any y ∈ Y and α ∈ (0 , 1), ay ∈ Y .

• It is always possible to decrease the scale of production.

Definition 6.8. A production set Y exhibits nondecreasingreturns to scale if for any y ∈ Y and α > 1 , ay ∈ Y .

• It is always possible to increase the scale of production.

Definition 6.9. A production set Y exhibits constantreturns to scale if for any y ∈ Y and α > 0 , ay ∈ Y .

• Nonincreasing and nondecreasing returns to scale.

Page 11: 6. Productionsites.bu.edu/manove/files/2013/05/MicroSlides4ProductionF05x2.pdf · Possibility Production 0 z1 y EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 258 •

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 271

Proposition 6.2. Let f (x) with x ∈ Rn+ be a concaveproduction function. Define a hidden input z ∈ R+ and a

production function

F (X, z) ≡ zfµ1

zX

¶.

Then F is concave, has constant returns to scale, and

F (x , 1) ≡ f (x).

• The quantityx ≡ 1

zX

should be interpreted as the quantity of X per unit of the hidden

input.

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 272

• If you think of the hidden input z as management, this says thateach separate unit of managment can operate the production

process described by f (x).

• Therefore, a total of z units of management and X = z x units ofthe original input gives us zf (x) units of output.

• This suggests that if a production function has decreasing returnsto scale, it is because of a hidden input that is not increased as

the scale of production increases.

Page 12: 6. Productionsites.bu.edu/manove/files/2013/05/MicroSlides4ProductionF05x2.pdf · Possibility Production 0 z1 y EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 258 •

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 273

• Once the hidden input is introduced, the new production functionis concave and has constant returns to scale.

• Equivalently, the set under the graph of the new productionfunction is a convex cone.

,x X

z

0

( )f x( ),F X z

1,x X

z

0

( )f x( ),F X z

1

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 274

0

,x X

z

( )f x( ),F X z

1

0

,x X

z

( )f x( ),F X z

1

0

,x X

z

( )f x( ),F X z

1

0

,x X

z

( )f x( ),F X z

1

Page 13: 6. Productionsites.bu.edu/manove/files/2013/05/MicroSlides4ProductionF05x2.pdf · Possibility Production 0 z1 y EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 258 •

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 275

Proof. We have

F (αX,αz) = αzf

µ1

αzαX

¶= αF (X, z) ,

which proves that F has constant returns to scale. In addition,

letting X 00 ≡ αX +(1 − α)X 0 and z 00 ≡ αz +(1 − α) z 0, we have

F (X 00, z 00) ≡ z 00fµ1

z 00X 00

¶≡ z 00f

µα

z 00X +

1 − α

z 00X 0¶

= z 00fµαz

z 001

zX +

(1 − α) z 0

z 001

z 0X 0¶.

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 276

And becauseαz

z00+(1− α) z0

z00= 1,

the concavity of f now implies:

F (X 00, z 00) ≥ αz

z 00z 00f

µ1

zX

¶+(1 − α) z 0

z 00z 00f

µ1

z 0X 0¶

≥ αzf

µ1

zX

¶+ (1 − α) z 0f

µ1

z 0X 0¶

= αF (X , z ) + (1 − α)F (X 0, z 0) ,

which proves that F is concave.

Page 14: 6. Productionsites.bu.edu/manove/files/2013/05/MicroSlides4ProductionF05x2.pdf · Possibility Production 0 z1 y EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 258 •

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 277

6.1 Profit Maximization and Cost Minimization

Definition 6.10. A firm is a price-taker if it assumes that allprices are fixed and that its own actions will have no effect onprices.

• This makes sense when a firm is very small compared to the size

of the market.

• For now, assume that firms are price-takers.•We also assume that there are n goods and that all productionsets Y are closed, contain 0 ,and have free disposability.

• Let Rn++ ≡ {p À 0}.

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 278

Definition 6.11. A firm’s profit-maximization problem(PMP) is:

maxy{py | y ∈ Y }

Definition 6.12. Suppose the PMP has a solution for every

p À 0 . Then, the profit function π : Rn++→ R is given by

π(p) ≡ maxy{py | y ∈ Y }

and the supply correspondence, by

y(p) ≡ argmaxy

{py | y ∈ Y }.

• Note: y is both the supply of outputs and the derived demand forinputs.

Page 15: 6. Productionsites.bu.edu/manove/files/2013/05/MicroSlides4ProductionF05x2.pdf · Possibility Production 0 z1 y EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 258 •

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 279

• Suppose there is one output q and a vector of inputs z , withscalar p > 0 the price of the output, and w À 0 the vector ofinput prices. Then, the profit function is given by:

π(p,w) = maxz{pf(z)−wz | z ≥ 0}

• and z , the derived demand for inputs, byz(p,w) = argmax

z{pf(z)−wz | z ≥ 0}.

with the supply of output given by

q(p,w) = f(z(p,w)).

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 280

• From Kuhn-Tucker we know that

p∂f

∂zj= wj for zj(p,w) > 0

and

p∂f

∂zj≤ wj for zj(p,w) = 0

• This says that the value of the marginal product of an input mustequal its price if the input is used and must be less or equal to its

price if the input is not used.

Page 16: 6. Productionsites.bu.edu/manove/files/2013/05/MicroSlides4ProductionF05x2.pdf · Possibility Production 0 z1 y EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 258 •

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 281

Proposition 6.3. If Y has nondecreasing returns to scale

(which includes the case of constant returns to scale), then

π(p) is not defined for some p À 0 .

Proof. Suppose y ∈ Y with y £ 0 .

• Choose p À 0 such that py > 0 .

To do this choose pi small for yi < 0 , large for yi > 0 .

• For any α > 1 , αy ∈ Y .• p(αy) = α(py)→∞ as α→∞.• By definition

π(p) ≡ maxy{py | y ∈ Y },

but py is unbounded for y ∈ Y , so the maximum doesn’t exist.

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 282

• In what follows, we assume that π(p) is defined for all p À 0 ,and that Y is closed, contains 0 , and satisfies free disposal.

Proposition 6.4. π is homogeneous of degree 1 and convexin prices.

Proof. The proof of homogeneity is the same as for theexpenditure function. For convexity:

• Suppose p, p 0 À 0 ,α ∈ [0 , 1 ] and p 00 = αp + (1 − α)p 0.

• For y 00 ∈ y(p 00) we haveπ(p 00) = p 00y 00

= αpy 00 + (1 − α)p 0y 00

≤ απ(p) + (1 − α)π(p 0). [Why?]

Page 17: 6. Productionsites.bu.edu/manove/files/2013/05/MicroSlides4ProductionF05x2.pdf · Possibility Production 0 z1 y EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 258 •

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 283

•What is the economic interpretation of the convexity of the profitfunction?

The average of profits at two different prices is at least as much

as profits at the average prices.

Profits are higher at extreme prices than at average prices.

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 284

6.2 The separating hyperplane theorem andduality in production.

• Suppose you have a production set and a point outside theproduction set.

• How can you find a price vector that makes the outside pointmore profitable than any point in the production set?

• The separating hyperplane theorem answers that question.

Page 18: 6. Productionsites.bu.edu/manove/files/2013/05/MicroSlides4ProductionF05x2.pdf · Possibility Production 0 z1 y EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 258 •

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 285

Definition 6.13. The set

Hp,x0 ≡ {x |x and x0 ∈ Rn, p(x− x0) = 0}is a hyperplane of dimension n − 1 orthogonal to p through thepoint x0 .

• A hyperplane is the union of all lines orthogonal to a fixed vectorand passing through a given point.

• The budget frontier is a hyperplane orthogonal to the price vectorand passing through a any point x0 , such that px0 = w .

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 286

Proposition 6.5. (Separating Hyperplane Theorem) IfB ⊂ Rn is convex and closed, and if s /∈ B, then

• there is a hyperplane H of dimension n − 1 such that B lies

on one side of H and s lies on the other;

•more precisely, there is some x0 and p 6= 0 , such that for allb ∈ B, pb ≤ px0 < ps.

0x

sp

0,p xHB

0x

sp

0,p xHB

Page 19: 6. Productionsites.bu.edu/manove/files/2013/05/MicroSlides4ProductionF05x2.pdf · Possibility Production 0 z1 y EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 258 •

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 287

Proof.

• Let x0 be the closest point in B to s.

[How do we know that a “closest point” exists? See the

problem set.]

• set p ≡ s − x0• so that 0 < p · p = p(s − x0).• Therefore px0 < ps.

• Suppose for some y ∈ B, py > px0 .

• Then p(y − x0) > 0 .

• Set x 0 = αy + (1 − α)x0 where α ∈ (0 , 1).• By convexity, x 0 ∈ B.

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 288

0x

sp

By

'x

0,p xH

0x

sp

By

'x

0,p xH

•We show that for small enough α, x 0 is closer to s than x0 is, acontradiction:

s − x 0 = s − αy − (1 − α)x0= (s − x0)− α(y − x0)= p − α(y − x0)

Page 20: 6. Productionsites.bu.edu/manove/files/2013/05/MicroSlides4ProductionF05x2.pdf · Possibility Production 0 z1 y EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 258 •

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 289

so that for very small α we have,

ks − x 0k2 = (s − x 0)(s − x 0)= (s − x0)(s − x0)+α2(y − x0)(y − x0)−2αp(y − x0)

< ks − x0k2 [Why?]

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 290

Definition 6.14. The dual production set Y 0 of a productionset Y is given by

Y 0 = {y | py ≤ π(p) for all pÀ 0},where π (p) is the profit function derived from Y .

• The dual production set is bounded by the lower envelope of thehyperplanes defined by the various price vectors and points on the

output axis as shown in the drawing below.

Y ′ 1p

2p3p

4p

x

y

1H

2H

4H

3H

( )4

4y

pp

π

( )2

2y

pp

π

( )1

10

y

pp

π≡

( )3

3y

pp

π

Y ′ 1p

2p3p

4p

x

y

1H

2H

4H

3H

( )4

4y

pp

π

( )2

2y

pp

π

( )1

10

y

pp

π≡

( )3

3y

pp

π

Page 21: 6. Productionsites.bu.edu/manove/files/2013/05/MicroSlides4ProductionF05x2.pdf · Possibility Production 0 z1 y EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 258 •

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 291

• For many commonly used production functions, the profit functionis undefined at price vectors p that contain input prices equal to0 .

Example 6.1. Consider the production function q (`) = 2√`,

where ` is the input of labor.

• Let the price of output be 1 and let w denote the wage rate,

so that π = 2√`− w`.

• The demand for labor ` (w) is unbounded at w = 0 , andπ (0) is undefined.

• But for all w > 0 , we have ` (w) = 1/w2 , and

π (w) = 2/w − 1/w = 1/w .

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 292

Problem 6.1. Prove more generally that for well-behavedhomogeneous production functions with decreasing returns to

scale, π (p) is defined for all p À 0 but is generally undefinedat price vectors p that contain zero prices for one or moreinputs.

• For this reason, it makes sense to define the dual production setin terms of p À 0 .

Page 22: 6. Productionsites.bu.edu/manove/files/2013/05/MicroSlides4ProductionF05x2.pdf · Possibility Production 0 z1 y EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 258 •

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 293

Proposition 6.6. (Duality Theorem for Production Sets).

Let Y 0 be the dual dual production set of Y . If Y closed,

contains 0 , has free disposability and is convex, then Y 0 = Y .

• The theorem says that just as you can derive the profit function

from the technology, so you can find the technology from

knowledge of the profit function.

Proof.

• First, suppose y ∈ Y .Because π(p) = max{py | y ∈ Y }, we have py ≤ π(p) for allp À 0 .

Therefore y ∈ Y 0, so that Y ⊂ Y 0.

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 294

• Now suppose y /∈ Y .

Define vectors of the form δj ≡

⎡⎢⎢⎢⎢⎣δ

δ

−1δ

⎤⎥⎥⎥⎥⎦, where δ > 0 and −1 is

the j th component.

Set Y = Y +Pαjδj for all αj ≥ 0 .

Note that as δ goes to 0 , Y looks more and more like Y .

Set δ small enough so that y /∈ Y .

Page 23: 6. Productionsites.bu.edu/manove/files/2013/05/MicroSlides4ProductionF05x2.pdf · Possibility Production 0 z1 y EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 258 •

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 295

0Y

Y

n+

n−

Y

Y

y p

0Y

Y

n+

n−

Y

Y

y p

Apply separating-hyperplane theorem to Y and y .

Find p and x0 such that px ≤ px0 < py for all x ∈ Y .Note p À 0 . Why?

π(p) ≤ px0 < py

y /∈ Y 0.

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 296

Proposition 6.7. (From M-C 5.C.1. pp. 138.) Suppose Y is

closed, contains 0 , and has the free-disposal property, andsuppose π is defined for all p À 0 .

i). the supply (and derived demand) relation y(·) ishomogeneous of degree 0.

ii). If Y is convex, then for each p, the set y(p) is convex.

iii). If Y is strictly convex, then y(·) is a function.iv). (Hotelling’s Lemma) If y(p) is a single point, then the

profit function π is differentiable at p and y(p) = ∇π(p).v). If y(·) is a function and is differentiable at p, then

∂y(p)/∂p is a symmetric positive-semidefinite matrix with

∂y(p)

∂pp = 0.

Page 24: 6. Productionsites.bu.edu/manove/files/2013/05/MicroSlides4ProductionF05x2.pdf · Possibility Production 0 z1 y EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 258 •

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 297

• The proofs are similar to the corresponding proofs for theexpenditure function.

• There are no income or wealth effects with supply and deriveddemand.

• Inputs are purchased, converted to outputs and then sold, allsimultaneously.

• No wealth is required in these models.

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 298

Proposition 6.8. (Law of Supply) Suppose y(·) is a supply(derived demand) function. Then for any two price vectors p 0

and p À 0 ,we have

(p0 − p)(y(p0)− y(p)) ≥ 0.

Proof. Because y(p) maximizes profits at prices p, we know that

p0y(p0) ≥ p0y(p)and

py(p) ≥ py(p0)

• If only one price changes, then the corresponding quantitychanges in the same direction

• Because ∂y(p)/∂p is a symmetric positive-semidefinite matrix,own-price elasticity of supply is positive, and that of derived

demand is negative (why?).

Page 25: 6. Productionsites.bu.edu/manove/files/2013/05/MicroSlides4ProductionF05x2.pdf · Possibility Production 0 z1 y EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 258 •

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 299

• Suppose we are given a production set Y and a price vector p.

• Sequential maximization is possible.We can find a short-run profit function holding capital fixed, ...

and from that we can find a long-run profit function allowing

capital to vary.

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 300

Example 6.2. Suppose the technology is defined by

Y =

⎧⎪⎨⎪⎩⎡⎢⎣ q

−k−`

⎤⎥⎦¯¯ k, ` ≥ 0 and q ≤ √k`

⎫⎪⎬⎪⎭ ,and suppose p, r and w , are the prices of q , k and `. Then findthe short- and long-run profit functions if k is fixed in the shortrun.

• The short-run passive profit function is:π (p, r, w | k) = max

`

np√k`− rk −w`

o[Why don’t we have to maximize over q?]

Page 26: 6. Productionsites.bu.edu/manove/files/2013/05/MicroSlides4ProductionF05x2.pdf · Possibility Production 0 z1 y EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 258 •

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 301

• The foc is0 =

∂π

∂`=p

2

rk

`−w

so that

` =k

4

,µw

p

¶2.

• Substituting into the passive profit function givesπ (p, r ,w | k) =

hp√k`− rk − w`

i`=k

4

.(wp )

2

=

µp2

4w− r

¶k .

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 302

•What happens ifp2

4w< r ?

• The long-run profit function is

π (p, r, w) = maxk

µp2

4w− r

¶k = ???

Page 27: 6. Productionsites.bu.edu/manove/files/2013/05/MicroSlides4ProductionF05x2.pdf · Possibility Production 0 z1 y EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 258 •

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 303

6.3 Cost Minimization

• If some commodities are always inputs and others are alwaysoutputs, then we can break the profit maximization problem into

two parts:

The minimization of costs over input vectors z conditional onthe output vector q .

The maximization of profits over all output vectors q .

• Similar to short-run and long-run profits, above.• For simplicity we assume that there is only one output q .• Let q = f (z ) be the production function, p, the price of theoutput, and w , the vector of input prices.

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 304

Definition 6.15. The passive cost function is defined byCP(z |w) = wz .

• The passive cost function adds up the cost of the shopping list.• It is of no use unless you know z .•We would like to know how much it cost to produce a givenquantity of output.

Definition 6.16. The cost minimizationproblem (CMP) is

minzCP(z |w)

s.t. f (z ) ≥ qz ≥ 0

Page 28: 6. Productionsites.bu.edu/manove/files/2013/05/MicroSlides4ProductionF05x2.pdf · Possibility Production 0 z1 y EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 258 •

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 305

Definition 6.17. The cost function c(w | q) is the solution ofCMP, that is

c(w | q) = minz≥0

{wz | f(z) ≥ q}.

Definition 6.18. The conditional derived-demand functionz (w | q) solves the CMP, that is

z(w | q) = argminz≥0

{wz | f(z) ≥ q}.

Proposition 6.9. The profit function is given by

π(p,w) = maxq{pq −wz(w | q)}

Proof. Apply sequential maximization.

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 306

• If w is assumed fixed and q is assumed variable, then we use:

Definition 6.19. The total cost function is defined byC (q) = c(w | q).Definition 6.20. The marginal cost function is defined byMC(q) ≡ C 0(q).

Definition 6.21. The average cost function is defined byAC(q) ≡ C (q)/q .Proposition 6.10. Suppose q∗ > 0 minimizes AC(q). ThenMC(q∗) = AC(q∗).

•Why?

Page 29: 6. Productionsites.bu.edu/manove/files/2013/05/MicroSlides4ProductionF05x2.pdf · Possibility Production 0 z1 y EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 258 •

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 307

Proposition 6.11. (M-C.5.C.2) Suppose that c(w , q) is thecost function of a single-output technology Y , closed with freedisposal and with production function f (z ), and suppose thatz (w | q) is the associated derived-demand correspondence.Then

i). c(w | q) is homogeneous of degree 1 in w and nondecreasing

in q .

ii). c(w | q) is a concave function of w .iii). (Duality theorem for cost functions) If {z | z ≥ 0 , f (z ) ≥ q}

is convex for every q , then

Y = {(−z, q) |wz ≥ c(w | q) for all wÀ 0}.

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 308

iv). z (w | q) is homogeneous of degree 0 in w .v). If {z | z ≥ 0 , f (z ) ≥ q} is convex, then z (w | q) is convex. If

{z | z ≥ 0 , f (z ) ≥ q} is strictly convex then z (w | q) issingle valued. If {z | z ≥ 0 , f (z ) ≥ q} is strictly convex forall q , then z is a function.

vi). (Shepard’s Lemma) If z (w | q) is a function, then c(w | q) isdifferentiable, and

∇wc(w | q) ≡ z(w | q).

Page 30: 6. Productionsites.bu.edu/manove/files/2013/05/MicroSlides4ProductionF05x2.pdf · Possibility Production 0 z1 y EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 258 •

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 309

vii). If z (w | q) is differentiable, then∂z(w | q)

∂w≡ ∂2c(w | q)

∂w2

so that ∂z (w | q)/∂w is a symmetric negative-semidefinite

matrix with∂z(w | q)

∂ww = 0.

viii). If f (z ) is homogeneous of degree 1 (has constant returns toscale), then so are c(w | q) and z (w | q) in q .

ix). If f (z ) is concave, then C (q) is a convex function of q (MCis increasing).

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 310

Example 6.3. Find conditional derived demand, the costfunction, supply and the profit function when

Q ≡ F(K ,L) ≡ AKαL1−α, where 0 < α < 1 , with pricesp, r ,w .

• Both capital and labor must be used to obtain positive output.• Therefore

∂F

∂Kr

=

∂F

∂Lw

AαL1−α

rK1−α =A (1 − α)Kα

wLα

wL

1 − α=rK

α

K =α

1 − α

w

rL.

• This shouldn’t be surprising, because with a Cobb-Douglasproduction function, the share of expenses for labor and capital

must be proportional to the exponents.

Page 31: 6. Productionsites.bu.edu/manove/files/2013/05/MicroSlides4ProductionF05x2.pdf · Possibility Production 0 z1 y EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 258 •

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 311

• Substituting into the production function yields the conditionalderived demands:

Q = A

µα

1 − α

w

r

¶αL

L∗ =1

A

µ1 − α

α

¶αµ rw

¶αQ

K ∗ =1

A

µα

1 − α

¶1−αµwr

¶1−αQ.

• Therefore the cost function isC (r ,w ,Q) = rK ∗ + wL∗

C (r ,w ,Q) = Arαw1−αQ

where

A =1

A

µ1− α

α

¶α+1

A

µα

1− α

¶1−α.

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 312

•We haveAC =MC = Arαw1−α

• If p < AC , nothing will be produced and profits are zero.

• If p > AC , production will be unbounded and so will profits.

Page 32: 6. Productionsites.bu.edu/manove/files/2013/05/MicroSlides4ProductionF05x2.pdf · Possibility Production 0 z1 y EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 258 •

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 313

6.4 Do firms behave according to theneoclassical model?

• Profit maximization may share some of the same problems asutility maximization.

The maximization problem is very difficult

◦ Firms don’t know their costs.◦ Firms don’t know which production activities are possible.Questions of psychology

◦ Entrepreneurs are biased by optimism and hubris.

◦ Time inconsistencies

EC 701, Fall 2005, Microeconomic Theory October 31, 2005 page 314

• Firms have problems that individuals do not.Principal/agent questions.

◦ How to get workers to work hard?◦ How to get managers to pursue the interests of the firm’sowners?

· Problems of managerial control of firms.· Private benefits.

Owners of firms may maximize their utility rather than profits.

◦ Risk aversion.