EJTP · 2008. 5. 17. · some scalar field , a non-minimal coupling between the scalar curvature...

159
Volume 3 Number 11 Electronic Journal of Theoretical Physics ISSN 1729-5254 EJTP Editors Ammar Sakaji Ignazio Licata http://www.ejtp.com June, 2006 E-mail:[email protected]

Transcript of EJTP · 2008. 5. 17. · some scalar field , a non-minimal coupling between the scalar curvature...

  • Volume 3 Number 11

    Electronic Journal of Theoretical Physics

    ISSN 1729-5254

    EJTP

    Editors

    Ammar Sakaji Ignazio Licata

    http://www.ejtp.com June, 2006 E-mail:[email protected]

  • Volume 3 Number 11

    Electronic Journal of Theoretical Physics

    ISSN 1729-5254

    EJTP

    Editors

    Ammar Sakaji Ignazio Licata

    http://www.ejtp.com June, 2006 E-mail:[email protected]

  • Editor in Chief

    A. J. Sakaji

    EJTP Publisher P. O. Box 48210 Abu Dhabi, UAE [email protected] [email protected]

    Editorial Board

    Co-Editor

    Ignazio Licata,Foundations of Quantum Mechanics Complex System & Computation in Physics and Biology IxtuCyber for Complex Systems Sicily – Italy

    [email protected]@ejtp.info [email protected]

    Wai-ning Mei Condensed matter TheoryPhysics DepartmentUniversity of Nebraska at Omaha,

    Omaha, Nebraska, USA e-mail: [email protected] [email protected]

    Tepper L. Gill Mathematical Physics, Quantum Field Theory Department of Electrical and Computer Engineering Howard University, Washington, DC, USA e-mail: [email protected]

    [email protected]

    F.K. DiakonosStatistical Physics Physics Department, University of Athens Panepistimiopolis GR 5784 Zographos, Athens, Greece e-mail: [email protected]

    Jorge A. Franco Rodríguez

    General Theory of Relativity Av. Libertador Edificio Zulia P12 123 Caracas 1050 Venezuela e-mail: [email protected] [email protected]

    J. A. MakiApplied Mathematics School of Mathematics University of East Anglia Norwich NR4 7TJ UK e-mail: [email protected]

    [email protected]

    Nicola Yordanov Physical Chemistry Bulgarian Academy of Sciences,BG-1113 Sofia, Bulgaria Telephone: (+359 2) 724917 , (+359 2) 9792546

    e-mail: [email protected]

    ndyepr[AT]bas.bg

    S.I. ThemelisAtomic, Molecular & Optical Physics Foundation for Research and Technology - Hellas P.O. Box 1527, GR-711 10 Heraklion, Greece e-mail: [email protected]

    T. A. HawaryMathematics Department of Mathematics Mu'tah University P.O.Box 6 Karak- Jordan e-mail: [email protected]

    Arbab Ibrahim Theoretical Astrophysics and Cosmology Department of Physics, Faculty of Science, University of Khartoum, P.O. Box 321, Khartoum 11115, Sudan

    e-mail: [email protected] [email protected]

  • Sergey Danilkin Instrument Scientist, The Bragg Institute Australian Nuclear Science and Technology Organization PMB 1, Menai NSW 2234 AustraliaTel: +61 2 9717 3338 Fax: +61 2 9717 3606

    e-mail: [email protected]

    Robert V. Gentry The Orion Foundation P. O. Box 12067 Knoxville, TN 37912-0067 USAe-mail: gentryrv[@orionfdn.org

    [email protected]

    Attilio Maccari Nonlinear phenomena, chaos and solitons in classic and quantum physics Technical Institute "G. Cardano" Via Alfredo Casella 3 00013 Mentana RM - ITALY

    e-mail: [email protected]

    Beny Neta Applied Mathematics Department of Mathematics Naval Postgraduate School 1141 Cunningham Road Monterey, CA 93943, USA

    e-mail: [email protected]

    Haret C. Rosu Advanced Materials Division Institute for Scientific and Technological Research (IPICyT) Camino a la Presa San José 2055 Col. Lomas 4a. sección, C.P. 78216 San Luis Potosí, San Luis Potosí, México

    e-mail: [email protected]

    A. AbdelkaderExperimental Physics Physics Department, AjmanUniversity Ajman-UAE e-mail: [email protected]

    [email protected]

    Leonardo Chiatti Medical Physics Laboratory ASL VT Via S. Lorenzo 101, 01100 Viterbo (Italy) Tel : (0039) 0761 236903 Fax (0039) 0761 237904

    e-mail: [email protected]

    [email protected]

    Zdenek Stuchlik Relativistic Astrophysics Department of Physics, Faculty of Philosophy and Science, Silesian University, Bezru covo n´am. 13, 746 01 Opava, Czech Republic

    e-mail: [email protected]

    Copyright © 2003-2006 Electronic Journal of Theoretical Physics (EJTP) All rights reserved

  • Table of Contents

    No Articles Page

    1 Non-Minimal Coupling Effects of the Ultra-Light Particles on Photons Velocities in the Radiation Dominated Era of the Universe. El-Nabulsi Ahmad Rami

    1

    2 A Toy Model of Financial Markets J. P. Singh and S. Prabakaran

    11

    3 Rayleigh process and matrix elements for the one-dimensional harmonic oscillator J.H. Caltenco, J.L. López-Bonilla, and J. Morales

    29

    4 Identical synchronization in chaotic jerk dynamical systemsVinod Patidar and K. K. Sud

    33

    5 Second Order Perturbation of Heisenberg Hamiltonian for Non-Oriented Ultra-Thin Ferromagnetic Films P. Samarasekara

    71

    6 Frameable Processes with Stochastic Dynamics Enrico Capobianco

    85

    7 Ab-initio Calculations for Forbidden M1/E2 Decay Rates in Ti XIX ion A. Farrag

    111

    8 Some Properties of Generalized Hypergeometric Thermal Coherent States Dusan Popov

    123

    9 Space-Filling Curves for Quantum Control Parameters Fariel Shafee

    133

    10 The Spectrum of the Lagrange Velocity Autocorrelation Function in Confined Anisotropic LiquidsSakhnenko Elena I and Zatovsky Alexander V.

    143

    11 On the Quantum Correction of Black Hole ThermodynamicsKourosh Nozari and S. Hamid Mehdipour

    151

    12 A Graphic Representation of States for Quantum CopyingSara Felloni and Giuliano Strini

    159

  • EJTP 10 (2006) 1–10 Electronic Journal of Theoretical Physics

    Non-Minimal Coupling Effects of the Ultra-LightParticles on Photons Velocities in the Radiation

    Dominated Era of the Universe

    El-Nabulsi Ahmad Rami ∗

    Plasma Application Laboratory, Department of Nuclear andEnergy Engineering and Faculty of Mechanical, Energy and Production Engineering,

    Cheju National University, Ara-dong 1, Jeju 690-756,Korea

    Received 6 September 2005 , Accepted 27 November 2005, Published 25 May 2006

    Abstract: The effect of the ultra-light masses of the order of the Hubble constant, implementedin Einstein’s field equations from non-minimal coupling and supergravities arguments, onphotons velocities in the radiation dominated epoch of the Universe within the frameworkof non-minimal interaction of electromagnetic fields with gravity is developed and discussed indetails.c© Electronic Journal of Theoretical Physics. All rights reserved.

    Keywords: Non-minimal coupling, ultra-light masses, effective cosmological constant, photonsvelocity.PACS (2006): 04.40 Nr, 98.80 -k, 95.30 SI

    1. Introduction

    A standard result of Einstein’s gravity is that massless particles, in particular photons,

    move at light celerity ‘c’. A question worth examining is whether the velocity of massless

    photons is shifted when these later propagate in exotic background filled of ultra-light

    particles (ULP) of tiny masses in the order of the Hubble constant (m ≈ H). This couldhave important cosmological and astrophysical implications. In fact, the possibility of

    shifting photon propagation (SPP) in gravitational fields (or non-trivial topologies) is

    an interesting prediction of quantum field theory in curved space-time. It appears that

    photon propagation may depend on their direction and polarisation, travel with speeds

    exceeding the normal speed of light ‘c’ [1]. It is a quantum effect induced by vacuum

    [email protected]

  • 2 Electronic Journal of Theoretical Physics 10 (2006) 1–10

    polarisation (allowing the photons to exist as a virtual e+e−pair so that at the quantumlevel it is characterized by the Compton wavelength of the electron) and implies that

    the Principle of Equivalence does not hold for interacting quantum field theories such

    as QED. The propagation of photon in Schwarzschild, Robertson-Walker, gravitational

    wave, de Sitter backgrounds, charged black hole were done and remarkable results were

    discovered [2]. In each case (except the totally isotropic de Sitter space-time) it was

    possible to find directions and polarisations for which the photon velocity exceeds ‘c’.

    Generalization to neutrino propagation in a Robertson-Walker metric using the Weinberg-

    Salam model was done in [3]. In a gravitational field, the photon propagation is sensitive

    to an anisotropic space-time curvature and may depend on this later [4,5]. Recently,

    a series of papers has appeared in which the light velocity varies in the early Universe

    and this solves the horizon, monopole and the flatness problems in standard cosmology

    [6,7,8,9]. In this work, we will investigate further the consequences of non-minimal

    coupling on light velocity in the presence of ultra-light particles.

    2. Non-minimal Coupling, Supergravities Arguments and Ein-

    stein Fields Equations

    We start with the non-minimal interaction of electromagnetic fields with gravity in the

    following form L̃ =√

    gξRμνFμα F

    νμ, ξ being the coupling constant, Rμν the Riemann

    tensor, g the metric scalar and Fμν = ∂μAν −∂νAμ is the electromagnetic strength (Aμ isthe vector potential). Terms like RF 2 are neglected here. In this way, the field equations

    read [10,11,12]:

    Dν [Fμν − 2ξ (RμαFαν − RναFαμ)] = 0

    where Dν is the covariant derivative. Let us now restrict our attention to the form of the

    Riemann tensor we will choose for this work. In a recent paper [13], we introduced, for

    some scalar field , a non-minimal coupling between the scalar curvature and the density of

    the scalar field in the following form L = −ξ√gRφ∗φ, ξ = 1/6 . R is the scalar curvatureand is the complex conjugate of . From a view point of quantum field theory in curved

    space-time, it is natural to consider such a non-minimal coupling. In fact, the conformal

    case results in an extension of the property of conformal invariance for massless fields,

    which is attractive from physical point of view. This parameter describes the strength

    of the coupling between the curvature of spacetime and the inflation. Minimal coupling

    corresponds to ξ = 0. It was shown that in this case and for a particular scalar negative

    complex potential field V (φφ∗) = 3/4m2(ωφ2φ∗2 − 1),ω being a tiny parameter inspiredfrom supergravity inflation theories, ultra-light masses ‘m’ are implemented naturally in

    Einstein field equations (EFE), leading to a cosmological constant ‘Λ’ in accord with

    observations2. In matter-free background, the scalar curvature was found to be =4Λ̄

    2 It has been argued that a non-minimal coupling term-generated by quantum corrections-is to be expectedwhenever the space-time curvature is large; in most theories that describe inflationary scenarios, it turnsout that a value of ξ different from zero is unavoidable. As a matter of fact, it seems sensible to consideran explicit non-minimal coupling in the supergravities inflationary paradigm.

  • Electronic Journal of Theoretical Physics 10 (2006) 1–10 3

    where Λ̄ = Λ−3/4m2 is the effective cosmological constant3 (in natural units, m ≈ �H/c2where ‘�’ is the Planck constant and ‘c’ being the celerity of light). As a result, one

    candidate Einstein field equations is(� = c = 1):

    Gμν ≡ Rμν − 12gμνR = −Λ̄gμν (1)

    Λ̄ = Λ − 3m2/4 ≡ Λ1 + Λ2 is the effective cosmological constant (Λ2 = −3λ̄−2C whereλC = �/mc is the Compton wavelength in natural units). Remark that for Λ1 = 0, the

    scalar curvature is negative and the space-time is not Minkowskian. Other field equations

    exist also but correspond only for p = ρ/3 (radiation era):

    Rμν − 12gμνR + Λgμν = −8πG

    [(p + ρ +

    3m2

    8πG

    )uμuν + pgμν

    ](2a)

    Rμν − 12gμνR = −8πG

    [(p + ρ +

    3m2

    8πG

    )uμuν +

    (p +

    Λ

    8πG

    )gμν

    ](2b)

    = −8πG[(p + ρ̄) uμuν +

    (p +

    Λ

    8πG

    )gμν

    ](2c)

    ≡ −8πG[Tμν (p, ρ) +

    Λ

    8πGgμν + tμν (m)

    ](2d)

    ≡ −8πG [Tμν (p, ρ) + Tμν (Λ,m)] (2e)≡ −8πG

    ∑Tμν (2f)

    p and ρ are the pressure and density of matter,ρ̄ = ρ + 3m2/8πG, tμν = 3m2/8πGuμuν

    and:

    Tμν (p, ρ) = (p + ρ) uμuν + pgμν (3)

    Tμν (Λ,m) = tμν +Λ

    8πGgμν =

    1

    8πG

    [3m2uμuν + Λgμν

    ](4)

    Contracting equations (2) with gμν using gμνuμuν = −1 yields of course. In this way,the ultra-light masses and the cosmological constant are parts of the matter contents of

    the Universe rather than geometrical entities. The radiative field equations (RFE) (2-

    a,b,c,d,e,f) are identical to that of Einstein standard ones but with an additional energy

    density ρm = 3m2/8πG(m ≤ H). One can also refer to equation (4) as the stress-energy

    tensor of vacuum and light particles, which is a ”microscopic stress-energy tensor”. In

    fact, the conservation law holds and we have:

    ∇ν∑

    Tμν ≡ ∇νTμν (p, ρ) + ∇νTμν (Λ,m) = 0 (5)

    When Tμν (p, ρ) = 0, the microscopic stress-energy tensor will behave as the macroscopic

    one if we assume that:

    P (Λ,m) ≡ PΛ = Λ/8πG (6)3 In [13], 8πG ≡ κ was set equal to unity.

  • 4 Electronic Journal of Theoretical Physics 10 (2006) 1–10

    ρ (Λ,m) =3m2 − Λ

    8πG(7)

    That is, in the microscopic version, if Λ = 0, P = 0 but the density is positive. While

    for Λ > 3m2, the pressure is positive and the density is negative. If 0 < Λ < 3m2, then

    both the pressure and the density are positive.

    Before treating the non-minimal coupling scenario, we will discuss briefly the impli-

    cations of equations (2) in standard cosmology. For this, we consider a homogenous and

    isotropic Universe in the radiation dominated epoch described by Friedman-Robertson-

    Walker line element with scale factor a (t)[14]. The radiative field equations read:

    ȧ2

    a2+

    k

    a2=

    8πGρ

    3+

    Λ

    3+ m2 (8)

    a= −8πGρ

    3+

    Λ

    3− m

    2

    2(9)

    k = −1, 0, +1 is the curvature constant for open, flat or closed space-time and dim (Λ) =dim (m2) = length−2. If the cosmological constant and the ultra-light masses are assumedto be constant with time, then from the energy conservation law: ρ ∝ a−4. For zerodensity, 2Λ > ( ( Λ, Λ̂ → 3/4m2. If for instance, we assume that m2 = β/a2and Λ = δȧ2/a2 +ηä/a, β, δ, η are constants [20,21], than from equation (10)4:

    a

    (1 − 2η

    3

    )+

    ȧ2

    a2

    (1 − 2δ

    3

    )+

    (k − β

    2

    )1

    a2= 0 (12)

    which gives:

    ȧ2 =3 (β − 2k)2 (3 − 2δ) + Da

    − 2(3−2δ)3−2η , D = const. (13)

    4 The fact that the two terms Λ and m2 play the role of two cosmological constant in the theory, wehave the freedom to choose Λ = δ1ȧ2

    /a2 + η1ä/a + β1

    /a2 and m2 = δ2ȧ2

    /a2 + η2ä/a + β2

    /a2where

    δ1,2, η1,2, β1,2 are constants. In this work, we simplified our assumptions just to have at the beginning asimple idea about the effects of the ultra-light masses in the theory.

  • Electronic Journal of Theoretical Physics 10 (2006) 1–10 5

    For D = 0 which corresponds to singular solutions, one finds for flat space-time(k = 0):

    a =

    √3β

    2 (3 − 2δ)t (14)

    where δ < 3/2, β > 0. In this way :

    m2 =2 (3 − 2δ)

    3t2(15)

    Λ =δ

    t2(16)

    From equation (8), we find:

    ρ =3 (δ − 1)8πGt2

    (17)

    with 1 < δ < 3/2. In this way, we don’t have an inflationary phase and no horizon

    problem appears. From the above equations, we see that the ultra-light masses, the

    cosmological constant and the density are independent of the value of β and η. The

    Hubble parameter is H = ȧ/a = 1/t and the density matter of the Universe is given by

    Ωr = ρ/ρc = δ − 1 < 1/2 where ρc = 3H2/8πG is the critical density. The decelerationparameter is q ≡ −äa/ȧ2 = 0. The density parameter due to vacuum contribution isΩΛ = Λ/3H2 = δ/3 and that due to ultra-light particles contributions is Ωm = m2/H2 =

    2 (3 − 2δ)/3. In this way ΩTotal = Ωr + Ωm + ΩΛ = 1 as required by inflation [22]. Theultra-light particles than contribute to the total energy density and their masses decrease

    as inverse to time. Note from equations (15) and (16) that Λ = 3δm2/2 (3 − 2δ) < 9m2/4.Finally, note that when the ‘Λ’ and ‘m2’ terms dominate the dynamics of equation (8)

    with the assumption that the Universe undergoes a long period of evolution during which

    the celerity of light changes as c = c0an, c0, n =constants [8]:

    ȧ2

    a2=

    Λc2 (t)

    3+ m2c2 (t) →

    3+ m2

    )c2n0 a

    2n (18)

    So at large times, we have a ∝ t−1/n and it was found in [8] that for negative ”n”, thereis a solution to the quasi-lambda problem.

    In order to have a very simple idea about the role of the ultra-light masses in the

    theory, we suppose that the space-time is flat, that is k = 0 with the following behavior of

    the ultra-light masses m2 = β/a2and the cosmological constant Λ = δ/a2, β, η=constants

    (see footnote 4 ) [23,24,25]. In this case, when ‘Λ’ and ‘m2’ terms dominate at large

    times the dynamics of equation (8):

    ȧ2

    a2=

    Λc2 (t)

    3+ m2c2 (t) =

    (β +

    δ

    3

    )c20a

    2n−2 (19)

    That is a ∝ t−1/n−1 and from [8,26], it is required that n < 0 and c = c0t−n/n−1. Insummary, m2 ∝ t2/n−1 and as a result mc ∝ 1/t. Another way to study shifting andtime-varying photons velocities is by using the non-minimal coupling of electromagnetic

    fields and gravity.

  • 6 Electronic Journal of Theoretical Physics 10 (2006) 1–10

    3. Varying Photons Velocities From Non-Minimal Coupling

    Following [10,11], we admit the existence of a surface S represented by φ (x) = 0. The

    wavenumber of the photon trajectories is given by the gradient of its phase kλ = ∇λφwhere the Faraday tensor vanishes at its hypersurface, that is (Fμν)S = 0. Its derivative

    defines a function φμν such that:

    (∂λFμν)S = (DλFμν)S = kλφμν (20)

    As a consequence, equation (1) takes the form:

    [φμν − 2ξ (Rμαφαν − Rναφαμ)] kν = 0 (21)

    In the radiation dominated era, it follows that:

    φμνkν − 2ξ{[

    φαν . (−χ){{

    3+ ρm

    }uμuν +

    3+

    ρm2

    − Λχ

    }}δμν

    ]

    +

    [−φαμ. (−χ)

    {{4ρ

    3+ ρm

    }uνuα +

    3+

    ρm2

    − Λχ

    }}δνα

    ]}kν = 0 (22)

    where χ = 8πG (� = c = 1). For simplicity, we let k0 = kμuμ and we use the antisym-

    metric fact of (φμν − φνμ = 2φμν) as well as Maxwell equations:

    φμνkλ + ϕνλkμ + φλμkν = 0 (23)

    By contracting by kλ the last equation, equation (23) reduces to:

    φμνkν =−2ξχ (4ρ

    3+ ρm

    )1 + 4χ

    (ρ3

    + ρm2− Λ

    χ

    )ξk0φ

    μνuν ≡ (N) k0φμνuν (24)

    Replacing (24) into (23), then:

    φμνk2 + N (−φμνkλ − ϕλμkν − kνφμλ) k0uλ = 0 (25)

    The antisymmetric of φμνeliminates all the terms in the parentheses of equation (25) and

    we are left with:

    φμν(k2 − Nk20

    )= 0 ⇒ k2 − Nk20 = 0,∀φμν (26)

    The effective photons velocity, in case allρ, ρm, Λ = 0, ∀ξ is then given by [6]:

    v2 =|kiki|k20

    = |1 + N | =∣∣∣∣∣∣ 1 − 4ξΛ − 4ξχ

    ρ3

    1 + 4ξχ(

    ρ3

    + ρm3− Λ

    χ

    )∣∣∣∣∣∣ (27)

    and the light velocities is not equal to ‘c’. Adopting equations (15), (16) and (17),

    equation (27) takes the form in normal units:

    v2 =

    ∣∣∣∣∣1 − 4 ξt2 (2δ − 1)1 + 4 ξt2

    (5 − 4δ)

    ∣∣∣∣∣ (28)

  • Electronic Journal of Theoretical Physics 10 (2006) 1–10 7

    with 1 < δ < 3/2. As a result, for ξ > () c (light celerity). Adopting

    the fact c = c0an with n < 0, than the photons velocities decreases with time whatever

    is the sign of the coupling constant.

    An interesting case is when the background is ‘free from matter ’ . From (27) we get:

    v2 =

    ∣∣∣∣ 1 − 4ξΛ1 + 4ξ (m2 − Λ)∣∣∣∣ (29)

    If m2 = 0, than v2 = 1 which is light celerity in units (� = c = 1). Assuming m2 = β/t2,

    4Λ = 3m2 or Λ̄ = 0 and as a result R = 0. In this case, equation (28) gives:

    v2 =

    ∣∣∣∣1 − 3m2ξ1 + m2ξ∣∣∣∣ =

    ∣∣∣∣∣1 − ξ 3βt21 + ξ βt2

    ∣∣∣∣∣ =∣∣∣∣t2 − 3ξβt2 + ξβ

    ∣∣∣∣ (30)Again, if ξ > () c (light celerity). As a result, the velocity of photons is

    affected and shifted by the presence of the ultra-light tiny masses and depends on the sign

    of the coupling constant. It doesn’t correspond in fact to null geodesics as in the standard

    case. Positive coupling constant corresponds to friction and negative one corresponds to

    superluminal case [27,28]. If we adopt the fact c = c0an, then the photons velocities not

    only is shifted but also decrease with time if n < 0 and increase if n > 0.

    The constancy of the speed of light is not preserved in this analysis. It depends on

    how is filled the background space and how is used a coupling constant different of zero

    that modifies presentation of the Einstein’s Field Equations (EFT ), with an additional

    term. It is important to notice that the environment where speed of light reaches its

    maximum value is the lightest one: the empty space, all because of the constancy of the

    speed of light law, which in time, originates the fourth time-coordinate. In our case, the

    red-shift coefficient ‘z’ varies with time according to cz = Hr combined to equations (29)

    or (30) for a matter free background. ‘r’ is supposed to be the distance form the galaxy

    to the earth [14]. If the coupling constant is assume to be positive, one can than have a

    cosmological model based on interpretation of the red shift by decrease of the light speed

    with time everywhere in the universe beginning with a certain moment of time in the

    past. Of course, the agreement with the fundamental physics laws will be completed by

    introducing in a future work the evolution of other fundamental constants synchronously

    with the variation of the light speed [29].

    Finally, we note that recently, growing amount of astrophysical data show important

    evidence for statistical and apparent physical association between low-redshift galaxies

    and high-redshift quasi-stellar objects suggesting noncosmological origin of their redshift

    and as a result failure of classical quasar explanation [30]. The author found analytical

    solution of Einstein equations describing bubbles made from axions with periodic inter-

    action potential considered as one of the leading dark matter candidate. Remember that

    in our model [13], the ultra-light masses implemented in Einstein field equations enabled

    us to solve the ‘missing mass problem’ and as result considered as dark matter candidate.

    In Minkowski space, objects at constant proper distance with respect to an observer have

    zero redshift. However, in an expanding universe special relativistic concepts do not gen-

    erally apply. In fact, a galaxy with zero total velocity does not have zero redshift even

  • 8 Electronic Journal of Theoretical Physics 10 (2006) 1–10

    in the empty universe case. This demonstrates that cosmological redshifts are not spe-

    cial relativity Doppler shifts [31,32]. It was also proved that Minkowski coordinate and

    the Robertson-Walker coordinates (FRW universe) are interchangeable descriptions for

    an empty universe. However, velocities in the Minkowski universe are not equivalent to

    velocities in the FRW universe because of the different definitions of time and distance in

    these two models. A coordinate transform relates velocities in the Minkowski universe to

    velocities in the FRW universe. Superluminal recession velocities in the FRW universe

    do not violate special relativity because they are not in the observer’s inertial frame.

    4. Conclusions:

    In this work, we used the Einstein’s field equations with effective cosmological constant

    inspired from non-minimal coupling and supergravities arguments to study the conse-

    quences of non-minimal coupling between electromagnetic fields and gravity on light

    velocity in the presence of ultra-light particles at the radiation dominated epoch of the

    Universe. We showed that if the cosmological constant and the ultra-light square masses

    varies as Λ = δȧ2/a2+ηä/a and m2 = β/a2, then at singular solutions and for a flat space-

    time, Λ, m2 and ρ decreases with time as 1/t2, the Hubble parameter vary as H = 1/t,

    the deceleration parameter is zero and ΩTotal = Ωr +Ωm+ΩΛ = 1 as required by inflation.

    As a result, the ultra-light particles than contribute to the total energy density and their

    masses decrease as inverse to time. When the ‘Λ’ and ‘m2’ terms dominate the dynamics

    of our field equations with the assumption that the Universe undergoes a long period of

    evolution during which the celerity of light changes as c = c0an, it was found that at large

    times a ∝ t−1/n and that for negative ‘n’, there is a solution to the quasi-lambda problem.Finally, we studied varying light velocities from non-minimal coupling. We found that

    photons velocities depends on the coupling constant and only on δ ∈ (1, 3/2)in a waythat ξ > () c with m

    2 > 0.

    The model described in this paper could have important implications in various sys-

    tems, in particular cosmological scenarios, black hole physics and quantum interactions

    [33,34,35,36,37]. It is important to discuss the impact of the assumptions established to

    reach the model and the fact that a non-Minkowskian space is necessary to obtain speeds

    greater than that of light, and that photon could be represented by a positron-electron

    pair for characterizing it with the electron’s Compton wavelength.

    To further investigate all these issues, further studies will be necessary and work is in

    progress.

    Acknowledgments:

    The author is grateful for the referees for their useful comments and suggestions.

  • Electronic Journal of Theoretical Physics 10 (2006) 1–10 9

    References

    [1] I.T. Drummond and S.J. Hathrell, Phys. Rev. D 22, 343 (1980).

    [2] R.D. Daniels and G.M. Shore, Nucl. Phys. B 425,634 (1994).

    [3] Y. Ohkuwa, Prog. Theor. Phys. 65, 1058 (1981).

    [4] R. G. Cai, Nucl. Phys. B 524,639 (1998).

    [5] G. M. Shore, Nucl. Phys. B 460, 379 (1996).

    [6] J. D. Barrow, astro-ph/9811022.

    [7] A. Albrecht and J. Maguiejo, Phys. Rev D 59, 043516 (1999) 043516.

    [8] J. D. Barrow and J. Maguiejo, Phys. Lett. B 443, 104-110 (1998).

    [9] P. Teyssandier, Annales de la Fondation Louis de Broglie, Volume 29 no 1-2, (2004)(gr-qc/0303081 ).

    [10] M. Novello, L. A. R Olivera and J. M. Salim J.M., Class. Quant. Grav. 7, 51 (1990).

    [11] M. Novello and S. D. Jorda, Mod. Phys. Lett. A, vol 4, n19, 1809, (1989).

    [12] 1-I. L. Buchbinder, S. D. Odintsov and I. L. Shapiro, Effective Action in QuantumGravity, IOP-Publishing Ltd, (1982).

    [13] R. A. El-Nabulsi, Phys. Letts. B, Vol. 619, 26 (2005).

    [14] S. Weinberg, Gravitation and Cosmology, NY, Wiley (1972).

    [15] J. M. Overduin and F. I. Cooperstock, astro-ph/9805260.

    [16] J. W. Moffat, Int. J. Mod. Phys. D2, 351 (1993).

    [17] J. W. Moffat, Found. Of Phys., 23, 411 (1993).

    [18] M. A. Clayton and J. W. Moffat, Phys. Lett.B 460, 263 (1999).

    [19] M. A. Clayton and J. W. Moffat, Phys. Lett.B 477, 269 (2000).

    [20] A. S. Al-Rawaf, Mod. Phys. Lett. A 13, 429 (1998).

    [21] A. I. Arbab, Spacetime and Substance 1(6), 39 (2001).

    [22] A. H. Guth, Phys. Rev. D 23, 347 (1981).

    [23] M. S. Berman, Nuovo Cimento 74B, 182 (1983).

    [24] M. S. Berman, Gen. Rel. Grav. 23, 465 (1991).

    [25] M. S. Berman and F. M. Gomide, Gen. Rel. Grav. 20, 191 (1988).

    [26] M. S. Berman and L. A. Trevisan, gr-qc/0112011.

    [27] D. Syer, astro-ph/9404063.

    [28] T. Chiba and K. Kohri, Prog. Theor. Phys. 107, 631 (2002).

    [29] V. S. Troitskii, Astrophysics and Space Science 139, 389 (1987).

    [30] A. A. Svidzinsky, astro-ph/0409064.

  • 10 Electronic Journal of Theoretical Physics 10 (2006) 1–10

    [31] Davis T. M., Lineweaver C. H., 2001, in Durrer R., Garcia-Bellido J., ShaposhnikovM., eds, Cosmology and Particle Physics 2000, American Institute of Physics conferenceproceedings, Volume 555. New York, p. 348.

    [32] Davis T. M., Lineweaver C. H., Webb J. K., Am. J. Phys., 71, 358 (2003)

    [33] C. F. E. Holzhey and F. Wilzeck, Nucl. Phys. B 380, 447 (1992).

    [34] R. A. El-Nabulsi, Chinese Phys. Lett. 23 No 5, 1124-1127 (2006).

    [35] R. A. El-Nabulsi, Elec. J. Theor. Phys. 7, 27-46 (2005).

    [36] R. A. El-Nabulsi, Elec. J. Theor. Phys. 9, 1-5 (2006).

    [37] R. A. El-Nabulsi, Supergravity, Non-mimimal Coupling and Eternal AcceleratedExpansion: Some important Cosmological Features of Ultra-Light Particles andInduced Cosmological Constant, Submitted to Elec. J. Theor. Phys.

  • EJTP 3, No. 11 (2006) 11–27 Electronic Journal of Theoretical Physics

    A Toy Model of Financial Markets

    J. P. Singh and S. Prabakaran ∗ †

    Department of Management StudiesIndian Institute of Technology Roorkee

    Roorkee 247667, India

    Received 27 October 2005 , Accepted 9 January 2006, Published 25 June 2006

    Abstract: Several techniques of fundamental physics like quantum mechanics, field theoryand related tools of non-commutative probability, gauge theory, path integral etc. are beingapplied for pricing of contemporary financial products and for explaining various phenomenaof financial markets like stock price patterns, critical crashes etc.. In this paper, we apply thewell entrenched methods of quantum mechanics and quantum field theory to the modeling ofthe financial markets and the behaviour of stock prices. After defining the various constituentsof the model including creation & annihilation operators and buying & selling operators forsecurities, we examine the time evolution of the financial markets and obtain the Hamiltonianfor the trading activities of the market. We finally obtain the probability distribution of stockprices in terms of the propagators of the evolution equations.c© Electronic Journal of Theoretical Physics. All rights reserved.

    Keywords: Economic Physics , Financial Markets , Stock Prices, Quantum ModelsPACS (2006): 89.65.Gh , 03.65.-w, 02.50.-r, 05.30.-d, 02.30.Tb

    1. Introductionn

    The specialty of “physics” is the study of interactions between the various mani-

    festations of matter and its constituents. The development of this subject over the last

    several centuries has led to a gradual refining of our understanding of natural phenomena.

    Accompanying this has been a spectacular evolution of sophisticated mathematical tools

    for the modeling of complex systems. These analytical tools are versatile enough to find

    application not only in point processes involving particles but also aggregates thereof

    leading to field theoretic generalizations and condensed matter physics.

    Furthermore, with the rapid advancements in the evolution and study of disordered

    [email protected]† Jatinder [email protected]

  • 12 Electronic Journal of Theoretical Physics 3, No. 11 (2006) 11–27

    systems and the associated phenomena of nonlinearity, chaos, self organized criticality

    etc., the importance of generalizations of the extant mathematical apparatus to enhance

    its domain of applicability to such disordered systems is cardinal to the further develop-

    ment of science.

    A considerable amount of work has already been done and success achieved in the

    broad areas of q-deformed harmonic oscillators [1], representations of q-deformed rotation

    and Lorentz groups [2-3]. q-deformed quantum stochastic processes have also been studied

    with realization of q-white noise on bialgebras [4]. Deformations of the Fokker Planck’s

    equation [5], Langevin equation [6] and Levy processes [7-8] have also been analysed and

    results reported.

    Though at a nascent stage, the winds of convergence of physics and finance are unmis-

    takably perceptible with several concepts of fundamental physics like quantum mechanics,

    field theory and related tools of non-commutative probability, gauge theory, path integral

    etc. being applied for pricing of contemporary financial products and for explaining var-

    ious phenomena of financial markets like stock price patterns, critical crashes etc. [8-19].

    The origin of the association between physics and finance, though, can be traced way back

    to the seminal works of Pareto [20] and Batchlier [21], the former being instrumental in

    establishing empirically that the distribution of wealth in several nations follows a power

    law with an exponent of 1.5, while the latter pioneered the modeling of speculative prices

    by the random walk and Brownian motion. The cardinal contribution of physicists to the

    world of finance came from Fischer Black & Myron Scholes through the option pricing

    formula [22] which bears their epitaph and which won them the Nobel Prize for economics

    in 1997 together with Robert Merton [23]. They obtained closed form expressions for the

    pricing of financial derivatives by converting the problem to a heat equation and then

    solving it for specific boundary conditions.

    The theory of stochastic processes constitutes the “golden thread” that unites the

    disciplines of physics and finance. Modeling of non relativistic quantum mechanics as

    energy conserving diffusion processes is, by now, well known [24]. Unification of the

    general theory of relativity and quantum mechanics to enable a consistent theory of

    quantum gravity has also been attempted on “stochastic spaces” [25]. Time evolution of

    stock prices has been, by suitable algebraic manipulations, shown to be equivalent to a

    diffusion process [26].

    Contemporary empirical research into the behavior of stock market price /return pat-

    terns has found significant evidence that financial markets exhibit the phenomenon of

    anomalous diffusion, primarily superdiffusion, wherein the variance evolves with time

    according to a power law tαwith α > 1.0. The standard technique for the study of su-

    perdiffusive processes is through a stochastic process that evolves according to a Langevin

    equation and whose probability distribution function satisfies a nonlinear Fokker Planck

    equation [27].

    There is an intricate yet natural relationship between the power law tails observed in

    stock market data and probability distributions that emanate as the solution of the Fokker

    Planck equation. The Fokker Planck equation is known to describe anomalous diffusion

  • Electronic Journal of Theoretical Physics 3, No. 11 (2006) 11–27 13

    under time evolution. Empirical results [28-31] establish that temporal changes of several

    financial market indices have variances that that are shown to undergo anomalous super

    diffusion under time evolution.

    One of the most exhaustive set of studies on stock market data in varying dimensions

    has been reported in [32-36]. In [36], a phenomenological study was conducted of stock

    price fluctuations of individual companies using data from two different databases cover-

    ing three major US stock markets. The probability distributions of returns over varying

    timescales ranging from 5 min. to 4 years were examined. It was observed that for

    timescales from 5 minutes upto 16 days the tails of the distributions were well described

    by a power law decay. For larger timescales results consistent with a gradual convergence

    to Gaussian behaviour was observed. In another study [32] the probability distributions

    of the returns on the S & P 500 were computed over varying timescales. It was, again,

    seen that the distributions were consistent with an asymptotic power law behaviour with

    a slow convergence to Gaussian behaviour. Similar findings were obtained on the analysis

    of the NIKKEI and the Hang –Sang indices [32].

    Stock market phenomena are assumed to result from complicated interactions among

    many degrees of freedom, and thus they were analyzed as random processes and one could

    go to the extent of saying that the Efficient Market Hypothesis [37-38] was formulated

    with one primary objective – to create a scenario which would justify the use of stochastic

    calculus [39] for the modeling of capital markets.

    The Efficient Market Hypothesis contemplates a market where all assets are fairly

    priced according to the information available and neither buyers nor sellers enjoy any

    advantage. Market prices are believed to reflect all public information, both fundamental

    and price history and prices move only as sequel to new information entering the market.

    Further, the presence of large number of investors is believed to ensure that all prices

    are fair. Memory effects, if any at all, are assumed to be extremely short ranging and

    dissipate rapidly. Feedback effects on prices are, thus, assumed to be marginal. The

    investor community is assumed rational as benchmarked by the traditional concepts of

    risk and return.

    An immediate corollary to the Efficient Market Hypothesis is the independence of

    single period returns, so that they can be modeled as a random walk and the defining

    probability distribution, in the limit of the number of observations being large, would be

    Gaussian.

    Anomalous diffusion is a hallmark of several intensively studied physical systems. It

    is observed, for example, in the chaotic dynamics of fluid in rapidly rotating annulus [40],

    conservative motion in a periodic potential [41], transport of fluid in a porous media [42],

    percolation of gases in porous media [43], crystal growth spreading of thin films under

    gravity [44], radiative heat transfer [45], systems exhibiting surface to surface growth [46]

    and so on.

    Several analogies between physical systems and financial processes have been explored

    in the last decade, some of which have already been mentioned above. Perhaps, the most

    striking one is that between financial crashes witnessed in stock markets and critical

  • 14 Electronic Journal of Theoretical Physics 3, No. 11 (2006) 11–27

    phenomena like phase transitions is discussed here to place the main theme of this paper

    in its proper perspective.

    Stock market crashes are believed to exhibit log periodic oscillations which are char-

    acteristic of systems exhibiting discrete scale invariance i.e. invariance through rescaling

    by integral powers of some length scale like the Serpinski triangle and other similar fractal

    shapes. In the years preceding the infamous crash of October 19, 1987, the S & P market

    index was seen to fit the following expression exceedingly precisely [47-48],

    (S & P )t = Ω + Γ (tc − t)γ {1 + Ξ cos [θ ln (tc − t) + φ]}Physicists working in solid state and condensed matter physics would immediately

    recognize the analogy of the above expression with the one obtained for critical phe-

    nomenon in spin model of ferromagnetism [49]. We briefly elucidate the salient features

    of this model. Crystalline solids comprise of atoms arranged in a lattice. Each such

    atom generates a magnetic field parallel to the direction of the atom’s spin. In the case

    of substances that do not exhibit ferromagnetic character, these spin directions are ran-

    domly oriented so that the aggregate magnetic field vanishes. However, in ferromagnetic

    substances these spins are polarized in a particular direction resulting in a nonzero ag-

    gregate field. Ferromagnetic substances usually exhibit two distinct phases. one in which

    the spins orient themselves in a particular direction resulting in an aggregate magnetic

    moment at temperatures below a well defined critical temperature tc and the other where

    the spins are disoriented with a zero aggregate moment above the critical temperature.

    At temperatures below tc, the coupling force between neighboring atoms predominates

    resulting in an alignment of spins whereas above tc the additional energy manifests itself

    in disorienting (randomizing) the spins.

    Renormalization group theory enables us to group these atoms in blocks of spins

    whose composite spins are equal to the algebraic sum of the spins of the atoms con-

    stituting the block. It then provides that a model involving interactions between these

    composite spins of a block can be constructed that replicates the macroscopic proper-

    ties of the block and yet cannot depend on the size of the block. That is, the sys-

    tem would exhibit a scaling symmetry, which is discrete, if we allow for the finite size

    of the atom and continuous otherwise. The magnetic susceptibility of such a mag-

    netic substance defined by χ (T ) = ∂M∂B

    ∣∣B=0

    , where the symbols have their usual mean-

    ing, obeys a power law of the form χ (T ) = Re[(T − Tc)α+iβ

    ]or equivalently χ (T ) =

    (T − Tc)α {1 + β cos [ln (T − Tc)] + O (β2)}which is reminiscent of op cited expression forlog periodic oscillations in financial crashes.

    Furthermore, the access to enhanced computing power during the last decade has

    enabled analysts to try refined methods like the phase space reconstruction methods

    for determining the Lyapunov Exponents [50] of stock market price data, besides doing

    Rescaled Range Analysis [51] etc. A set of several studies has indicated the existence

    of strong evidence that the stock market shows chaotic behavior with fractal return

    structures and positive Lyapunov exponents. Results of these studies have unambiguously

    established the existence of significant nonlinearities and chaotic behavior in these time

  • Electronic Journal of Theoretical Physics 3, No. 11 (2006) 11–27 15

    series [52-55].

    In this paper, we attempt one such model. The objective is to apply the well en-

    trenched methods of quantum mechanics and quantum field theory to the study of the

    financial markets and the behaviour of stock prices. Section 2, which forms the essence of

    this paper, arrives at various results for financial markets by modeling them as quantum

    Hamiltonian systems. The probability distribution for stock prices in efficient markets is

    also obtained. Section 3 concludes.

    1.1 Quantum Model of Financial Markets

    We consider an “isolated” financial market comprising of n investors and m type of

    securities. The market is “isolated” in the sense that new types of securities are nei-

    ther created nor are existing ones destroyed. Further, the number of investors is also

    constant. The investor i, i = 1, 2, 3.......n is assumed to possess a cash balance of

    xi, i = 1, 2, 3.......n (which may be negative, representing borrowings) and yij (z) , i =

    1, 2, 3.....n; j = 1, 2, 3....m units of security j at a unit price of z . Obviously, yij ≥ 0,∀i, j.Towards constructing a basis for our Hilbert space representing the financial market,

    we define a pure state of the system as

    |Ψi〉 = |{xi, {yij (z) , j = 1, 2, ...m} , i = 1, 2, ...n}〉 (1)Thus, a pure state represents a state of the market where the entire holdings of cash

    and securities of every investor are known with certainty. This represents a complete

    measurement of the market and hence, is in conformity with the standard definition of

    “pure state” of a system.

    A basis for our Hilbert space may then be constituted by the set of all the pure states

    of the type (1) i.e.

    Ψ = {|{xi, {yij (z) , j = 1, 2, ...m} , i = 1, 2, ...n}〉} (2)The elements of this basis set Ψ satisfy the orthogonality condition 〈Ψi | Ψj〉 = δij withrespect to the scalar product defined in the sequel. The orthogonality condition makes

    sense in the financial world – it implies that if a market is in a pure state |Ψi〉 then itcannot be in any other pure state.

    However, a complete measurement of the market is, obviously, not practicable in real

    life. At any point in time, we are likely to have certain information only about a fraction

    of the market constituents. Hence, the instantaneous state of the market |ψ (t)〉 may berepresented by a linear combination of the pure states |Ψl (t)〉 i.e.

    |ψ (t)〉 =∑

    l

    Cl |Ψl (t)〉 (3)

    We endow our Hilbert space H with the scalar product

    〈ψ (t) | ξ (t)〉 =∑l,m

    C∗l Dm 〈Ψl (t) | Ψm (t)〉 =∑l,m

    C∗l Dmδlm =∑

    l

    C∗l Dl (4)

  • 16 Electronic Journal of Theoretical Physics 3, No. 11 (2006) 11–27

    where we have assumed the orthogonality of the pure states.

    The components of the state space vector |ψ (t)〉are given byCl = 〈Ψl (t) | ψ (t)〉 andare related to the probability of finding the market in the pure state |Ψl (t)〉.

    Since our basis comprises of all possible measurable pure states, the completeness of

    the basis is ensured so that

    I =∑

    l

    |Ψl (t)〉 〈Ψl (t)| (5)

    In analogy with the no particle state or ground state in quantum mechanics, we can

    define a ground state of our financial market as

    |0〉 = |xi = 0, yij (z) = 0∀i, j, z〉 (6)

    i.e. the ground state is the market state in which no investor has any cash balances nor

    any securities. This state is, obviously, a pure state being fully measurable and would

    also not evolve in time since no trade can take place in this market.

    We define the cash and security coordinate operators x̂i& ŷij (z) by their action on

    the basis state (1) to provide respectively the balances of cash and the jth security (at

    price z) with the ith investor as the eigenvalues i.e.

    x̂i |{xi, {yij (z) , j = 1, 2, ...m} , i = 1, 2, ...n}〉 = xi |{xi, {yij (z) , j = 1, 2, ...m} , i = 1, 2, ...n}〉(7)

    ŷij (z) |{xi, {yij (z) , j = 1, 2, ...m} , i = 1, 2, ...n}〉 = yij (z) |{xi, {yij (z) , j = 1, 2, ...m} , i = 1, 2, ...n}〉(8)

    A cash translation operator T̂i (z) is also defined by the following

    T̂i (z′) |{xi, {yij (z) , j = 1, 2, ...m} , i = 1, 2, ...n}〉 = |{xi + z′, {yij (z) , j = 1, 2, ...m} , i = 1, 2, ...n}〉 (9)

    i.e. it transfers an amount of cash z to the ith investor.

    The operator T̂i (z) obviously satisfies the following properties

    T̂i (z1) T̂i (z2) = T̂i (z1 + z2) (10)

    T̂i (0) = Î (11)[T̂i (z) , x̂j

    ]= T̂i (z) x̂j − x̂jT̂i (z) = −zδijT̂i (z) (12)

    T̂ ↑i (z) = T̂i (−z) (13)Towards obtaining an explicit representation of the cash translation operator, we assume

    p̂i =dT̂i(z)

    dz

    ∣∣∣z=0

    as the generator of infinitesimal cash translations dz to the investor i.

    Expanding T̂i (z) as a Taylor’s series and using eqs. (10), (11) we have

    dT̂i (z)

    dz= lim

    dz→0T̂i (z + dz) − T̂i (z)

    dz= lim

    dz→0

    �T̂i (dz) − 1

    �T̂i (z)

    dz= lim

    dz→0

    �T̂i (0) +

    dT̂i(z)dz

    ���z=0

    dz... − 1�

    T̂i (z)

    dz= p̂iT̂i (z)

    (14)

  • Electronic Journal of Theoretical Physics 3, No. 11 (2006) 11–27 17

    with the solution T̂i (z) = ezp̂i . Furthermore, we have (suppressing the yij indices for the

    sake of brevity)

    |{xi + dz, i = 1, 2, ...n}〉 = T̂i (dz) |{xi, i = 1, 2, ...n}〉 =[T̂i (0) +

    dT̂i(z)dz

    ∣∣∣z=0

    dz...]|{xi, i = 1, 2, ...n}〉

    = [I + p̂idz...] |{xi, i = 1, 2, ...n}〉(15)

    Hence,

    ∂〈{xi,i=1,2,...n}|ψ〉∂xi

    = limdz→0

    〈{xi+dz,i=1,2,...n}|ψ〉−〈{xi,i=1,2,...n}|ψ〉dz

    = p̂↑i 〈{xi, i = 1, 2, ...n} | ψ〉 = −p̂i 〈{xi, i = 1, 2, ...n} | ψ〉 ⇒ p̂i = − ∂∂xi(16)

    so that T̂i (z) = e−z ∂

    ∂xi . The following commutation rule holds between x̂iand p̂i

    [x̂i, p̂j] = δij (17)

    The condition of an isolated market ensures that the basis and hence the Hilbert space

    does not depend on time. This implies that the temporal evolution of the system is

    unitary.

    Creation & Annihilation Operators for Securities

    We define âij (z)as the annihilation operator of the security j from the portfolio of

    investor i for a price z i.e. when operator âij (z) acts on a state, the number of units of

    security j is reduced by one from the portfolio of investor i for a price z.Similarly, we

    define creation operators â↑ij (z) as the adjoint of the annihilation operators that increasethe number of units of security j in the portfolio of investor i for a price z.The precise

    action of these operators on a state vector is defined by the following

    âij(z) |{xi, {yij (z) , j = 1, 2, ...m} , i = 1, 2, ...n}〉 =√

    yij(z).z |{xi, {yij (z) − 1, j = 1, 2, ...m} , i = 1, 2, ...n}〉(18)

    and

    â↑ij(z) |{xi, {yij (z) , j = 1, 2, ...m} , i = 1, 2, ...n}〉 =√

    (yij(z) + 1)z |{xi, {yij (z) + 1, j = 1, 2, ...m} , i = 1, 2, ...n}〉(19)

    where the factor ‘z’ has been introduced in the eigenvalues to ensure “scale invariance”

    of the theory.

    These operators satisfy the following commutation relations:-[âij(z), â

    ↑ij(z

    ′)]

    = zδzz′δikδjl (20)

    and

    [âij(z), âkl(z′)] =

    [â↑ij(z), â

    ↑ij(z

    ′)]

    = 0 (21)[T̂i (z) , âjk (z

    ′)]

    =[T̂i (z) , â

    ↑jk (z

    ′)]

    = 0 (22)[T̂ ↑i (z) , âjk (z

    ′)]

    =[T̂ ↑i (z) , â

    ↑jk (z

    ′)]

    = 0 (23)

  • 18 Electronic Journal of Theoretical Physics 3, No. 11 (2006) 11–27

    Further more

    â↑ij (z) âij (z) |{xi, {yij (z) , j = 1, 2, ...m} , i = 1, 2, ...n}〉 = zyij (z) |{xi, {yij (z) , j = 1, 2, ...m} , i = 1, 2, ...n}〉(24)

    which implies that the number operator would be

    ŷij (z) =â↑ij (z) âij (z)

    z(25)

    Using the aforesaid operators we can construct an arbitrary basis state from the ground

    state as follows

    |{xi, {yij (z) , j = 1, 2, ...m} , i = 1, 2, ...n}〉 =n∏

    i=1

    T̂i (xi)m∏

    j=1

    ∏{z,yij(z)∈N}

    (â↑ij (z)

    )yij(z) |0〉(26)

    Buying and selling operators

    The buying (selling) operation of a security is, in each case, a composite operation

    consisting of the following:-

    i. the creation (annihilation) of a security at the relevant price z; and

    ii. the decrease (increase) in the cash balance by z of the investor undertaking the

    trade.

    Hence we can define the buying (selling) operator as composite of the cash translation

    operator and the creation (annihilation) operators for securities as follows:-

    b̂↑ij (z) = â↑ij (z) T̂

    ↑i (z) = â

    ↑ij (z) T̂i (−z) (27)

    for the “buying” operation and

    b̂ij (z) = âij (z) T̂i (z) (28)

    for the “selling” operation. These operators satisfy the following commutation rules[b̂ij (z) , b̂

    ↑kl (z

    ′)]

    = zδzz′δikδjl (29)

    [b̂ij (z) , b̂kl (z

    ′)]

    =[b̂↑ij (z) , b

    ↑kl (z

    ′)]

    = 0 (30)

    [b̂ij (z) , T̂k (z

    ′)]

    =[b̂↑ij (z) , T̂k (z

    ′)]

    = 0 (31)

    [b̂↑ij (z) , x̂k

    ]= zδikb̂

    ↑ij (z) (32)[

    b̂ij (z) , x̂k

    ]= −zδikb̂ij (z) (33)

  • Electronic Journal of Theoretical Physics 3, No. 11 (2006) 11–27 19

    1.2 Temporal Evolution of Financial Markets

    In analogy with quantum mechanics, we mandate that the state of the market at a given

    instant of time ‘t’, is represented by a vector in the Hilbert space H whose components

    determine the statistical nature of the market. Hence the temporal evolution of the

    market in essentially determined by the evolution of this vector with the flow of time. In

    the Schrödinger picture, the time evolution of a system can be characterized through a

    unitary evolution operator∧U (t, t0) in H, that acts on the initial state |ψ (t0)〉 to transform

    it to |ψ (t)〉 i.e|ψ (t)〉 = Û (t, t0) |ψ (t0)〉 (34)

    The assumption of the market being isolated and hence

    Ψ = {|{xi, {yij (z) , j = 1, 2, ...m} , i = 1, 2, ...n}〉} being a complete basis at all times, andthe conservation of probability i.e.

    ∑l

    |Cl (t)|2 = 1,∀t together with the group property

    of∧U (t, t0) implies that the temporal evolution is unitary i.e.

    U (t, t0) U↑ (t, t0) = U↑ (t, t0) U (t, t0) = 1 (35)

    Furthermore Û (t0, t0) = 1. Defining the Hamiltonian Ĥ (t) = i∂∂t

    Û (t, t0)∣∣∣t=t0

    as the in-

    finitesimal generator of time translations (evolution) we obtain, through a Taylor’s ex-

    pansion up to first order Û (t + δt, t0) = Û (t, t0) +∂Û∂t

    (t + δt, t)∣∣∣δt=0

    Û (t, t0) δt + ...or

    ∂Û (t, t0)

    ∂t= lim

    δt→0Û (t + δt, t0) − Û (t, t0)

    δt= −iĤ (t) Û (t, t0) (36)

    with the immediate solution Û (t, t0) = e− � tt0 Ĥ(t)dt where time ordering of the operators

    constituting the Hamiltonian is assumed.

    Before progressing further with the development of the model, some observations are in

    order about the theory developed thus far.

    (1) In standard quantum mechanics, Ĥ (t) is usually a bounded operator and hence the

    exponential series in Û (t, t0) = e− � tt0 Ĥ(t)dtconverges so that its approximation to first

    order is acceptable giving i∂|ψ(t)〉∂t

    = Ĥ (t) |ψ (t)〉 which is the Schrödinger equationof wave mechanics. This may not always be the case in financial markets.

    (2) Since time evolution of financial market, essentially, occurs through trades in securi-

    ties, it is appropriate to infer that the Hamiltonian represents the trading activities

    of the market.

    (3) In order that the evolution operator Û (t, t0) is well defined, we mandate that the

    Hilbert space His so constructed that the kernel of Û (t, t0) is empty.

    1.3 Modeling Time Value of Money

    Time value of money and interest rate instruments are classically modeled through the

    first order differential equation dB(t)dt

    = r (t) B (t)with the solution B (t) = B (0) e�

    r(t)dt.

  • 20 Electronic Journal of Theoretical Physics 3, No. 11 (2006) 11–27

    A possible candidate for the Hamiltonian function H(in the classical picture) that would

    generate this temporal development as the equations of motion is

    H (x, p; t) =n∑

    i=1

    Hi (xi, pi; t) =n∑

    i=1

    ri (t) xi (t) pi (t) (37)

    This Hamiltonian leads to the following equations of motion

    dxi (t)

    dt=

    ∂Hi (xi, pi; t)

    ∂pi= ri (t) xi (t) ,

    dpi (t)

    dt= −∂Hi (xi, pi; t)

    ∂xi= −ri (t) pi (t) (38)

    While the interpretation of first of these equations is straightforward being the growth

    of cash reserves of the ithinvestor with the instantaneous rate ri (t), the implications of

    second equation are more subtle. To provide a financial logic to this equation, we note

    that pi is the infinitesimal generator of cash translations in the classical picture and hencedpi(t)

    dt= −∂Hi(xi,pi;t)

    ∂xi= −ri (t) pi (t) represents the rate of change of the cash translations

    generator which, given a fixed rate of growth of cash, would decrease with the amount of

    cash translations.

    Using the Weyl formalism for transformation from the classical to the quantum pic-

    ture, we require that the quantum mechanical analog of H (x, p; t) be Hermitian and

    symmetric in its component operators. Hence, we postulate the ansatz

    Ĥ (x̂ (t) , p̂ (t) ; t) =n∑

    i=1

    Ĥ (x̂i (t) , p̂i (t) ; t) =n∑

    i=1

    iri (t)

    2(x̂ip̂i + p̂ix̂i) =

    n∑i=1

    iri (t) x̂i

    (p̂i +

    1

    2Î

    )(39)

    for the quantum mechanical Hamiltonian representing the time value of money, so that

    the time development operator is

    Û (t, t0) = e

    �−i

    t�t0

    Ĥ(t)dt

    �= e

    n�i=1

    t�t0

    ri(t)xi(p̂i+ 12 Î)dt(40)

    which may be evaluated using standard methods like Green’s functions and Feynmann

    propagator theory.

    1.4 Representation of Trading Activity

    Let us consider a deal in which an investor ‘i’ buys a security ‘j’ at a price of ‘z’ units

    and immediately thereafter sells the same security to another investor ‘k’ at a price of

    ‘z′’ units and credits/debits the difference z′ − z to his cash account. The compositetransaction will, in our operator formalism, take the form b̂ij (z

    ′) b̂↑ij (z). In analogy withthis argument, we can represent the Hamiltonian for trading activity of the market as

    HTr (t) =∑i,j,k,l

    ∞∫0

    dz

    z

    ∞∫0

    dz′

    z′hijkl (ξ, t) b̂

    ↑ij (z) b̂kl (z

    ′) (41)

    where ξ = ln z′

    zensures that the amplitudes are scale invariant.

  • Electronic Journal of Theoretical Physics 3, No. 11 (2006) 11–27 21

    1.5 Probability Distribution of Stock Prices

    We now derive the probability distribution of stock prices in market equilibrium and show

    that the prices follow a lognormal distribution, thereby vindicating the efficacy of this

    model.

    For this purpose, we assume that an investor i = α buys one unit of a security j = β

    at time t = ti for a price z. We need to ascertain the probability PT (z′ |z )i.e. the

    probability of the security j = β having a price z′ at time tf = ti + T .We assume thatduring the period tf − ti, investor α holds exactly one unit of β and that before ti andafter tf ,α holds no unit of β.

    Let∣∣∣ψz

    αβ(ti)

    〉be the state that represents investor α holding exactly one unit of β at a

    price z at time tiin the Hilbert space H. Hence, we have∣∣∣ψz

    αβ(ti)

    〉= b̂↑αβ (z)

    ∣∣∣ψαβ (ti)〉where∣∣∣ψαβ (ti)〉is the state that represents investor α not holding any unit of β. This also im-plies that b̂αβ (z)

    ∣∣∣ψαβ (ti)〉 = 0.Let us assume that the final state corresponding to theinitial state

    ∣∣∣ψzαβ

    (ti)〉

    is represented by∣∣∣ψz

    αβ(tf )

    〉so that

    ∣∣ψzαβ(tf )〉 = Û(ti, tf ) ∣∣ψzαβ(ti)〉 = e−itf�

    ti

    Ĥdt

    b̂↑αβ(z)∣∣∣ψαβ(ti)〉 (42)

    The amplitudes of∣∣ψz′αβ (tf )〉 are determined in the usual way by taking scalar product〈

    ψz′

    αβ(tf )

    ∣∣∣ ψzαβ

    (tf )〉

    and we have, for the matrix elements of the propagator

    G (z′, tf ; z, ti) =〈ψαβ(tf )

    ∣∣∣ b̂αβ (z′) e−itf�

    ti

    Ĥdt

    b̂↑αβ(z)∣∣∣ψαβ(ti)〉 (43)

    In this case, the trading Hamiltonian will contain creation and annihilation operators

    relating to the investor α and those relating to the securityβ i.e., it will be of the form

    ĤTr (t) =∑k,l

    ∞∫0

    dz

    z

    ∞∫0

    dz′

    z′hαβkl (ξ, t) b̂

    ↑αβ (z) b̂kl (z

    ′) (44)

    We further make the assumption that the amplitudes can be approximated by their first

    two moments about ξ = 0, being sharply peaked about z′ = zsince, in the timescalesbeing considered, most trades would occur around z. Hence, we have

    hαβkl ∼[Ωαβkl (t) − iξ−1Ξαβkl (t)

    ]δ (ξ) (45)

    Noting that ξ = ln z′

    z, we have ξ−1 =

    (ln z

    ′z

    )−1=(

    z′z− 1)−1 = z

    z′−z to first order and

    δ (ξ) = δ(ln z

    ′z

    )= δ (z′ − z)

    [d�ln z

    ′z

    dz′

    ]−1= z′δ (z′ − z). Using these results and eqs. (44)

    & (45), we obtain

    ĤTr (t) ∼∑k,l

    ∞∫0

    dz

    z

    ∞∫0

    dz′

    z′zδ (z′ − z)

    [Ωαβkl (t) − i z

    z′ − zΞαβkl (t)]b̂↑αβ (z) b̂kl (z

    ′)

  • 22 Electronic Journal of Theoretical Physics 3, No. 11 (2006) 11–27

    =∑k,l

    ∞∫0

    dz

    zb̂↑αβ (z)

    [Ωαβkl (t) + izΞαβkl (t)

    ∂z

    ]b̂kl (z

    ′) (46)

    We note that this expression for the Hamiltonian is linear in ∂∂z

    and hence it can be

    diagonalized in the “momentum space” through a Fourier transformation and we have

    ĤTr (t) =1

    ∑k,l

    ∞∫0

    dz

    z

    ∞∫0

    dz′

    z′

    ∞∫−∞

    dpb̂↑αβ (z) [Ωαβkl (t) + iΞαβkl (t) p] b̂kl (z′) eipξ (47)

    The assumption of market equilibrium implies that the Hamiltonian should be inde-

    pendent of time over the relevant timescales that would be much smaller than those

    determining aggregate market behaviour so that we may write eq. (43) as

    G (z′, tf ; z, ti) =〈ψ

    αβ(ti)

    ∣∣∣ b̂αβ (z′) e−iĤ(ti)T b̂↑αβ (z) ∣∣∣ψαβ (ti)〉 (48)Because of the Hamiltonian being diagonal in momentum space, it is more convenient to

    work in momentum space for evaluating the propagators and we have, for the equivalent

    of eq. (48) in momentum space as

    G̃ (p′, p;T, ti) =〈ψ

    αβ(ti)

    ∣∣∣⎡⎣ ∞∫

    0

    dz′

    z′eip

    ′ln(z′/κ)b̂αβ (z′)

    ⎤⎦ e−iĤ(ti)T⎡⎣ ∞∫

    0

    dz

    ze−ipln(z/κ)b̂↑αβ (z)

    ⎤⎦ b̂↑αβ (z) ∣∣∣ψαβ (ti)〉(49)

    To solve the problem further, we make use of second order perturbation theory. The first

    step is to split the Hamiltonian into components as follows

    Ĥ (t) =∑

    l

    ∞∫0

    dz

    zb̂↑αβ (z) [Ωαβαl (t) + Ξαβαl (t) p] b̂αβ (z)+

    ∑k,l,k �=α

    ∞∫0

    dz

    zb̂↑αβ (z) [Ωαβkl (t) + iΞαβkl (t) p] b̂kl (z

    ′)

    (50)

    Let Eibe the energy eigenstate of the unperturbed Hamiltonian i.e. of the state of the

    market before the purchase of security β by the investor α , then the energy eigenstate

    of the Hamiltonian Ĥ (ti)i.e. after the purchase of security β by the investor α will be of

    the form Ep = Ei +∑l

    [Ωαβαl (ti) + iΞαβαl (ti) p]− ip2σ2where the second term representsthe impact on the energy eigenstates of the transactions involving investor α or security

    β and the last term is the second order perturbation term due to the overall fluctuations

    of the market. Substituting this value of Ep in eq. (49) and noting that the Hamiltonian

    and hence the propagator G̃ (p′, p; T, ti)is also diagonal in “momentum space”, we have

    G̃ (p′, p; T, ti) ∼ 2πδ (p′ − p) e−iTEp = 2πδ (p′ − p) e−iT [Ei+Ω(ti)+iΞ(ti)p−ip2σ2](51)

    where∑l

    Ωαβαl (ti) = Ω (ti) ,∑l

    Ξαβαl (ti) = Ξ (ti) .

    Inverting back to “coordinate space”, we obtain

    G (z′, tf ; z, ti) =1

    ∞∫−∞

    dpe−iT [Ei+Ω(ti)+iΞ(ti)p−ip2σ2]−ip ln z′/z ∼ e

    iT (Ei+Ω)

    2σ√

    πTe

    �(ln(z′/z)+ΞT)2

    4σ2T

    (52)

  • Electronic Journal of Theoretical Physics 3, No. 11 (2006) 11–27 23

    The probability PT (z′ |z )i.e. the probability of the security j = β having a price z′ at

    time tf = ti + T will then be proportional to the square of the above amplitude and

    hence, we finally obtain

    PT (z′ |z ) α |G (z′, tf ; z, ti)|2 =

    (4πσ2T

    )−1e

    �(In(z′/z)+ΞT)2

    2σ2T

    �(53)

    which agrees perfectly with the standard stochastic theory of finance wherein stock re-

    turns are modeled extensively through lognormal distributions.

    2. Conclusions

    The following interesting observations emanate from the above analysis:-

    (1) Eq. (53), on comparison with the standard expression for probability distribution

    of stock price in the conventional stochastic calculus based approach to the Black Scholes

    formula, identifies Ξ with the expected return on stock. This return is independent of

    the eigenvalue Eiand hence, the state of the market. A financial interpretation of this

    could be that the stock returns are dependent on the performance of the company and

    independent of market dynamics.

    (2) Independence of stock returns of the market dynamics would, however, mandate

    that the stock volatility measured by the standard deviation σ is related to the stock

    market dynamics which seems justified since higher trading volumes would imply greater

    volatility and vice versa.

    (3) If we define the uncertainty of measurement of a random variate by its standard

    deviation, then, from eqs. (52) & (53), we have the uncertainty for the stock price process

    zand its Fourier conjugate p, after a time T , as σz = σ√

    Tand σp =1

    2σ√

    Tso that σzσp =

    12

    as it should be, since the distribution of z is assumed Gaussian in the aforesaid analysis.

    (4) Furthermore, σzσp

    = 2σ2T which enables the identification of σ2 as the reciprocal

    of the mass and hence, the inertia of the stock price process. It is intriguing to note that

    the same analogy follows through another completely independent analysis i.e. the Black

    Scholes equation for the option price in its standard form is given by ∂C∂t

    = −rSt ∂C∂S −12σ2S2t

    ∂2C∂S2

    + rC, where C (St, t) denotes the instantaneous price of a call option with

    exercise price E at any time t before maturity when the price per unit of the underlying

    is St. Making the substitution St = exwe obtain ∂C

    ∂t= −r ∂C

    ∂x− 1

    2σ2 ∂

    2C∂x2

    + 12σ2 ∂C

    ∂x+ rC

    which, when compared with the standard quantum mechanical Hamiltonian in one degree

    of freedom identifies σ2 as the reciprocal of the mass of the underlying system.

    Contemporary quantitative finance is dominated by stochastic modeling of market

    behaviour. These models are essentially in the nature of tools of data analysis that aim

    to predict future events by applying probabilistic methods to historical data. Empirical

    evidence testifies that probability distributions of stock returns are negatively skewed,

    have fat tails and show leptokurtosis [56]. Some of the features of empirical distributions

    of stock prices are modeled through Levy distributions [57-60], stochastic volatility [61]

    or cumulant expansions around the lognormal case. Each of these models, however,

  • 24 Electronic Journal of Theoretical Physics 3, No. 11 (2006) 11–27

    attempts to empirically attune the model parameters to fit observed data and hence, is

    equivalent to interpolating or extrapolating observed data in one form or the other.

    Hence, stochastic models fail to take cognizance of causal factors that get submerged

    in the superficial patterns exhibited by the avalanche of data being analysed. In actual

    fact, every new price determination of a security and hence, the fluctuation of prices is

    attributable to a new trade in the relevant security at that price. The “trading process”

    therefore manifests itself as a price history of a security. The fundamental limitation of

    stochastic tools in simulating extended memory effects is circumvented by this approach.

    An attempt has also been made through this “toy model” to establish that a quantum

    mechanical version of financial markets results in a temporal evolution of the probabil-

    ity distribution analogous to that of simple stochastic systems. Stochastic models also

    lack ability to accommodate collective effects like phase coherency in lasers that could,

    possibly, be built into this quantized description.

    It need be emphasized here that the above is purely a phenomenological model for

    modeling stock behavior. It is fair to say that the current stage of research in financial

    processes is dominated by the postulation of phenomenological models that attempt to

    explain a limited set of market behavior. There is a strong reason for this. A financial

    market consists of a huge number of market players. Each of them is endowed with

    his own set of beliefs about rational behavior and it is this set of beliefs that govern

    his actions. The market, therefore, invariably generates a heterogeneous response to

    any stimulus. Furthermore, “rationality” mandates that every market player should have

    knowledge and understanding about the “rationality” of all other players and should take

    full cognizance in modeling his response to the market. This logic would extend to each

    and every market player so that we have a situation where every market player should have

    knowledge about the beliefs of every other player who should have knowledge of beliefs

    of every other player and so on. We, thus, end up with an infinitely complicated problem

    that would defy a solution even with the most sophisticated mathematical procedures.

    Additionally, unlike as there is in physics, financial economics does not possess a basic

    set of postulates like General Relativity and Quantum Mechanics that find homogeneous

    applicability to all systems in their domain of validity.

  • Electronic Journal of Theoretical Physics 3, No. 11 (2006) 11–27 25

    References

    [1] A. J. Macfarlane, J.Phys., A 22, (1989), 4581;

    [2] L.C. Biedenharn, J.Phys., A 22, (1989), L873;

    [3] S. Zakrzewski, J.Phys., A 31, (1998), 2929 and references therein; Shahn Majid, J.Math. Phy., 34, (1993), 2045;

    [4] Michael Schurmann, Comm. Math. Phy., 140, (1991), 589;

    [5] C. Blecken and K.A. Muttalib, J.Phys., A 31, (1998), 2123;

    [6] J. P. Singh, Ind. J. Phys., 76, (2002), 285;

    [7] U. Franz and R. Schott, J. Phys., A 31, (1998), 1395;

    [8] V.I. Man’ko et al, Phy. Lett., A 176, (1993), 173; V.I. Man’ko and R.Vileta Mendes,J.Phys., A 31, (1998), 6037;

    [9] W. Paul & J. Nagel, Stochastic Processes, Springer, (1999);

    [10] J. Voit, The Statistical Mechanics of Financial Markets, Springer, (2001);

    [11] Jean-Philippe Bouchard & Marc Potters, Theory of Financial Risks, Publication bythe Press Syndicate of the University of Cambridge, (2000);

    [12] J. Maskawa, Hamiltonian in Financial Markets, arXiv:cond-mat/0011149 v1, 9 Nov2000;

    [13] Z. Burda et al, Is Econophysics a Solid Science?, arXiv:cond-mat/0301069 v1, 8 Jan2003;

    [14] A. Dragulescu, Application of Physics to Economics and Finance: Money, Income,Wealth and the Stock Market, arXiv:cond-mat/0307341 v2, 16 July 2003;

    [15] A. Dragulescu & M. Yakovenko, Statistical Mechanics of Money, arXiv:cond-mat/0001432 v4, 4 Mar 2000;

    [16] B. Baaquie et al, Quantum Mechanics, Path Integration and Option Pricing:Reducing the Complexity of Finance, arXiv:cond-mat/0208191v2, 11 Aug 2002;

    [17] G. Bonanno et al, Levels of Complexity in Financial markets, arXiv:cond-mat/0104369 v1, 19 Apr 2001;

    [18] A. Dragulescu, & M. Yakovenko, Statistical Mechanics of money, income and wealth:A Short Survey, arXiv:cond-mat/0211175 v1, 9 Nov 2002;

    [19] J. Doyne Farmer, Physics Attempt to Scale the Ivory Tower of Finance, adap-org/9912002 10 Dec 1999;

    [20] V. Pareto, Cours d’Economie Politique (Lausannes and Paris),(1897);

    [21] L. Batchlier, Annelas Scientifiques de l’Normal Superieure III-17 21-86,(1900); P.Cootner, The Random Character of Stock Market Prices (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press) Reprint ,(1964);

    [22] F. Black & M. Scholes, Journal of Political Economy, 81, (1973), 637;

    [23] R. C. Merton, Journal of Financial Economics, (1976), 125;

    [24] M. Nagasawa, Stochastic Processes in Quantum Physics, Birkhauser, (2000);

  • 26 Electronic Journal of Theoretical Physics 3, No. 11 (2006) 11–27

    [25] E. Purgovecki, Stochastic Quantum Mechanics and Quantum Spacetime: Aconsistent unification of relativity and quantum theory based on stochastic spacesReidel, Dordrecht, 1st printing 1984, revised printing, 1986

    [26] M. Baxter & E. Rennie, Financial Calculus, Cambridge University Press, (1992).

    [27] H. Risken, The Fokker Planck Equation, Springer, (1996);

    [28] R.N. Mantegna & H.E. Stanley, An Introduction to Econophysics, Cambridge, (2000);

    [29] M.M. Dacrrogna et al, J. Int’l Money & Finance, 12, (1993), 413;

    [30] R.N. Mantegna & H.E. Stanley, Nature, 383, (1996), 587;

    [31] R.N. Mantegna, Physica A, 179, (1991), 232;

    [32] P. Gopikrishnan et al, Phys. Rev. E 60, (1999), 5305;

    [33] P. Gopikrishnan et al, Phys. Rev. E 62, (2000) R4493;

    [34] P. Gopikrishnan et al, Physica A, 299, (2001), 137;

    [35] P. Gopikrishnan et al, Phys. Rev. E 60, (1999) 5305;

    [36] V. Plerou et al, Phys. Rev. E 60, (1999) 6519;

    [37] W.F. Sharpe, Portfolio Theory & Capital Markets, McGraw Hill, (1970);

    [38] E.J. Elton & M.J. Gruber, Modern Portfolio Theory, & Investment Analysis, Wiley,(1981);

    [39] S.M. Ross, Stochastic Processes, John Wiley, (1999);

    [40] A. Ott el al., Phys. Rev.Lett. 65, (1990) 2201; J.P.Bouchaud et al., J.Phys.(France)II 1, (1991), 1465 ; C.-K. Peng et al., Phys. Rev. Lett. 70, (1993), 1343; R.N Mantegnaand H.E Stanley, Nature (London) 376, (1995) 46; T.H.Solomon et al., Phys. Rev.Lett.71, 3975 (1993); F.Bardou et al., ibid. 72, (1994), 203 ;

    [41] J. Klafter and G. Zumofen, Phys. Rev E 49, (1994), 4873,4;

    [42] H. Spohn, J. Phys. (France) I 3, (1993), 69;

    [43] M. Muskat, The Flow of Homogeneous Fluids Through Porous Media (McGraw-Hill,New York, (1937);

    [44] J. Buckmaster, J. Fluid Mech. 81 (1995), 735;

    [45] E.W. Larsen and G.C. Pomraning, SIAM J. Appl. Math. 39, (1980), 201;

    [46] W.L Kath, Physica D 12, (1984), 375;

    [47] J. Feigenbaum & P. G. O. Freund, Int. J Mod. Phys. B 10, (1996), 3737;

    [48] D Sornette, A. Johansen & J.P. Bouchaud, J. Phys. I (France ) 6, (1996), 167;

    [49] D. Sornette, Phys. Rep. 297, (1998), 239;

    [50] A. Wolf, J.B. Swift, S.L. Swinney & J.A. Vastano, Determining Lyapunov ExponentsFrom a Time Series, Physica 16D, (1985), 285;

    [51] B.B. Mandlebrot, The Fractal Geometry of Nature, Freeman Press, (1977);

    [52] G. DeBoek, Ed., Trading on the Edge, Wiley, (1994);

  • Electronic Journal of Theoretical Physics 3, No. 11 (2006) 11–27 27

    [53] J.G. DeGooijer, Testing Nonlinearities in World Stock Market Prices, EconomicsLetters, 31, (1989);

    [54] E. Peters, A Chaotic Attractor for the S&P 500, Financial Analysts Journal,March/April, (1991);

    [55] E. Peters, Fractal Structure in the Capital Markets, Financial Analysts Journal,July/August, 31, (1989); P. Cootner, Ed., The Random Character of Stock MarketPrices, Cambridge MIT Press, (1964);

    [56] E. Peters, Chaos & Order in the Capital Markets, Wiley, (1996) and referencestherein;

    [57] L. Andersen L & J. Andreasen, Review of Derivatives Research, 4, (2000), 231;

    [58] J.P. Bouchaud et al, Risk 93, (1996), 61;

    [59] J.P. Bouchaud & M.Potters, Theory of Financial Risks, Cambridge, (2000);

    [60] E. Eberlein et al, Journal of Business 71(3), (1998), 371;

    [61] B. Dupire, RISK Magazine, 8, January 1994;

  • EJTP 3, No. 11 (2006) 29–32 Electronic Journal of Theoretical Physics

    Rayleigh process and matrix elements for theone-dimensional harmonic oscillator

    J.H. Caltenco1∗, J.L. López-Bonilla1†, J. Morales2‡

    1Escuela Superior de Ingenieŕıa Mecánica y EléctricaInstituto Politécnico Nacional

    Edif. Z, Acc. 3-3er Piso Col. Lindavista C.P. 07738 México D.F.2Area de F́ısica AMA, CBI

    Universidad Autónoma Metropolitana-Azc.Apdo. Postal 16-306, CP 02200 México DF

    Received 21 December 2005 , Accepted 2 February 2005, Published 25 June 2006

    Abstract: We show that, the matrix elements 〈m |e−γ x |n 〉 for the one-dimensional harmonicoscillator have application in Markov process theory, permitting thus to resolve the Fokker-Planck equation for the two-dimensional probability density corresponding to Rayleigh case.c© Electronic Journal of Theoretical Physics. All rights reserved.

    Keywords: Matrix elements, One-dimensional harmonic oscillator, Markov process theory,Fokker-Planck equationPACS (2006): 03.65.Ta , 03.65.Ge ,02.50.Ga, 46.25.Cc, 02.70.Ns

    1. Introduction

    In [1-4] were calculated the matrix elements:

    f(γ) = 〈m| e−γx |n〉 =∫ ∝−∝

    ψ∗m(x) e−γ xψn(x)dx (1)

    for the harmonic oscillator in one dimension, where γ ≥ 0 is an arbitrary parameter.Then, it was deduced the following result for m ≥ n:

    f(γ) =

    √n !

    m !

    (− γ√

    2

    )m−neγ2/4Lm−nn

    (−γ

    2

    2

    )(2)

    [email protected]† jlopezb@ipn,mx, [email protected][email protected]

  • 30 Electronic Journal of Theoretical Physics 3, No. 11 (2006) 29–32

    in terms of the associated Laguerre polynomials Lqn.

    It is interesting to observe that the 2nd order differential equation [5-8] defining to

    Lpq permits to show, via (2), that f(γ)satisfies the equation:

    d2f

    dγ2+

    1

    γ

    df

    dγ− 1

    4γ2(γ4 + 4Aγ2 + 4Q

    )f = 0 (3)

    where A = m + n + 1 and Q = (m − n)2. That is, (2) is solution of (3), with which it ispossible to obtain [9] the Morse’s radial wave function [10].

    In Sec. 2, f(γ)is employed to resolve the nonstationary stochastic Fokker-Planck

    equation (FPE) [11] for the Rayleigh distribution.

    2. Two-Dimensional Probability Density Associated to Rayleigh

    Process.

    The equation (3) has the structure:

    D1(γ)f =

    (γ2

    4+ A +

    Q

    γ2

    )f (4)

    where it appears the important Bessel’s operator [12]:

    DC(γ) =d2

    dγ2+

    C

    γ

    d

    dγ(5)

    for the case C = 1. The operator (5) has interesting applications in hydrodynamics,

    the theory of subharmonic functions, electrostatics, the Euler-Poisson-Darboux equation,

    elasticity, the generalized radiation problem, quantum mechanics and generalized axially

    symmetric potential. Here we shall show that, the Bessel’s operator D1 is useful for to

    determine the probability density ω associated to Rayleigh process in two dimensions,

    because the FPE can adopt a form similar to (4).

    In fact, the nonstationary stochastic FPE for the Rayleigh distribution is given by

    [11] p. 73:

    ω̇ =∂

    ∂ x

    [(β x − k

    2x

    ]+

    k

    2

    ∂2ω

    ∂ x2(6)

    being k and β positive parameters, then the corresponding eigenfunctions X (x) are

    solutions of:

    σ2d2X

    d x2+

    (x − σ

    2

    x

    )d X

    d x+

    (1 +

    σ2

    x2+

    λ

    β

    )X = 0 (7)

    with σ2 = k2β

    . The operator D1 participates when in (7) we make the following change

    of functions:

    F (x) = x−1ex2

    4σ2 X (8)

    obtaining thus the relation:

    D1(x)F =

    (x2

    4σ4− 1

    σ2− λ

    σ2β

    )F (9)

  • Electronic Journal of Theoretical Physics 3, No. 11 (2006) 29–32 31

    On the other hand, in (4) it is possible to realize the formal change of variable:

    γ =i

    σx , i =

    √−1 (10)

    then it results the equation:

    D1(x)f =

    (x2

    4σ4+

    Q

    x2− A

    σ2

    )f , (11)

    with the same structure as (9); therefore Q = 0, that is m = n, and A = 2n+ 1 = 1 + λβ

    ,

    then λ = 2nβ , n= 0,1,2,. . . Besides, F is proportional to f given by (2) with the change

    (10):

    F ∝ e− x2

    4σ2 Ln

    (x2

    2σ2

    )(12)

    then (8), (12) and factors of normalization lead us to the eigenfunctions:

    Xn(x) =x

    n!σ2e−

    x2

    2σ2 Ln

    (x2

    2σ2

    )(13)

    which are solutions of (7) for λ = 2nβ. The result (13) is our principal aim because

    it permits to write immediately the two-dimensional probability density associated to

    Rayleigh case, to see [11].

  • 32 Electronic Journal of Theoretical Physics 3, No. 11 (2006) 29–32

    References

    [1] A. E. Glassgold and D. Holliday, Phys. Rev. A139 (1965) 1717.

    [2] J. Morales, J. López-Bonilla and A. Palma, J. Math. Phys. 28 (1987) 1032.

    [3] J. Morales and A. Flores-Riveros, J. Math. Phys. 30 (1989) 393.

    [4] J. López-Bonilla and G. Ovando, Bull. Irish Math. Soc. N.44 (2000) 61.

    [5] C. Lanczos, Linear differential operators, D. Van Nostrand Co., London (1961).

    [6] J. D. Talman, Special functions, W. A. Benjamin Inc. New York (1968).

    [7] H. Hochstadt, The functions of Mathematical Physics, Dover, New York (1971).

    [8] M. Abramowitz and I. A. Stegun, Handbook of mathematical functions, John Wileyand Sons, New York (1972).

    [9] J. H. Caltenco, J. López-Bonilla and R. Peña-Rivero, J. Sci. Res. 50 (2002) 125.

    [10] Ch. S. Johnson Jr. and L. G. Pedersen, Problems and solutions in QuantumChemistry and Physics, Dover, New York (1986).

    [11] R. L. Stratonovich, Topics in the theory of random noise. Vol. I, Gordon and Breach,New York (1963).

    [12] A. Weinstein, Ann. Mat. Pura Appl. 49 (1960) 359.

  • EJTP 3, No. 11 (2006) 33–70 Electronic Journal of Theoretical Physics

    Identical synchronization in chaoticjerk dynamical systems

    Vinod Patidar1∗ and K. K. Sud2

    1Department of PhysicsBanasthali Vidyapith Deemed UniversityBanasthali - 304022, Rajasthan, INDIA

    2Department of PhysicsCollege of Science Campus

    M. L. S. University, Udaipur – 313002, INDIA

    Received 23 December 2005 , Accepted 24 February 2006, Published 25 June 2006

    Abstract: It has been recently investigated that the jerk dynamical systems are the simplest ever systems, which possessvariety of dynamical behaviours including chaotic motion. Interestingly, the jerk dynamical systems also describe various

    phenomena in physics and engineering such as electrical circuits, mechanical oscillators, laser physics, solar wind driven

    magnetosphere ionosphere (WINDMI) model, damped harmonic oscillator driven by nonlinear memory term, biological

    systems etc. In many practical situations chaos is undesirable phenomenon, which may lead to irregular operations in

    physical systems. Thus from a practical point of view, one would like to convert chaotic solutions into periodic limit cycle

    or fixed point solutions. On the other hand, there has been growing interest to use chaos profitably by synchronizing chaotic

    systems due to its potential applications in secure communication. In this paper, we have made a thorough investigation

    of synchronization of identical chaotic jerk dynamical systems by implementing three well-known techniques: (i) Pecora-

    Carroll (PC) technique, (ii) Feedback (FB) technique and (iii) Active Passive decomposition (APD). We have given a

    detailed review of these techniques followed by the results of our investigations of identical synchronization of chaos in

    jerk dynamical systems. The stability of identical synchronization in all the aforesaid methods has also been discussed

    through the transversal stability analysis. Our extensive numerical calculation results reveal that in PC and FB techniques

    the x-drive configuration is able to produce the stable identical synchronization in all the chaotic jerk dynamical systems

    considered by us (except for a few cases), however y-drive and z-drive configurations do not lead to the stable identical

    synchronization. For the APD approach, we have suggested a generalized active passive decomposition, which leads to the

    stable identical synchronization without being bothered about the specific form of the jerk dynamical system. Several other

    active passive decompositions have also been listed with their corresponding conditional Lyapunov exponents to achieve

    the stable identical synchronization in various chaotic jerk dynamical systems.

    c© Electronic Journal of Theoretical Physics. All rights reserved.

    Keywords: Chaos, Jerk dynamical systems, Identical synchronization of chaos, synchronizedchaosPACS (2006): 05.45.+b; 47.52.+j; 05.45.-a

    ∗ vinod r [email protected]

  • 34 Electronic Journal of Theoretical Physics 3, No. 11 (2006) 33–70

    1. Introduction

    Various studies of nonlinear dynamical systems in the last four decades have signif-

    icantly extended the notion of oscillations in these systems. It has been shown that the

    post-transient oscillations in dynamical systems can be associated not only with the regu-

    lar behavior such as periodic or quasiperiodic oscillations, but also with chaotic behavior

    [1-5].

    Chaos has long-term unpredictable behavior, which is usually couched mathematically

    as sensitivity to initial conditions i.e., where the system’s dynamics takes it, is hard to

    predict from the starting point. One way to demonstrate this is to run two identical

    chaotic systems side by side, starting both at very close, but not exactly equal initial

    conditions. The systems soon diverge from each other, but both retain the same attractor

    pattern. An interesting question to ask is: Can we force the two chaotic systems to follow

    the same path on the attractor? i.e., Can chaotic systems be made synchronized? The

    affirmative answer is possible to this question. It has been shown that some of the ideas of

    synchronization can also be extended for the description of particular type of behaviour

    in c