1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

56
1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II

Transcript of 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

Page 1: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

1

Chapter 16

Capital Structure Decisions: Part II

Page 2: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

2

Topics in Chapter

MM and Miller models Hamada’s equation Financial distress and agency costs Trade-off models Asymmetric information theory

Page 3: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

3

Who are Modigliani and Miller (MM)? They published theoretical papers that

changed the way people thought about financial leverage.

They won Nobel prizes in economics because of their work.

MM’s papers were published in 1958 and 1963. Miller had a separate paper in 1977. The papers differed in their assumptions about taxes.

Page 4: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

4

What assumptions underlie the MM and Miller Models?

Firms can be grouped into homogeneous classes based on business risk.

Investors have identical expectations about firms’ future earnings.

There are no transactions costs.(More...)

Page 5: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

5

All debt is riskless, and both individuals and corporations can borrow unlimited amounts of money at the risk-free rate.

All cash flows are perpetuities. This implies perpetual debt is issued, firms have zero growth, and expected EBIT is constant over time.

(More...)

Page 6: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

6

MM’s first paper (1958) assumed zero taxes. Later papers added taxes.

No agency or financial distress costs.

These assumptions were necessary for MM to prove their propositions on the basis of investor arbitrage.

Page 7: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

7

Proposition I:

VL = VU.

Proposition II:

rsL = rsU + (rsU - rd)(D/S).

MM with Zero Taxes (1958)

Page 8: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

8

Given the following data, find V, S, rs, and WACC for Firms U and L.

Firms U and L are in same risk class. EBITU,L = $500,000. Firm U has no debt; rsU = 14%. Firm L has $1,000,000 debt at rd =

8%. The basic MM assumptions hold. There are no corporate or personal

taxes.

Page 9: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

9

VU = = = $3,571,429.

VL = VU = $3,571,429.

EBITrsU

$500,0000.14

1. Find VU and VL.

Page 10: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

10

VL = D + S = $3,571,429

$3,571,429 = $1,000,000 + S

S = $2,571,429.

2. Find the market value of Firm L’s debt and equity.

Page 11: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

11

rsL = rsU + (rsU - rd)(D/S)

= 14.0% + (14.0% - 8.0%)( )= 14.0% + 2.33% = 16.33%.

$1,000,000$2,571,429

3. Find rsL.

Page 12: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

12

WACC = wdrd + wcers = (D/V)rd + (S/V)rs

= ( )(8.0%)

+( )(16.33%)

= 2.24% + 11.76% = 14.00%.

$1,000,000$3,571,429

$2,571,429$3,571,429

4. Proposition I implies WACC = rsU. Verify for L using WACC formula.

Page 13: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

13

Without taxesCost of Capital (%)

26

20

14

8

0 20 40 60 80 100Debt/Value Ratio (%)

rs

WACC

rd

MM Relationships Between Capital Costs and Leverage (D/V)

Page 14: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

14

The more debt the firm adds to its capital structure, the riskier the equity becomes and thus the higher its cost.

Although rd remains constant, rs

increases with leverage. The increase in rs is exactly sufficient to keep the WACC constant.

Page 15: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

15

Value of Firm, V (%)

4

3

2

1

0 0.5 1.0 1.5 2.0 2.5Debt (millions of $)

VLVU

Firm value ($3.6 million)

With zero taxes, MM argue that value is unaffected by leverage.

Graph value versus leverage.

Page 16: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

16

With corporate taxes added, the MM propositions become:

Proposition I:

VL = VU + TD.

Proposition II:

rsL = rsU + (rsU - rd)(1 - T)(D/S).

V, S, rs, and WACC for Firms U and L (40% Corporate Tax Rate)

Page 17: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

17

Notes About the New Propositions

1. When corporate taxes are added,VL ≠ VU. VL increases as debt is added to the capital structure, and the greater the debt usage, the higher the value of the firm.

2. rsL increases with leverage at a slower rate when corporate taxes are considered.

Page 18: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

18

Note: Represents a 40% decline from the no taxes situation.

VL = VU + TD = $2,142,857 + 0.4($1,000,000)

= $2,142,857 + $400,000

= $2,542,857.

VU = = = $2,142,857.EBIT(1 - T)rsU

$500,000(0.6)0.14

1. Find VU and VL.

Page 19: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

19

VL = D + S = $2,542,857

$2,542,857 = $1,000,000 + S

S = $1,542,857.

2. Find market value of Firm L’s debt and equity.

Page 20: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

20

= 14.0% + (14.0% - 8.0%)(0.6)( ) = 14.0% + 2.33% = 16.33%.

$1,000,000$1,542,857

3. Find rsL.

rsL = rsU + (rsU - rd)(1 - T)(D/S)

Page 21: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

21

WACCL= (D/V)rd(1 - T) + (S/V)rs

= ( )(8.0%)(0.6)

+( )(16.33%)

= 1.89% + 9.91% = 11.80%.When corporate taxes are considered, the WACC is lower for L than for U.

$1,000,000$2,542,857

$1,542,857$2,542,857

4. Find Firm L’s WACC.

Page 22: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

22

Cost of Capital (%)

26

20

14

8

0 20 40 60 80 100Debt/Value Ratio (%)

rs

WACCrd(1 - T)

MM: Capital Costs vs. Leverage with Corporate Taxes

Page 23: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

23

Under MM with corporate taxes, the firm’s value increases continuously as more and more debt is used.

Value of Firm, V (%)

4

3

2

10 0.5 1.0 1.5 2.0 2.5

Debt(Millions of $)

VL

VU

TD

MM: Value vs. Debt with Corporate Taxes

Page 24: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

24

Miller’s Proposition I:

VL = VU + [1 - ]D.

Tc = corporate tax rate.Td = personal tax rate on debt income.Ts = personal tax rate on stock income.

(1 - Tc)(1 - Ts)(1 - Td)

Miller Model with Personal Taxes (Td

= 30% and Ts = 12%)

Page 25: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

25

VL = VU + [1 - ]D

= VU + (1 - 0.75)D

= VU + 0.25D.

(1 - 0.40)(1 - 0.12)(1 - 0.30)

Tc = 40%, Td = 30%, and Ts = 12%.

Value rises with debt; each $100 increase in debt raises L’s value by $25.

Page 26: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

26

Miller vs. MM Model with Corporate taxes

If only corporate taxes, thenVL = VU + TcD = VU + 0.40D.

Here $100 of debt raises value by $40. Thus, personal taxes lowers the gain from leverage, but the net effect depends on tax rates.

(More...)

Page 27: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

27

If Ts declines, while Tc and Td remain constant, the slope coefficient (which shows the benefit of debt) is decreased.

A company with a low payout ratio gets lower benefits under the Miller model than a company with a high payout, because a low payout decreases Ts.

Page 28: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

28

Why do personal taxes lower value of debt?

Corporate tax laws favor debt over equity financing because interest expense is tax deductible while dividends are not.

(More...)

Page 29: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

29

However, personal tax laws favor equity over debt because stocks provide both tax deferral and a lower capital gains tax rate.

This lowers the relative cost of equity vis-a-vis MM’s no-personal-tax world and decreases the spread between debt and equity costs.

Thus, some of the advantage of debt financing is lost, so debt financing is less valuable to firms.

Page 30: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

30

What does capital structure theory prescribe for corporate managers?

MM, No Taxes: Capital structure is irrelevant--no impact on value or WACC.

MM, Corporate Taxes: Value increases, so firms should use (almost) 100% debt financing.

Miller, Personal Taxes: Value increases, but less than under MM, so again firms should use (almost) 100% debt financing.

Page 31: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

31

Do firms follow the recommendationsof capital structure theory?

Firms don’t follow MM/Miller to 100% debt. Debt ratios average about 40%.

However, debt ratios did increase after MM. Many think debt ratios were too low, and MM led to changes in financial policies.

Page 32: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

32

How is analysis different if firms U and L are growing?

Under MM (with taxes and no growth) VL = VU + TD

This assumes the tax shield is discounted at the cost of debt.

Assume the growth rate is 7% The debt tax shield will be larger if

the firms grow:

Page 33: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

33

7% growth, TS discount rate of rTS

Value of (growing) tax shield = VTS = rdTD/(rTS –g)

So value of levered firm =VL = VU + rdTD/(rTS – g)

Page 34: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

34

What should rTS be?

The smaller is rTS, the larger the value of the tax shield. If rTS < rsU, then with rapid growth the tax shield becomes unrealistically large—rTS must be equal to rU to give reasonable results when there is growth. So we assume rTS = rsU.

Page 35: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

35

Levered cost of equity

In this case, the levered cost of equity is rsL = rsU + (rsU – rd)(D/S)

This looks just like MM without taxes even though we allow taxes and allow for growth. The reason is if rTS = rsU, then larger values of the tax shield don't change the risk of the equity.

Page 36: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

36

Levered beta

If there is growth and rTS = rsU then the equation that is equivalent to the Hamada equation is

bL = bU + (bU - bD)(D/S) Notice: This looks like Hamada

without taxes. Again, this is because in this case the tax shield doesn't change the risk of the equity.

Page 37: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

37

Relevant information for valuation

EBIT = $500,000 T = 40% rU = 14% = rTS

rd = 8% Required reinvestment in net

operating assets = 10% of EBIT = $50,000.

Debt = $1,000,000

Page 38: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

38

Calculating VU

NOPAT = EBIT(1-T) = $500,000 (.60) = $300,000

Investment in net op. assets = EBIT (0.10) = $50,000

FCF = NOPAT – Inv. in net op. assets= $300,000 - $50,000= $250,000 (this is expected FCF

next year)

Page 39: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

39

Value of unlevered firm, VU

Value of unlevered firm = VU = FCF/(rsU – g)

= $250,000/(0.14 – 0.07)= $3,571,429

Page 40: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

40

Value of tax shield, VTS and VL

VTS = rdTD/(rsU – g)

= 0.08(0.40)$1,000,000/(0.14-0.07)= $457,143

VL = VU + VTS

= $3,571,429 + $457,143 = $4,028,571

Page 41: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

41

Cost of equity and WACC

Just like with MM with taxes, the cost of equity increases with D/V, and the WACC declines.

But since rsL doesn't have the (1-T) factor in it, for a given D/V, rsL is greater than MM would predict, and WACC is greater than MM would predict.

Page 42: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

42

Cost of Capital for MM and Extension

0%

5%

10%

15%

20%

25%

30%

35%

40%

0% 10% 20% 30% 40% 50% 60% 70% 80%

D/V

MM cost of equity

MM WACC

Extension cost ofequityExtension WACC

Page 43: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

43

What if L's debt is risky?

If L's debt is risky then, by definition, management might default on it. The decision to make a payment on the debt or to default looks very much like the decision whether to exercise a call option. So the equity looks like an option.

Page 44: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

44

Equity as an option Suppose the firm has $2 million face

value of 1-year zero coupon debt, and the current value of the firm (debt plus equity) is $4 million.

If the firm pays off the debt when it matures, the equity holders get to keep the firm. If not, they get nothing because the debtholders foreclose.

Page 45: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

45

Equity as an option The equity holder's position looks

like a call option with P = underlying value of firm = $4

million X = exercise price = $2 million t = time to maturity = 1 year Suppose rRF = 6% = volatility of debt + equity = 0.60

Page 46: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

46

Use Black-Scholes to price this option

V = P[N(d1)] - Xe –rRF

t [N(d2)].

d1 =ln(P/X) + [rRF + (σ2/2)]t .

√σ t

d2 = d1 √- σ t .

Page 47: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

47

Black-Scholes Solution

V = $4[N(d1)] - $2e -(0.06)(1.0) [N(d2)].

ln($4/$2) + [(0.06 + 0.36/2)](1.0)d1 = (0.60)(1.0)

= 1.5552.

d2 = d1 – (0.60)(1.0) = d1 – 0.60

= 1.5552 – 0.6000 = 0.9552.

Page 48: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

48

N(d1) = N(1.5552) = 0.9401

N(d2) = N(0.9552) = 0.8383

Note: Values obtained from Excel using NORMSDIST function.

V = $4(0.9401) - $2e-0.06(0.8303) = $3.7604 - $2(0.9418)(0.8303) = $2.196 Million = Value of Equity

Page 49: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

49

Value of Debt

The value of debt must be what is left over:

Value of debt = Total Value – Equity= $4 million – 2.196 million= $1.804 million

Page 50: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

50

This value of debt gives us a yield

Debt yield for 1-year zero coupon debt

= (face value / price) – 1= ($2 million/ 1.804 million) –

1 = 10.9%

Page 51: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

51

How does affect an option's value?

Higher volatility means higher option value.

Page 52: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

52

Managerial Incentives

When an investor buys a stock option, the riskiness of the stock () is already determined. But a manager can change a firm's by changing the assets the firm invests in. That means changing can change the value of the equity, even if it doesn't change the expected cash flows:

Page 53: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

53

Managerial Incentives

So changing can transfer wealth from bondholders to stockholders by making the option value of the stock worth more, which makes what is left, the debt value, worth less.

Page 54: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

54

Value of Debt and Equity for Different Volatilities

$0.00

$0.50

$1.00

$1.50

$2.00

$2.50

$3.00

Volatility (Sigma)

Va

lue

(M

illio

ns

)

EquityDebt

Page 55: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

55

Bait and Switch

Managers who know this might tell debtholders they are going to invest in one kind of asset, and, instead, invest in riskier assets. This is called bait and switch and bondholders will require higher interest rates for firms that do this, or refuse to do business with them.

Page 56: 1 Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II.

56

If the debt is risky coupon debt

If the risky debt has coupons, then with each coupon payment management has an option on an option—if it makes the interest payment then it purchases the right to later make the principal payment and keep the firm. This is called a compound option.