0 f 317532 f 549449036000000

23
10.1177/0010414005282383 Comparative Political Studies Thames, Edwards / Mixed-Member Electoral Systems Differentiating Mixed- Member Electoral Systems Mixed-Member Majoritarian and Mixed-Member Proportional Systems and Government Expenditures Frank C. Thames Martin S. Edwards Texas Tech University, Lubbock, Texas The increasing use of mixed-member electoral systems has led to an explosion of research attempting to specify their effects. Yet there has been no work on the economic policy effects of such systems, even though this has been a signif- icant subject of debate for scholars analyzing other electoral systems. An anal- ysis of mixed-member system policy effects is problematic, given the wide variation in institutional rules among different systems. This article attempts to determine whether the institutional differences between mixed-member majoritarian (MMM) and mixed-member proportional (MMP) systems lead to differences in policy outputs. The political economy literature finds that gov- ernment expenditures are positively correlated with electoral system propor- tionality. Our statistical analysis of government expenditures in 17 mixed- member systems between 1990 and 2000 shows that MMP systems, which are more proportional than MMM systems, are correlated with higher levels of government spending. Thus the MMM-MMP distinction produces significant policy differences. Keywords: mixed-member system; fiscal policy; electoral system T he global explosion of mixed-member electoral systems has spurred sig- nificant research in a number of areas. Some analyze the decision to select a mixed-member system over competing alternatives (e.g., Bawn, 1993; Benoit & Schiemann, 2001; Navarra & Sobbrio, 2001; Remington & Smith, 1996; Shugart & Wattenberg, 2001b; Smith & Remington, 2001). Another focus of recent scholarship is the strategic responses of both parties and voters to the incentives created by mixing electoral rules (e.g., Bawn, 1 Comparative Political Studies Volume XX Number X Month 2006 1- © 2006 Sage Publications 10.1177/0010414005282383 http://cps.sagepub.com hosted at http://online.sagepub.com

Transcript of 0 f 317532 f 549449036000000

  • 10.1177/0010414005282383Comparative Political StudiesThames, Edwards / Mixed-Member Electoral Systems

    Differentiating Mixed-Member Electoral SystemsMixed-Member Majoritarian andMixed-Member Proportional Systemsand Government Expenditures

    Frank C. ThamesMartin S. EdwardsTexas Tech University, Lubbock, Texas

    The increasing use of mixed-member electoral systems has led to an explosionof research attempting to specify their effects. Yet there has been no work onthe economic policy effects of such systems, even though this has been a signif-icant subject of debate for scholars analyzing other electoral systems. An anal-ysis of mixed-member system policy effects is problematic, given the widevariation in institutional rules among different systems. This article attempts todetermine whether the institutional differences between mixed-membermajoritarian (MMM) and mixed-member proportional (MMP) systems lead todifferences in policy outputs. The political economy literature finds that gov-ernment expenditures are positively correlated with electoral system propor-tionality. Our statistical analysis of government expenditures in 17 mixed-member systems between 1990 and 2000 shows that MMP systems, which aremore proportional than MMM systems, are correlated with higher levels ofgovernment spending. Thus the MMM-MMP distinction produces significantpolicy differences.

    Keywords: mixed-member system; fiscal policy; electoral system

    The global explosion of mixed-member electoral systems has spurred sig-nificant research in a number of areas. Some analyze the decision toselect a mixed-member system over competing alternatives (e.g., Bawn,1993; Benoit & Schiemann, 2001; Navarra & Sobbrio, 2001; Remington &Smith, 1996; Shugart & Wattenberg, 2001b; Smith & Remington, 2001).Another focus of recent scholarship is the strategic responses of both partiesand voters to the incentives created by mixing electoral rules (e.g., Bawn,

    1

    Comparative Political StudiesVolume XX Number X

    Month 2006 1- 2006 Sage Publications

    10.1177/0010414005282383http://cps.sagepub.com

    hosted athttp://online.sagepub.com

  • 1999; G. Cox, 1997; K. Cox & Schoppa, 2002; Ferrara, 2004; Gschwend,Johnston, & Pattie, 2003; Ferrara & Herron, 2005; Herron & Nishikawa,2001; Moser, 1999, 2001; Moser & Scheiner, 2004; Reed, 2001). In a similarmanner, another group of scholars focuses specifically on the legislativeeffects of such systems, seeking to determine if the mixing of electoral incen-tives affects overall patterns of legislative behavior (e.g., Bawn & Thies,2003; Haspel, Remington, & Smith, 1998; Herron, 2002; Lancaster &Patterson, 1990; Stratmann & Baur, 2002; Thames, 2001).

    Although these studies are important, most of them focus on the electoraland party system effects of mixed-member systems rather than their potentialpolicy effects. Understanding when parties will coordinate campaigns,determining when they will form preelection alliances, conceptualizing howmixed-member legislators behave, or defining the conditions under whichvoters will split their votes are tremendously important questions. However,we have yet to understand how differences between mixed systems lead todifferences in policy outcomes, especially in the area of economic policy.This is a surprising lacuna given that the broader literature on electoral sys-tems increasingly focuses on the effects that different electoral systems haveon key economic policies.1

    An analysis of policy effects, or really any effect, of mixed-member sys-tems is hampered, however, by the simple fact that within the category ofmixed-member electoral systems, there is much variation. Almost all mixed-member systems combine the direct election of legislators in geographicallydefined districts, the nominal tier, with some form of a list proportional rep-resentation system, the list tier (Shugart & Wattenberg, 2001a). However,mixed-member systems can vary in number of areas including the type ofnominal-tier election (single-member districts or single nontransferablevote), the formula to determine the proportional representation results fromthe list tier, the proportion of legislators elected in the different elections, anda host of others. One critical distinction between mixed-member systems,however, is whether the separate tiers allocate seats independently (Shugart& Wattenberg, 2001a). In mixed-member proportional (MMP) systems,such as those in Germany or New Zealand, the total number of legislativeseats received by a party is proportional to its list-tier results. In mixed-mem-ber majoritarian (MMM) systems, such as those in Ukraine and Russia, how-ever, the list and nominal tiers both allocate seats independently, not trying to

    2 Comparative Political Studies

    1. Scholars find that electoral systems affect macroeconomic performance (Crepaz, 1996),government expenditures (Hallerberg & Marier, 2004), inflation (Rogowski & Kayser, 2002),trade policy (McGillivray, 1997; Nielson, 2003), and exchange rates (Bernhard & Leblang,1999; Leblang, 1999).

  • maintain proportionality between seats and votes. Thus MMM and MMPsystems differ primarily in their commitment to proportionality.

    Does this difference in proportionality matter? Bawn and Thies (2003)hypothesize that the decision to link tiers is critical. Linking tiers to obtainoutcomes that are more proportional means that MMP systems more closelyresemble pure proportional representation systems in terms of behavior andincentives, whereas MMM systems more closely resemble pure single-mem-ber district systems in terms of behavior and incentives. If true, then distinc-tions between MMP and MMM systems should produce divergent out-comes, raising questions about the value of collapsing mixed-membersystems into one category.

    This article seeks to deal with both the issue of the policy effects of mixedsystems as well as the broader issue of comparing mixed systems by under-taking a statistical analysis of government spending in 17 mixed-membersystems between 1990 and 2000.2 We not only begin the long process ofplacing mixed-member electoral systems within the context of the broaderelectoral systems literature on economic policy effects but also demonstratethat the MMM-MMP distinction is a critical one. We take our cue from thepolitical economy literature on government expenditures, which consistentlyfinds that they are positively correlated with more proportional electoral sys-tems that reward expensive public goods spending (Annett, 2002; Inter-American Development Bank, 1997; Persson, Roland, & Tabellini, 2000;Persson & Tabellini, 1999). Although our empirical results demonstratethat MMM systems spend less than comparable MMP systems as pre-dicted, this effect is contingent on the percentage of seats elected throughthe nominal tier of the electoral system. Moreover, this finding is robusteven if we examine spending on public goods, and not simply total govern-ment expenditures.

    After specifying the differences between MMM and MMP systems, wediscuss the literature on electoral systems and government expenditures.Then, the article presents statistical models that test the argument that MMMsystems will produce lower levels of government expenditures and lower lev-els of spending on public goods. The conclusion addresses the significanceof the arguments made here.

    Thames, Edwards / Mixed-Member Electoral Systems 3

    2. With the exceptions of Moser and Scheiner (2004) and Ferrara and Herron (2005), thereare very few large-N, cross-national studies of mixed-member electoral systems.

  • Distinguishing MMM and MMP Systems

    For most of the 20th century, the bulk of the worlds electoral systems fellinto two categories: majoritarian or proportional systems. In majoritariansystems, the candidate who attracts the most votes in a given district wins aseat. Such systems can differ on the number of representatives in a given dis-trict and whether they use majority or plurality rule. Nonetheless, such sys-tems are associated with not only the tendency to create two-party systems(Duverger, 1954) but also the representation of local interests (King, 1990).Proportional representation systems use multimember districts and usually,party lists, creating multiparty systems that tend to represent national constit-uencies. Much of the electoral reform for most of the 20th century featuredthe transition toward proportional representation systems from majoritariansystems, whereas the end of the 20th century has featured the explosion ofmixed-member electoral systems. Although Germany adopted its mixed-member system in 1953, the balance of mixed-member systems did notappear until the late 1980s and 1990s. New democracies, such as those inRussia and Ukraine, adopted these systems in the initial postcommunistyears. However, the adoption of mixed-member systems was not limited tonew democracies. Italy, Japan, and New Zealand chose mixed-membersystems as replacements for their previous systems.

    Typically, mixed-member systems blend representation by pairing a nom-inal-tier election with a list-tier election. In the nominal-tier election, votersvote for individual candidates, who accrue the votes independently of party(Shugart & Wattenberg, 2001a). The majority of mixed-member systems usesingle-member district elections for the nominal tier; however, Taiwan, forexample, uses a single nontransferable vote election for the nominal tier. Forthe list tiers, legislative seats are distributed according to votes for multiplecandidates nominated on party lists (Shugart & Wattenberg, 2001a). Mixed-member systems often vary on whether the list-tier election is in a national orregional district, whereas almost all mixed-member systems use some ver-sion of a proportional representation system (dHondt, largest remainder,etc.) with closed party lists.

    Although the benefits to research on mixed-member systems are great,the difficulties of studying them are also great given the wide range of institu-tional rules that encompass them. If we look at mixed-member systems, wefind a plethora of axes along which they may vary institutionally: the ratio ofnominal-tier to list-tier seats, the electoral formula used in both the nominaland list tiers, the district magnitude of the list-tier election, the legal thresholdof the list-tier election, and the relationship between the tiers (Moser, 2001).

    4 Comparative Political Studies

  • Potentially, these variations could significantly alter the effects of differentmixed-member systems, raising doubts about our ability to treat them as aseparate class of systems or simply variations of majoritarian or list systems.Consequently, to understand better the effects of mixed-member systems onpolicy outcomes, or on other dependent variables, we need to come to gripswith distinctions between systems.

    Theoretically, the decision to link tiers is a critical decision, given how itchanges the incentives for parties and legislators. To understand this, we firstmust grapple with implications of mixing a tier that creates incentives fornational representation with a tier that creates incentives for local representa-tion. In either single-member district or single nontransferable vote systems,legislators achieve reelection by winning local elections. This creates astrong electoral connection for individual legislators to support the inter-ests of their local constituency, often at the expense of party or national con-cerns (Bean, 1990; Fenno, 1978; Fiorina, 1997; Mayhew, 1974; North, 1994;Norton & Wood, 1990; Reed & Thies, 2001; Ward & Peter, 1999). Con-versely, the list tier encourages the representation of national issues by bothparties and individual legislators. Because parties compete in large, some-times national, multimember constituencies, party leaders and individuallegislators have a strong incentive to promote policies that speak to a broaderswath of voters. A party in a list election that focused only on parochial issueswould risk losing important votes in other regions. Consequently, the list tiercreates positive incentives for parties and legislators to move beyond limited,regional interests and trumpet national issues more likely to appeal to largergroups. Thus the simultaneous use of both a nominal and list tier theoreti-cally creates an electoral system that should give parties and legislatorsincentives to embrace both national and regional interests.

    In terms of legislative behavior, this should create legislatures that featuretwo distinct patterns of behavior based on the different electoral incentives ofnominal- and list-tier legislators. The mandate divide hypothesis has beentested in a number of different contexts with mixed results. Several studiesfind meaningful differences between nominal- and list-tier legislators incommittee preferences (Stratmann & Baur, 2002), preferences for pork bar-rel spending (Lancaster & Patterson, 1990), propensity for constituencywork (Scholl, 1986), and party discipline (Thames, 2001). Smith andRemington (2001) find some evidence of a mandate divide in the RussianDuma; however, the appearance of the divide often varies depending on theissue. Others find little evidence of a mandate divide (Herron, 2002; Ishiyama,2000).

    Thames, Edwards / Mixed-Member Electoral Systems 5

  • None of these legislative behavior studies, however, address the potentialdistinctions between MMM and MMP systems. In MMP systems, a partystotal number of seats is determined by its percentage of the vote in the list tier(Shugart & Wattenberg, 2001a). In the German system, for example, thismeans that parties add list seats to their total nominal seats to have their totalnumber of seats proportional to their list vote result. Effectively, MMP sys-tems link their tiers, because a partys overall allocation of seats dependson the interaction of the results of both tiers. This ensures greater proportion-ality in the legislature with the list-tier results. In MMM systems, however,both the nominal and list tiers independently allocate seats to parties(Shugart & Wattenberg, 2001a). Thus in the Russian system, for example,the nominal-seat total is added to the list-seat total to determine the totalnumber of Duma seats allocated to an individual party. There is no attempt tomaintain proportionality with the list-tier vote for total party seat allocationin MMM systems; therefore, the tiers are unlinked.3

    The decision to link or unlink the tiers could have a significant impact onthe effects of each system because they produce different incentives for poli-ticians and parties. This becomes clear if we simply assume that parties ineach system want to maximize their number of seats in the legislature andthat legislators strive primarily for reelection. In MMP systems, a party max-imizes seats by winning as many list votes as possible because its overallnumber of legislative seats will be determined by the list tier. As Bawn andThies (2003) cogently point out, this means that political parties are less con-cerned about winning nominal seats because winning these seats does notadd to the partys overall seat total. This does not mean that political parties inMMP systems have no interest in supporting candidates in these elections,for having strong local candidates may improve the partys list vote (Bawn &Thies, 2003; Herron & Nishikawa, 2001). However, it does mean that politi-cal parties may prefer to support candidates who will consistently support theparty and the partys agenda to maximize national prospects in the list tier.Legislators who were interested only in supporting local constituents inter-ests would undermine the partys coherence and its need to satisfy nationalconcerns. Even if such legislators were popular candidates, winning nominalseats by large majorities would not increase the partys overall seat total inMMP systems. Thus parties have a reduced incentive to back popular but ill-disciplined candidates.

    6 Comparative Political Studies

    3. In some systems, the votes for a partys failed nominal-seat candidates are added to its listtotal (Shugart & Wattenberg, 2001b). This does not produce the same incentives as produced bymixed-member proportional (MMP) systems that link seats, because parties have an incentive tosupport strong local, but perhaps not victorious, candidates to obtain more votes to ensure com-pensatory seats.

  • In MMM systems, however, political parties are in a different situation.Because the partys seat total is increased by winning nominal seats, politicalparties are more beholden to successful, although perhaps wayward, nomi-nal-tier legislators (Bawn & Thies, 2003). In this situation, parties may beforced to cater more often to the demands of parochial legislators to increaseoverall seat totals by helping them win local elections. A party that ignoresthe constituency demands of its nominal-tier legislators in favor of morenational concerns might sacrifice its overall seat total. Therefore, in MMMsystems, parties must be more flexible in their policy stances to placate notonly their list but also their nominal-tier needs.

    Moreover, for parties seeking to build coalitions, MMM systems createpotentially two sets of legislators from which to pull support. A party seekingto build coalitions in an MMP system faces legislators who are tied to politi-cal parties that cater to national interests. For a party in an MMM system, theterrain is different. Potentially, a party could build intraparty and interpartycoalitions with not only list-tier legislators tied to parties but also more paro-chial nominal-tier legislators. In such circumstances, parties (and even exec-utives) have more flexibility to build coalitions around legislators with differ-ent incentives. This may allow parties to build coalitions that are not simplybased on legislator and party perceptions of their national interests.

    What does this difference mean in terms of the policy outputs of mixed-member electoral systems? Bawn and Thies (2003) conclude that MMM isnot only more like pure SMD [single-member district] (and MMP more likepure PR [proportional representation]) in terms of seat shares but also interms of electoral incentives of district members (p. 23). If the linking oftiers in MMP systems gives parties an incentive to focus on national issueseven with nominal legislators, then the behavior of MMP systems shouldresemble those of pure proportional representation systems.4 Conversely, theincentives produced by MMM systems for nominal-tier legislators to cater toparochial interests, coupled with the parties weak incentives to stop them,means that such systems will behave more like pure majoritarian systems.Thus the presence of nominal-tier legislators beholden to local constituentsdistinguishes it from MMP systems. If the institutional incentives created byinstitutional variations between MMM and MMP systems matter, then wewould expect policy patterns in each system to diverge. In MMM systems,policy making should resemble patterns found in majoritarian electoral sys-

    Thames, Edwards / Mixed-Member Electoral Systems 7

    4. Bawn (1993) also points out that supporters of the creation of the original German MMPsystem chose it because they assumed it would produce effects similar to proportional represen-tation systems.

  • tems. Conversely, in MMP systems, policy making should resemble patternsfound in proportional representation electoral systems.5

    Electoral Systems and Government Expenditures

    The dearth of policy effects studies of mixed-member systems is surpris-ing given the significant attention paid to the subject in the broader electoralsystems literature. The effect of different electoral rules has been particularlyanalyzed in the comparative political economy literature on governmentexpenditure. This literature consistently finds that majoritarian electoral sys-tems produce lower levels of government expenditure than do proportionalrepresentation electoral systems (Annett, 2002; Grilli, Masciandaro, &Tabellini, 1991; Inman, 1990; Inter-American Development Bank, 1997;Kontopoulos & Perotti, 1999; Perotti & Kontopoulos, 2002; Persson et al.,2000; Persson & Tabellini, 1999). Assuming that the distinction in institu-tional rules that makes MMM systems behave more like pure majoritariansystems and MMP systems behave more like pure proportional representa-tion systems is significant, then government expenditures should be lower inMMM systems than in MMP systems.6

    How does the literature arrive at the conclusion that these electoral sys-tems will produce different levels of government expenditures? Previousworks connect proportional representation to higher expenditures throughtwo lines of argument. The first suggests that proportional representationsystems can aggravate collective action problems in fiscal policy making bycreating coalition governments (Annett, 2000; Grilli et al., 1991; Inman,1990; Inter-American Development Bank, 1997; Kontopoulos & Perotti,1999; Perotti & Kontopoulos, 2002; Persson & Tabellini, 1999; Peterson,1985/1986; Roubini & Sachs, 1989). Increases in the number of partiesforces governments to accommodate the spending demands of more actors,producing higher expenditures and making fiscal adjustment more difficult.

    8 Comparative Political Studies

    5. The similarity between mixed-member majoritarian (MMM) systems and majoritariansystems and MMP and proportional systems is found in other studies of the political effects ofmixed-member systems (K. Cox & Schoppa, 2002; Ferrara & Herron, 2005; Moser, 2001; Rob-erts, 1988).

    6. Moser (2001) points out that mixed-member systems provide the opportunity to test theo-ries on two different electoral systems while holding other factors such as culture, social cleav-ages, and level of socioeconomic development constant (p. 21). Some argue this is difficultbecause of contamination or interaction effects between the tiers (K. Cox & Schoppa, 2002;Ferrara & Herron, 2005; Herron & Nishikawa, 2001); however, this corruption may not be signif-icant enough to undermine the usefulness of the controlled comparison (Moser, 2001; Moser &Scheiner, 2004).

  • A second line of argument focuses more on the electoral dimensions ofproportional representation systems. In most proportional representationsystems, seats are allocated on the basis of party performance in large, some-times nationwide, constituencies. As a result, parties face incentives to adoptpolicies that speak to as broad a swath of voters as possible, not limitingthemselves to narrow interests (Lizzeri & Persico, 2001; Milesi-Ferretti &Perotti, 2002; Persson & Tabellini, 1999). Consequently, parties in these sys-tems can maximize votes by delivering public goods to large classes of vot-ers. Such spending tends to be expensive, leading to increases in overallgovernment expenditure.

    The incentives created by majoritarian systems, on the other hand, canlead to lower government expenditures. First, the lower number of partiesoften found in majoritarian electoral systems reduces the level of competi-tion concerning fiscal policy in comparison with proportional representationsystems by making coalition government and gridlock less likely. Conse-quently, the spending dynamic found in multiparty proportional representa-tion systems is less of a problem in majoritarian systems. In addition,majoritarian systems produce fewer incentives for expensive public goodsspending in comparison with proportional representation systems. In majorit-arian systems, legislators prefer to provide targeted spending to select blocs ofvoters to achieve a majority of votes in their constituencies. As Mayhew(1974) notes, this allows deputies to claim credit for targeted spending.

    Most important for us, this weakens, but obviously does not eliminate, theincentive to increase public good expenditures to satisfy large, nationwideclasses of voters. By having nominal-tier legislators seeking to reap the bene-fits of targeted spending, coupled with the fact that parties must cater to theselegislators to maximize votes, expenditure bills can be passed in MMM legis-latures with targeted appeals to nominal-tier legislatures, and not simply withmore expensive public goods spending. Another way to think about it is toconsider the situation of an executive attempting to pass the yearly state bud-get. In an MMP system, creating a successful budget coalition requires pro-viding enough public goods spending to entice the support of parties whomaximize seats by winning nationally. In an MMM system, the executive isin a different situation. Although providing public goods spending can getvotes from some legislators and parties, executives can also use targetedspending to increase support for the budget among nominal-tier legislators.Thus executives can essentially buy legislative support with particularistictransfers, avoiding the more expensive public goods spending. Potentially,executives in MMM systems could build not only intraparty butalso interparty coalitions, using the lure of particularistic resources to enticenominal-tier legislatures who must satisfy local constituents at all costs. In an

    Thames, Edwards / Mixed-Member Electoral Systems 9

  • MMP system, however, executives are forced to bargain with other partiesover expensive public goods spending. Thus coalition building in MMP sys-tems is more expensive in MMM systems, leading, potentially, to both moreoverall expenditures and more public goods expenditures.

    This discussion leads to two key conclusions for the work that follows.First, if our contention that the distinction between MMM and MMP is a sub-stantive one, we expect a similar link between proportionality and govern-ment spending and find that MMM systems produce lower levels of govern-ment expenditure than MMP systems:

    Hypothesis 1: MMM systems will have lower levels of government expenditurethan MMP systems.

    Second, it is possible that the effect of MMM systems will be conditionalnot simply on the absence of the link between the tiers but also the proportion

    10 Comparative Political Studies

    Table 1Data Set of Mixed-Member Electoral Systems

    Mixed Nominal-Tier Executive Years inCountry System Type Percentage Type Data Set

    Albaniaa MMP 74.2 Presidential 2Bolivia MMP 52.3 Presidential 4Georgia MMM 36.2 Presidential 4Germany MMP 50 Parliamentary 9Hungary MMM 45.6 Parliamentary 10Italy MMM 75.4 Parliamentary 6Japan MMM 60 Parliamentary 7Lithuania MMM 50.4 Semipresidential 8Mexico MMM 60 Presidential 3New Zealand MMP 54.2 Parliamentary 5Panama MMM 36.6 Presidential 8Philippines MMM 93.7 Presidential 3Russia MMM 50 Semipresidential 3South Korea MMM 80.5b Presidential 9Taiwan MMM 76.9b Presidential 4Ukraine MMM 50 Semipresidential 2Venezuela MMP 45.2b Presidential 8

    Note: MMM = mixed-member majoritarian; MMP = mixed-member proportional.a. Between 1992 and 1996, Albania employed an MMM system. Our data for government spend-ing in Albania, however, cover only the MMP period.b. Because of changes in the electoral system, this is the average percentage of nominal-tier seatsacross the different systems.

  • of nominal-tier legislators. The proportion of nominal-tier to list-tier legisla-tors varies significantly between different electoral systems. For example,although the Russian and Ukrainian systems elect 50% of their legislators inthe nominal tier, the Philippine systems elects 93.7% of its legislators in thenominal tier. If the expenditure savings in MMM systems comes from theability of executives or parties to build budget coalitions with targeted spend-ing aimed at nominal-tier legislators, it makes sense that expenditures wouldvary based on the amount of nominal-tier legislators. A larger pool of nomi-nal-tier legislators creates more opportunities to use cheaper particularisticspending to build coalitions. If this insight were correct, we would expect that

    Hypothesis 2: In MMM systems the level of government expenditure shoulddecrease as the percentage of nominal-tier seats increases.

    In addition, the difference between systems may be not merely in totalgovernment expenditures but also in levels of public goods spending. If legis-lators in proportional representation systems desire more public goodsspending than legislators in majoritarian systems, then we should definitelysee differences in public goods spending between these systems. If we do notfind such a link, then one could argue that the levels of increased spendingmay simply reflect greater transfer payments and pork barrel politics, andnot greater public goods spending. Thus the following can be hypothesized:

    Hypothesis 3: MMM systems will have lower levels of public goods spending thanMMP systems.

    Hypothesis 4: In MMM systems, the level of public goods spending shoulddecrease as the percentage of nominal-tier seats increases.

    Data and Method

    To test our hypotheses, we constructed a data set of 17 countries withmixed-member electoral systems between 1990 and 2000 (see Table 1).7 Wedid not include observations for those years in which countries were notat least minimally democratic.8 Moreover, the lack of data forced us toeliminate several potential cases such as Armenia, Azerbaijan, Cameroon,Croatia, Guinea, Guatemala, Macedonia, Senegal, Thailand, and Tunisia.

    Thames, Edwards / Mixed-Member Electoral Systems 11

    7. This range of cases was driven primarily by the availability of data and the fact that the1990s saw the creation of so many new systems.

    8. For an observation to be included, the country must have scored at least six on the Democ-racy score in the Polity IV data set (Polity IV Project, 2000).

  • The Bulgarian legislature elected by the mixed system served for only 1 year;therefore, it is also removed from the sample.9

    We employ two dependent variables to test our hypotheses. First, we mea-sure government expenditure as a percentage of GNP (Bank of Japan, 2004;Republic of China Directorate-General of Budget, Accounting, and Statis-tics, 2002; World Bank, 2002). This variable is the best available cross-national measure of government spending. Second, we measure publicgoods as the percentage of government spending devoted to social supportprograms (International Monetary Fund, 2004 2003 IN REF). Social sup-port programs are by definition universal in design and cannot be tailored tothe specific demands of citizens. Thus this operationalization fits the notionof a public good well. For our purposes, this includes spending on programsfor sickness and disability, old age, survivors, families and children, unem-ployment, and housing (International Monetary Fund, 2001).10

    To estimate these equations, we use time-series regression models thatemploy panel-corrected standard errors with an AR (1) specification. TheWooldridge (2002) test for autocorrelation in panel data indicated the pres-ence of autocorrelation in all model specifications. This is not surprising,given that one of the strongest determinants of expenditure in a given year isthe level of expenditure in the previous year. Thus we use an AR (1) specifi-cation in all models and assume the autocorrelation is common to all panels(N. Beck & Katz, 1995). In addition, the model assumes that the errors areheteroscedastic and correlated across panels.

    To understand mixed-electoral system effects on overall state spendingand public goods spending, we use two independent variables. First, MMMis a dummy variable that indicates those systems that are MMM systems. Inour data set, there are 5 states with MMP systems and 12 states with MMMsystems. If Hypotheses 1 and 3 are correct, then this variable should be nega-tively correlated with both total government expenditures as a percentage ofGNP and with the percentage of public goods spending when controlling forother factors.

    To test the effect of the percentage of nominal-tier seats (Hypotheses 2and 4), we construct an interaction term between MMM and the percentageof nominal-tier seats. If our hypotheses are correct, this variable should benegatively correlated with both total government expenditures as a percent-

    12 Comparative Political Studies

    9. Some states adopted mixed-member systems during the period covered in our data set. Tocontrol for this, we ran several models with dummy variables indicating these countries andfound no significant changes in the results.

    10. We do not claim that differences between types of mixed systems affect the year-on-yearchange in spending levels, because our argument does not address how differences in mixed sys-tems make it easier for politicians to increase or decrease the rate of change of governmentexpenditure.

  • age of GNP and with the percentage of public goods spending when control-ling for other factors.

    For models with the interaction term, however, we do not include the maineffects variable MMM. Although this goes against standard practice, thereare solid theoretical reasons to remove this variable from the models. In amodel that included the interaction and the MMM main effects variable, wewould interpret the main effects variable as an MMM system with no nomi-nal-tier seats. This would be equivalent to a pure proportional representationsystem. More important, when nominal-tier seats are 0, there is no theoreticaldifference between MMM and MMP. Thus we drop the main effects MMMvariable because the difference between MMM and MMP can exist onlywhen the percentage of nominal-tier seats is above 0.11 Furthermore, it

    Thames, Edwards / Mixed-Member Electoral Systems 13

    Table 2Time-Series Regression on Government Spending as a Percentage of

    GNP

    Model 1 Model 2 Model 3Independent Variable Coefficient Coefficient Coefficient

    GNP per capita(t 1) 0.0002 (0.0002) 0.0003 (0.0002) 0.0002 (0.0002)Growth(t 1) 0.0307 (0.1021) 0.0400 (0.1084) 0.0389 (0.1071)Unemployment(t 1) 0.1086 (0.2078) 0.1185 (0.2179) 0.1164 (0.2159)Percentage of populationolder than 65 0.5070 (0.4141) 0.6754 (0.4494) 0.6488 (0.4363)

    Openness(t 1) 0.0345 (0.0283) 0.0332 (0.0296) 0.0343 (0.0299)Inflation(t 1) 0.0014 (0.0041) 0.0016 (0.0043) 0.0015 (0.0043)Lagged election (1,0) 0.0086 (0.7834) 0.0685 (0.8183) 0.0517 (0.8265)Effective number ofpolitical parties 0.6537 (0.4824) 0.5919 (0.5726) 0.5530 (0.5707)

    Presidentialsystem (1,0) 9.5665** (4.2084) 9.5554** (4.1587) 9.5126* (4.1148)

    MMM (1,0) 3.3509*** (1.2328) 4.0303*** (1.5006)Percentage ofnominal-tier seats 6.7717 (6.6715) 13.1901* (7.6555)

    MMM*Percentage ofnominal-tier seats 7.5632*** (2.4018)

    Constant 29.5542*** (8.5820) 25.4347** (10.7870) 21.8163* (11.1675)Countries 17 17 17Cases 95 95 95Model chi-square test 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000

    Note: Panel-Corrected standard errors in parentheses. MMM = mixed-member majoritarian.*p > .10. **p > .05. ***p > .01.

    11. The authors would like to thank Kathleen Bawn and an anonymous reviewer for makingthis point to us.

  • should be noted that this situation does not correspond to a real world case.Consequently, we report models with the interaction term of MMM andnominal-tier seat percentage without the main effects variable MMM.12

    To control for potential economic determinants of government expendi-ture, we include a host of lagged independent variables that could potentiallyaccount for changes in government expenditure: GNP per capita, GNPgrowth, unemployment, the percentage of the population older than 65 yearsof age, openness of the economy to trade, and the rate of inflation as mea-sured by a GDP deflator. These control variables are standard in the econo-metric analysis of fiscal policy (Milesi-Ferretti & Perotti, 2002; Perotti &Kontopoulos, 2002) and are taken from the World Banks (2002) WorldDevelopment Indicators.

    In addition, our regression models employ further political controls. Sev-eral studies indicate that presidential systems tend to be associated withlower levels of spending (Baldez & Carey, 2001; McCarty, 2000; Perssonet al., 2000; Persson & Tabellini, 1999). Thus we will estimate models usinga presidential dummy variable as well. For this variable, all presidentialsystems are coded 1.

    We also include a control for the number of political parties in the politicalsystem in all models. The increased spending in MMP systems might simplybe because of the number of political parties and not what types of spendingthey demand. To control for the effect of multiple parties, we include a vari-able measuring the effective number of political parties (T. Beck, Clarke,Groff, Keefer, & Walsh, 2001; Taagepera & Shugart, 1979).

    Finally, we include a lagged dummy variable indicating an election in theprevious year. The literature on the political business cycle suggests thatexpenditures may increase as incumbent governments ramp up spending tosecure electoral support (Alesina, 1994; Schultz, 1998). To ensure that ourresults correctly attribute changes in expenditures to the existing politicalinstitutions, we control for preelection years as well.

    Results

    Table 2 presents the time-series regression results on government spend-ing as a percentage of GNP. Models 1 and 2 show strong support for Hypoth-esis 1. Even after controlling for other institutional factors, including thepresence of a presidential system, lagged elections, and the effective numberof political parties in the legislature, governments in MMM systems have

    14 Comparative Political Studies

    12. The substantive results of the model do not differ if we include the MMM main effectsvariable.

  • consistently lower levels of expenditure on the order of more than 3% ofGNP (Model 1). The effect of MMM systems holds even when we control forthe percentage of nominal-tier seats (Model 2). Yet although strong theoryand prior empirical work both recommend the inclusion of the control vari-ables, none of them individually are significant determinants of the level ofexpenditure.13

    Turning to Model 3 in Table 2, the percentage of nominal seats increasesgovernment spending as a percentage of GNP only in those systems that areMMP. This suggests that Hypothesis 2 may be correct. To confirm Hypothe-sis 2, however, requires that we assess the effect of increasing the percentageof nominal seats in MMM systems. The variable MMM*nominal-tier seatpercentage tells us how these two variables are related, and from Model 3 wesee that the slope of the regression line changes substantially as we increasethe percentage of nominal-tier seats. From this, we see that as the nominal-tier seat percentage increases, the distinction between MMM and MMPbecomes more salient, as MMM systems have even lower levels of govern-ment expenditure.14

    To better illustrate the magnitude of these effects, we follow Brambor,Clark, and Golders (2004) advice to illustrate graphically the marginaleffects of MMM on government expenditure across the observed range ofnominal-tier percentage. The graph of this effect is shown in Figure 1. Wehave added confidence bands around the estimate to make our results moreapparent.

    Figure 1 suggests that differences between MMM and MMP are notmerely a pure intercept difference but instead, are closely related to the per-centage of nominal seats. When the percentage of nominal seats is low, theseconfidence intervals are wide and only one of them is above the 0 line. As thepercentage of nominal seats increases past 60%, the upper and lower boundsof the confidence intervals are both negative, telling us that MMM systemsexhibit significantly lower levels of government spending in this range ofnominal seats, as suggested in Hypothesis 2.15

    Of course, the reason these results hold is simple. It is theoretically possi-ble for a country to have an MMM system with a very small percentage ofseats elected by single-member districts. However, one should not expectsuch a system to exhibit the same behavior as an MMM system in which 75%of the members are elected in single-member districts because the prefer-

    Thames, Edwards / Mixed-Member Electoral Systems 15

    13. Joint tests, however, indicate that we could not reject the hypothesis that these variablesare not different from 0.

    14. Standard linear combination tests also support this claim (Friedrich, 1982).15. Of our observations, 42% have nominal-seat percentages above 60% and are MMM (N =

    40). Thus this result is not driven by a small number of observations.

  • ences of legislators in each system for transfers or public goods will differ.As we increase the percentage of legislators chosen by the nominal tier, thismeans more legislators that prefer (lower cost) transfers to (more expensive)public goods spending. As a result, the budgets that are adopted in this sec-ond system have lower levels of expenditure than in the first.

    As we note above, the extant literature links proportional representationsystems to higher levels of public goods spending. To better demonstratethis, we run similar models using percentage of expenditures on social pro-tection as our measure of public goods spending to test Hypotheses 3 and 4.16

    Table 3 reports the results of these models. As expected, MMM systems havelower levels of social protection spending even when controlling for othereconomic and political factors (Hypotheses 3). As in Table 2, we see the neg-ative effects of presidential regimes on spending. In contrast, however, wealso find that the rate of inflation, the percentage of population older than 65,and per capita income are important determinants of the level of social pro-tection expenditure.17

    16 Comparative Political Studies

    16. Unfortunately, we do not have reliable public goods spending data for Georgia, Japan,and Taiwan.

    17. The result for percentage of population older than 65 is negative, not positive. This resultis because of a high level of collinearity with the presidential dummy, and we chose to leave it inrather than omit the variable from Models 4 through 6. We estimated the models without bothvariables and found no significant changes in the results.

    -30

    -20

    -10

    0

    10

    20

    30

    Mar

    gina

    l Eff

    ect o

    f M

    MM

    0 20 40 60 80 100 Percentage Nominal Tier Seats

    Marginal Effect of MMM

    95% Confidence Interval

    Figure 1Marginal Effect of Mixed-Member Majoritarian

    on Expenditure as a Percentage of GDP

    Note: MMM = mixed-member majoritarian.

  • Tabl

    e 3

    Tim

    e-Se

    ries

    Reg

    ress

    ion

    on S

    ocia

    l Pro

    tect

    ion

    as a

    Per

    cent

    age

    of G

    over

    nmen

    t Sp

    endi

    ng

    Inde

    pend

    ent V

    aria

    ble

    Mod

    el 4

    Coe

    ffic

    ient

    Mod

    el 5

    Coe

    ffic

    ient

    Mod

    el 6

    Coe

    ffic

    ient

    GN

    P pe

    r ca

    pita

    (t

    1)

    5.88

    0E-0

    6**

    (2.4

    10E

    -06)

    5.00

    0E-0

    6**

    (2.4

    00E

    -06)

    5.67

    0E-0

    6***

    (2.0

    20E

    -06)

    Gro

    wth

    (t

    1)

    0.0

    001

    (0.0

    003)

    0.00

    01(0

    .000

    3)0.

    0000

    (0.0

    004)

    Une

    mpl

    oym

    ent (t

    1

    )0

    .001

    4(0

    .001

    7)0

    .001

    3(0

    .001

    7)0

    .001

    3(0

    .001

    7)Pe

    rcen

    tage

    of

    popu

    latio

    n ol

    der

    than

    65

    0.0

    308*

    **(0

    .009

    4)0

    .030

    8***

    (0.0

    092)

    0.0

    322*

    **(0

    .008

    5)O

    penn

    ess (t

    1

    )0

    .000

    4(0

    .000

    3)0

    .000

    4(0

    .000

    3)0

    .000

    4(0

    .000

    3)In

    flat

    ion (

    t 1

    )0

    .000

    1*(0

    .000

    0)0

    .000

    1*(0

    .000

    0)0

    .000

    1*(0

    .000

    0)L

    agge

    d el

    ectio

    n (1

    ,0)

    0.00

    53(0

    .004

    7)0.

    0043

    (0.0

    048)

    0.00

    42(0

    .004

    7)E

    ffec

    tive

    num

    ber

    of p

    oliti

    cal p

    artie

    s0.

    0187

    ***

    (0.0

    057)

    0.02

    05**

    *(0

    .006

    5)0.

    0212

    ***

    (0.0

    067)

    Pres

    iden

    tial s

    yste

    m (

    1,0)

    0.3

    545*

    **(0

    .081

    4)0

    .367

    5***

    (0.0

    789)

    0.3

    749*

    **(0

    .075

    0)M

    MM

    (1,

    0)0

    .050

    0**

    (0.0

    241)

    0.0

    573*

    *(0

    .023

    5)Pe

    rcen

    tage

    of

    nom

    inal

    -tie

    r se

    ats

    0.07

    66*

    (0.0

    393)

    0.15

    96**

    *(0

    .051

    5)M

    MM

    *Per

    cent

    age

    of n

    omin

    al-t

    ier

    seat

    s0

    .099

    8***

    (0.0

    324)

    Con

    stan

    t0.

    5321

    ***

    (0.1

    256)

    0.50

    12**

    *(0

    .129

    5)0.

    4631

    ***

    (0.1

    314)

    Cou

    ntri

    es14

    1414

    Cas

    es77

    7777

    Mod

    el c

    hi-s

    quar

    e te

    st0.

    0000

    0.00

    000.

    0000

    Not

    e:Pa

    nel-

    Cor

    rect

    edst

    anda

    rder

    rors

    inpa

    rent

    hese

    s.M

    MM

    =m

    ixed

    -mem

    berm

    ajor

    itari

    an.

    *p>

    .10.

    **p

    > .0

    5. *

    **p

    > .0

    1.

    17

  • However, our claim is not that this distinction is merely an intercepteffect. As can be seen from Model 6 in Table 3, the interactive variableMMM*nominal-tier seat percentage is negative and strongly significant, assuggested in Hypothesis 4. To further support Hypothesis 4, we estimate themarginal effects of MMM across the percentage of nominal-tier seats (seeFigure 2).

    Figure 2 presents the estimates of the marginal effects of MMM across thepercentage of nominal-tier seats, using the same procedure described earlier.These results are similar to those displayed in Figure 1. As more legislatorsare elected in the nominal tier, the differences between MMM and MMP sys-tems become more visible. Increases in the nominal-tier percentage meanthat more legislators are elected in local districts and have incentives to pro-vide particularistic goods to local constituents. Because we know that theselegislators have lower demands for public goods spending and becauseMMM systems have independent tiers, there are weak incentives for higherlevels of expenditure. Not only does it not help individual legislators winoffice but also the parties do not have incentives to cater to broad swaths ofvoters.18

    18 Comparative Political Studies

    18. We reestimated both models with a 2SLS regression in which growth or unemploymentled politicians to change either the electoral system or the percentage of nominal seats. Ourregressions using this approach produced no evidence that this charge has validity.

    -.5

    -.4

    -.3

    -.2

    -.1 0

    .1

    .2

    .3

    .4

    .5

    Mar

    gina

    l Eff

    ect o

    f M

    MM

    0 20 40 60 80 100 Percentage of Nominal Tier Seats

    Marginal Effect of MMM

    95% Confidence Interval

    Figure 2Marginal Effect of Mixed-Member Majoritarian

    on Social Protection Expenditure as a Percentage of GDP

    Note: MMM = mixed-member majoritarian.

  • Conclusion

    The proliferation of mixed-member electoral systems has led to signifi-cant effort to specify their effects. However, scholars studying these systemsare notably silent regarding how differences within the category of mixedsystems shape policy outcomes. Although the category of mixed-membersystems encompasses a multitude of different institutional configurations,this article demonstrates how these distinctions can be simplified by address-ing two significant distinctions in mixed-member systems, namely, whethera system is MMM or MMP and the percentage of nominal seats. Using thepolitical economy literature on the electoral system effects on size of govern-ment, we hypothesize that MMM systems would behave more like puremajoritarian systems and that MMP systems would behave more like pureproportional representation systems. We provide empirical support for thishypothesis and show that the institutional differences between the systemsproduce divergent policy outcomes. In addition, we find that the distinctionbetween MMM and MMP is in fact contingent, as it turns on the percentageof nominal seats. Increases in the size of the nominal tier serve to heightendistinctions between MMM and MMP, leading to important distinctionsbetween the two types of systems in expenditure patterns.

    These findings have definite implications for the future of study of mixed-member electoral systems. The differences in fiscal policy outcomes betweenMMM and MMP systems noted here is further indication of the diversityamong mixed-member systems. It is clear that this diversity is a warning tothose who make arguments about the common effects of mixed-member sys-tems as a whole. More important, however, the findings of this article indi-cate that more research must take place on institutional differences amongmixed-member systems to understand better when and how these distinc-tions matter.

    Finally, there are clear policy implications for the institutional variationsamong mixed-member systems. The decision to link tiers and the choice of aparticular nominal-tier to list-tier ratio clearly affects levels of governmentexpenditures and the types of expenditures the system produces. Thus whenwe try to understand the policy effects of mixed-member systems, we need totake into account the differences among mixed-member system rules. Theresults presented here fit within the broader literature on the fiscal policyeffects of electoral systems, lending credence to them. Nonetheless, only fur-ther research can indicate whether the different institutional configurationsof mixed-member systems can lead to different results in areas beyond fiscalpolicy.

    Thames, Edwards / Mixed-Member Electoral Systems 19

  • References

    Alesina, Alberto. (1994). Political models of macroeconomic policy and fiscal reforms. In Ste-phen Haggard and Steven Webb (Eds.), Voting for reform (pp. 37-60). New York: OxfordUniversity Press.

    Annett, Anthony. (2002). Politics, government size, and fiscal adjustment in industrial countries(IMF Working Paper No. 02/162). Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.

    Baldez, Lisa, & Carey, John. (2001). Budget procedure and fiscal restraint in posttransitionChile. In S. Haggard & M. McCubbins (Eds.), Presidents, parliaments, and policy (pp. 105-148). Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

    Bank of Japan. (2004). Bank of Japan statistics and other key statistics. Retrieved April 29, 2004,from http://www.boj.or.jp/en/stat/sk/ske.htm

    Bawn, Kathleen. (1993). The logic of institutional preferences: German electoral law as a socialchoice outcome. American Journal of Political Science, 37, 965-989.

    Bawn, Kathleen. (1999). Voter responses to electoral complexities: Ticket splitting, rational vot-ers, and representation in the federal republic of Germany. British Journal of Political Sci-ence, 29, 487-505.

    Bawn, Kathleen, & Thies, Michael. (2003). A comparative theory of electoral incentives: Repre-senting the unorganized under PR, plurality, and mixed-member electoral systems. Journalof Theoretical Politics, 15, 5-32.

    Bean, Clive. (1990). The personal vote in Australian federal elections. Political Studies, 38, 253-268.

    Beck, Nathaniel, & Katz, Jonathan. (1995). What to do (and not to do) with time-series cross-section data. American Political Science Review, 89, 634-648.

    Beck, Thorsetne, Clarke, George, Groff, Albert, Keefer, Philip, & Walsh, Patrick. (2001). Newtools and new tests in comparative political economy: The database of political institutions.World Bank Economic Review, 15, 65-176.

    Benoit, Kenneth, & Schiemann, John. (2001). Institutional choice in new democracies: Bargain-ing over Hungarys 1989 electoral law. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 13, 159-188.

    Bernhard, William, & Leblang, David. (1999). Democratic institutions and exchange-rate com-mitments. International Organization, 53, 71-97.

    Brambor, Thomas, Clark, William, & Golder, Matt. (2004, April). Understanding interactionmodels: What we thought we knew but obviously didnt. Paper presented at the annual meet-ing of the Midwest Political Science Association.

    Cox, Gary. (1997). Making votes count: Strategic coordination in the worlds electoral systems.Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

    Cox, Karen, & Schoppa, Len. (2002). Interaction effects and mixed-member systems: Theoryand evidence from Germany, Japan, and Italy. Comparative Political Studies, 35, 1027-1053.

    Crepaz, Markus. (1996). Consensus versus majoritarian democracy: Political institutions andtheir impact on macroeconomic performance and industrial disputes. Comparative PoliticalStudies, 19, 4-26.

    Duverger, Maurice. (1954). Political parties. New York: John Wiley.Fenno, Richard. (1978). Home style: House members in their districts. Boston: Little, Brown.Ferrara, Frederico. (2004). Electoral coordination and the strategic desertion of strong parties in

    compensatory mixed systems with negative vote transfers. Electoral Studies, 23, 391-413.Ferrara, Frederico, & Herron, Erik. (2005). Going it alone? Strategic entry under mixed electoral

    rules. American Journal of Political Science, 49, 16-31.Fiorina, Morris. (1997). Congress: Keystone of the Washington establishment. New Haven, CT:

    Yale University Press.

    20 Comparative Political Studies

  • Friedrich, Robert. (1982). In defense of interactive terms in multiple regression equations. Amer-ican Journal of Political Science, 26, 797-833.

    Gschwend, Thomas, Johnston, Ron, & Pattie, Charles. (2003). Split-Ticket voting in mixed-member proportional election systems: Estimates and analyses of their spatial variation inthe German federal election, 1998. British Journal of Political Science, 33, 109-128.

    Grilli, Vittoro, Masciandaro, Donato, & Tabellini, Guido. (1991). Political and monetary institu-tions and public financial policies in the industrial countries. Economic Policy, 13, 341-392.

    Hallerberg, Mark, & Marier, Patrik. (2004). Executive authority, the personal vote, and budgetdiscipline in Latin American and Caribbean countries. American Journal of Political Sci-ence, 48, 571-587.

    Haspel, Moshe, Remington, Thomas, & Smith, Steven. (1998). Electoral institutions and partycohesion in the Russian Duma. Journal of Politics, 60, 417-439.

    Herron, Erik. (2002). Electoral influences on legislative behavior in mixed-member systems:Evidence from the Ukraines Verkhovna Rada. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 27, 361-381.

    Herron, Erik, & Nishikawa, Misa. (2001). Contamination effects and the number of parties inmixed superposition electoral systems. Electoral Studies, 20, 63-86.

    Inman, Robert. (1990). Public debts and fiscal politics? American Economic Review Papers andProceedings, 80, 81-85.

    Inter-American Development Bank. (1997). Latin America after a decade of reforms. Baltimore:Johns Hopkins University Press.

    International Monetary Fund. (2001). Government financial statistics manual 2001. Washing-ton, DC: Author.

    International Monetary Fund. (2003). Government financial statistics [CD-ROM]. Washington,DC: Author.

    Ishiyama, John. (2000). Candidate recruitment, party organization and the Communist succes-sor parties: The cases of the MSzP, the KPRF, and the LDDP. Europe-Asia Studies, 52, 875-896.

    King, Gary. (1990). Electoral responsiveness and partisan bias in multiparty democracies. Legis-lative Studies Quarterly, 15, 159-181.

    Kontopoulos, Yianos, & Perotti, Roberto. (1999). Government fragmentation and fiscal policyoutcomes: Evidence from OECD countries. In James Poterba & Jurgen von Hagen (Eds.),Fiscal institutions and fiscal performance (pp. 81-102). Chicago: University of ChicagoPress.

    Lancaster, Thomas, & Patterson, W. David. (1990). Comparative pork barrel politics: Percep-tions from the West German Bundestag. Comparative Political Studies, 22, 458-477.

    Leblang, David. (1999). Domestic political institutions and exchange rate commitments in thedeveloping world. International Studies Quarterly, 43, 599-620.

    Lizzeri, Alessandro, & Persico, Nicola. (2001). The provision of public goods under alternativeelectoral incentives. American Economic Review, 91, 225-245.

    Mayhew, David. (1974). Congress: The electoral connection. New Haven, CT: Yale UniversityPress.

    McCarty, Nolan. (2000). Presidential pork: Executive veto power and distributive politics.American Political Science Review, 94, 117-129.

    McGillivray, Fiona. (1997). Party discipline as a determinant of the endogenous formation of tar-iffs. American Journal of Political Science, 41, 584-607.

    Milesi-Ferretti, Gian Maria, & Perotii, Roberto (with Rostagno, Massimo). (2002). Electoralsystems and public spending. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117, 609-658.

    Moser, Robert. (1999). Electoral systems and the number of parties in post-Communist states.World Politics, 51, 359-384.

    Thames, Edwards / Mixed-Member Electoral Systems 21

  • Moser, Robert. (2001). Unexpected outcomes: Electoral systems, political parties, and repre-sentation in Russia. Pittsburgh, PA: Pittsburgh University Press.

    Moser, Robert, & Scheiner, Ethan. (2004). Mixed electoral systems and electoral system effects:Controlled comparison and cross-national analysis. Electoral Studies, 23, 575-599.

    Navarra, Pietro, & Sobbrio, Giuseppe. (2001). Election running and the nature of constitutionalchoices: The case of Italian electoral reform. Constitutional Political Economy, 12, 31-50.

    Nielson, Daniel. (2003). Supplying trade reform: Political institutions and liberalization in mid-dle-income presidential democracies. American Journal of Political Science, 47, 470-491.

    North, Philip. (1994). The growth of the constituency role of the MP. Parliamentary Affairs, 47,705-720.

    Norton, Philip, & Wood, David. (1990). Constituency service by members of parliament: Does itcontribute to a personal vote? Parliamentary Affairs, 43, 196-208.

    Perotti, Roberto, & Kontopoulos, Yianos. (2002). Fragmented fiscal policy. Journal of PublicEconomics, 82, 191-222.

    Persson, Torsten, Roland, Gerard, & Tabellini, Guido. (2000). Comparative politics and publicfinance. Journal of Political Economy, 106, 1121-1160.

    Persson, Torsten, & Tabellini, Guido. (1999). The size and scope of government: Comparativepolitics with rational politicians. European Economic Review, 43, 699-735.

    Peterson, Paul. (1985/1986). The new politics of deficits. Political Science Quarterly, 100, 575-601.

    Polity IV Project. (2000). Polity IV data set (Version p4v2000) [Computer file]. College Park:University of Maryland, Center for International Development and Conflict Management.

    Reed, Steven. (2001). Duvergers law is working in Italy. Comparative Political Studies, 34, 312-327.

    Reed, Steven, & Thies, Michael. (2001). The causes of electoral reform in Japan. In MatthewShugart & Martin Wattenberg (Eds.), Mixed-Member electoral systems: The best of bothworlds? (pp. 152-172). Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.

    Remington, Thomas, & Smith, Steven. (1996). Political goals, institutional context, and thechoice of an electoral system: The Russian parliamentary electoral law. American Journal ofPolitical Science, 40, 545-572.

    Republic of China Directorate-General of Budget, Accounting, and Statistics. (2002). Statisticalyearbook of the Republic of China. Taipei, Taiwan: Author.

    Roberts, Geoffrey. (1988). The second-vote campaign strategy of the West German Free Dem-ocratic Party. European Journal of Political Research, 16, 317-337.

    Rogowski, Ronald, & Kayser, Mark Andreas. (2002). Majoritarian electoral systems and con-sumer power: Price-Level evidence from the OECD countries. American Journal of PoliticalScience, 46, 526-539.

    Roubini, Nouriel, & Sachs, Jeffrey D. (1989). Political and economic determinants of budgetdeficits in the industrial democracies. European Economic Review, 33, 903-933.

    Scholl, Edward. (1986). The electoral system and constituency-oriented activity in the EuropeanParliament. International Studies Quarterly, 30, 315-332.

    Schultz, Kenneth. (1995). The politics of the political business cycle. British Journal of PoliticalScience, 25, 79-99.

    Shugart, Matthew, & Wattenberg, Martin. (2001a). Mixed-Member electoral systems: A defini-tion and typology. In Matthew Shugart & Martin Wattenberg (Eds.), Mixed-Member elec-toral systems: The best of both worlds? (pp. 9-24). Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.

    Shugart, Matthew, & Wattenberg, Martin. (Eds.). (2001b). Mixed-Member electoral systems:The best of both worlds? Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.

    22 Comparative Political Studies

  • Smith, Steven, & Remington, Thomas. (2001). The politics of institutional choice: The forma-tion of the Russian State Duma. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Stratmann, Thomas, & Baur, Martin. (2002). Plurality rule, proportional representation, and theGerman Bundestag: How incentives to pork-barrel differ across electoral systems. AmericanJournal of Political Science, 46, 506-514.

    Taagepera, Rein, & Shugart, Matthew. (1979). Seats & votes: The effects and determinants ofelectoral systems. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

    Thames, Frank. (2001). Legislative voting behaviour in the Russian Duma: Understanding theeffect of mandate. Europe-Asia Studies, 53, 869-884.

    Ward, Hugh, & Peter, John. (1999). Targeting benefits for electoral gain: Constituency marginal-ity and the distribution of grants to English local authorities. Political Studies, 47, 32-52.

    Wooldridge, Jeffrey. (2002). Econometric analysis of cross section and panel data. Cambridge,MA: MIT Press.

    World Bank. (2002). World development indicators [CD-ROM]. Washington, DC: World Bank.

    Frank C. Thames is an assistant professor in the Department of Political Science at Texas TechUniversity. His research primarily focuses on legislative behavior in post-Communist regimes.His recent work has appeared in Comparative Political Studies, Social Science Quarterly, andCommunist and Post-Communist Studies.

    Martin S. Edwards is an assistant professor in the Department of Political Science at TexasTech University. His research primarily focuses on the interaction of domestic and internationalfinancial institutions. His most recent work has appeared in Social Science Quarterly.

    Thames, Edwards / Mixed-Member Electoral Systems 23